TheEconomist 2024 06 22
TheEconomist 2024 06 22
TheEconomist 2024 06 22
Duolingo - 快乐、高效学外
语, 带你玩转听说读写! 点击下载
英阅阅读器 - 让您高效阅读
英语书, 点击查词、句子翻译、背单词、词汇透析一应俱全! 点击下载
Notability - 高 效 、 便 捷 的
PDF笔记App, 随时记录你的想法! 点击下载
欧路词典 - 英语学习者的必
备词典App ! 点击下载
The world this week
Politics
Business
KAL’s cartoon
This week’s covers
The world this week
Politics
June 20th 2024
Vladimir Putin visited North Korea. The Russian president was given an
elaborate welcome before holding talks with Kim Jong Un, the Asian
country’s dictator. The pair have strengthened their alliance during the war
in Ukraine, with North Korea providing Russia with weapons. The West
fears that in return Russia is helping North Korea with its nuclear
programme. Both leaders signed a mutual-defence pact. Mr Putin then went
to Vietnam, where he was also given the full state-visit treatment.
South Korean soldiers fired warning shots at North Korean troops who had
breached the demarcation line in the demilitarised zone that separates the
South and North. It was the second such incident in a week, though South
Korea thinks the breaches were accidental.
Thaksin Shinawatra, who was deposed as Thailand’s prime minister in a
coup in 2006 and returned from exile last year, was formally charged with
insulting the monarchy. Mr Thaksin, an influential figure in Thai politics,
was granted bail, deferring for now the problematic prospect of sending him
to prison. The indictment is one of three politically charged cases that could
rock Thai politics. The Constitutional Court has set dates for early July to
hear one case that could bring down the prime minister, Srettha Thavisin,
and another that could ban Move Forward, the main opposition party.
A global summit to shore up support for Ukraine in its fight against Russia
ended without securing the agreement of the big non-aligned countries.
China stayed away from the gathering in Switzerland and countries such as
India, Indonesia, Mexico, Saudi Arabia and South Africa did not sign the
final communiqué.
The Israel Defence Forces said that it would hold a daily “tactical pause” of
military activity on a road in the south of Gaza to allow more aid to enter
the territory through the Kerem Shalom crossing. Binyamin Netanyahu,
Israel’s prime minister, denounced the decision. The IDF made it clear that this
did not amount to a ceasefire. It said that fighting would continue in Rafah,
where eight soldiers were killed recently.
A ship that was attacked recently by Houthi insurgents from Yemen sank in
the Red Sea, the second vessel that the rebels have sunk since starting their
campaign to disrupt shipping last November. One crewman died in the
incident. The Houthis used a drone boat packed with explosives.
South Africa’s two biggest political parties, the African National Congress
and the Democratic Alliance, formed a coalition government headed by
Cyril Ramaphosa, the president, after the ANC lost its parliamentary majority.
The new government, which also includes other smaller parties, agreed to
focus on economic growth, cheering investors. MK, the party of Jacob Zuma, a
disgraced former ANC president, will join the opposition.
Senegal joined the club of African oil producers, as the country’s first
offshore project commenced production after a string of delays. The new
government of Bassirou Diomaye Faye, Senegal’s left-leaning nationalist
president, hopes the nascent oil and gas industry will enable it to invest more
heavily in its priorities, such as agriculture.
The UN Security Council adopted a resolution ordering the Rapid Support
Forces, a rebellious Sudanese paramilitary group, to lift its siege of el-
Fasher, in the Darfur region. It also called for a halt in fighting between the
RSF and the official Sudanese Armed Forces. The resolution, which passed
Large protests were held in Brazil against a proposed change to the law that
would equate abortions after 22 weeks to homicide. Conservatives in
Congress support the bill, but critics note that late abortions are often
performed on children who were abused by relatives. Abortion is legal in
Brazil only in cases of rape, fetal deformation and when the woman’s life is
in danger.
Venezuela’s opposition coalition said that four more of its activists had been
arrested ahead of the presidential election on July 28th. Dozens of
opposition figures have been detained this year on bogus conspiratorial
claims. Polling suggests that Nicolás Maduro, the authoritarian president,
would heavily lose a free and fair vote.
Ecuador will temporarily suspend visa waivers for Chinese nationals from
July 1st, as tens of thousands of migrants travel to the country en route to the
United States. Ecuador is one of only two South American countries that
grant visa-free travel to Chinese visitors (Suriname is the other). From there,
they often head north. The number of Chinese nationals trying to cross the US
border has rocketed since 2022.
This article was downloaded by zlibrary from https://www.economist.com/the-world-this-week/2024/06/20/politics
The world this week
Business
June 20th 2024
Nvidia overtook Microsoft and Apple to become the world’s most valuable
company, with a stockmarket value of more than $3.3trn. The maker of
chips for artificial intelligence has seen its share price surge by 40% since
issuing bumper quarterly revenues and profits a month ago, and expects
sales to increase from the roll-out of its Blackwell chip, billed as the world’s
most powerful. Nvidia is only one of a dozen companies to lead the S&P 500
since its creation in 1926. It recently split its stock, lowering the share price
to make it more attractive to small investors.
Broadcom’s share price also hit new highs, after the chipmaker announced a
ten-for-one stock split that comes into effect in July. Over the past few years
big tech companies have been using stock splits to dilute the price of their
surging shares, though Meta and Microsoft have notably not done so.
A study by the IMF said that the “sheer scale and speed of the transformation”
in AI would amplify job losses, reducing the share of labour income in
national accounts and exacerbating inequality. It called on governments to
prepare social systems that will “cushion the transition costs for workers”.
The Bank of England held its main interest rate steady, at 5.25%. The day
before the decision new figures showed headline annual inflation in Britain
dropping to 2% in May, bang on the bank’s target, though the core rate,
excluding food and energy, was 3.5%, and inflation for services didn’t fall as
much as expected. The bank’s next monetary-policy meeting is on August
1st, after a general election that is expected to usher Labour into power.
Investor reprieve
A judge in Texas dismissed what remained of ExxonMobil’s lawsuit against
activist investors over its emissions targets. Arjuna Capital and Follow This
had proposed a proxy vote on quickening the pace of Exxon’s emission cuts,
but they dropped the proposal when it threatened to sue, claiming they were
abusing the proxy system. The judge ruled that the case against Arjuna was
now invalid, as it had pledged not to refile the motion. He had already
removed Follow This from the suit.
KAL’s cartoon
June 20th 2024
KAL’s cartoon appears weekly in The Economist. You can see last week’s
here.
This article was downloaded by zlibrary from https://www.economist.com/the-world-this-week/2024/06/20/kals-cartoon
The world this week | The Economist
This week we had two covers. In the EU we explored how the character of
warfare is about to be profoundly changed by artificial intelligence (AI). This
rapid change has several causes. One is the crucible of war itself, most
notably in Ukraine. A second is the recent exponential advance of AI. A third
is the rivalry between America and China, in which both see AI as the key to
military superiority. The scale of AI-based war means that mass and industrial
heft are likely to become even more important than they are today. The
uncertainties are profound. The only sure thing is that AI-driven change is
drawing near.
Leader: The exponential growth of solar power will change the world
Essay: Solar power is going to be huge
Africa: Private firms are driving a revolution in solar power in Africa
Business: China’s giant solar industry is in turmoil
Business: Floating solar has a bright future
This article was downloaded by zlibrary from https://www.economist.com/the-world-this-week/2024/06/20/this-weeks-covers
Leaders
The exponential growth of solar power will change the world
AI will transform the character of warfare
Emmanuel Macron’s project of reform is at risk
How to tax billionaires—and how not to
Javier Milei’s next move could make his presidency—or break it
India should liberate its cities and create more states
Leaders | The solar age
It is 70 years since AT&T’s Bell Labs unveiled a new technology for turning
sunlight into power. The phone company hoped it could replace the batteries
that run equipment in out-of-the-way places. It also realised that powering
devices with light alone showed how science could make the future seem
wonderful; hence a press event at which sunshine kept a toy Ferris wheel
spinning round and round.
Today solar power is long past the toy phase. Panels now occupy an area
around half that of Wales, and this year they will provide the world with
about 6% of its electricity—which is almost three times as much electrical
energy as America consumed back in 1954. Yet this historic growth is only
the second-most-remarkable thing about the rise of solar power. The most
remarkable is that it is nowhere near over.
Solar cells will in all likelihood be the single biggest source of electrical
power on the planet by the mid 2030s. By the 2040s they may be the largest
source not just of electricity but of all energy. On current trends, the all-in
cost of the electricity they produce promises to be less than half as expensive
as the cheapest available today. This will not stop climate change, but could
slow it a lot faster. Much of the world—including Africa, where 600m
people still cannot light their homes—will begin to feel energy-rich. That
feeling will be a new and transformational one for humankind.
To grasp that this is not some environmentalist fever dream, consider solar
economics. As the cumulative production of a manufactured good increases,
costs go down. As costs go down, demand goes up. As demand goes up,
production increases—and costs go down further. This cannot go on for
ever; production, demand or both always become constrained. In earlier
energy transitions—from wood to coal, coal to oil or oil to gas—the
efficiency of extraction grew, but it was eventually offset by the cost of
finding ever more fuel.
As our essay this week explains, solar power faces no such constraint. The
resources needed to produce solar cells and plant them on solar farms are
silicon-rich sand, sunny places and human ingenuity, all three of which are
abundant. Making cells also takes energy, but solar power is fast making that
abundant, too. As for demand, it is both huge and elastic—if you make
electricity cheaper, people will find uses for it. The result is that, in contrast
to earlier energy sources, solar power has routinely become cheaper and will
continue to do so.
Another worry is that the vast majority of the world’s solar panels, and
almost all the purified silicon from which they are made, come from China.
Its solar industry is highly competitive, heavily subsidised and is
outstripping current demand—quite an achievement given all the solar
capacity China is installing within its own borders. This means that Chinese
capacity is big enough to keep the expansion going for years to come, even
if some of the companies involved go to the wall and some investment dries
up.
In the long run, a world in which more energy is generated without the oil
and gas that come from unstable or unfriendly parts of the world will be
more dependable. Still, although the Chinese Communist Party cannot rig
the price of sunlight as OPEC tries to rig that of oil, the fact that a vital industry
resides in a single hostile country is worrying.
It is a concern that America feels keenly, which is why it has put tariffs on
Chinese solar equipment. However, because almost all the demand for solar
panels still lies in the future, the rest of the world will have plenty of scope
to get into the market. America’s adoption of solar energy could be
frustrated by a pro-fossil-fuel Trump presidency, but only temporarily and
painfully. It could equally be enhanced if America released pent up demand,
by making it easier to install panels on homes and to join the grid—the
country has a terawatt of new solar capacity waiting to be connected. Carbon
prices would help, just as they did in the switch from coal to gas in the
European Union.
The aim should be for the virtuous circle of solar-power production to turn
as fast as possible. That is because it offers the prize of cheaper energy. The
benefits start with a boost to productivity. Anything that people use energy
for today will cost less—and that includes pretty much everything. Then
come the things cheap energy will make possible. People who could never
afford to will start lighting their houses or driving a car. Cheap energy can
purify water, and even desalinate it. It can drive the hungry machinery of
artificial intelligence. It can make billions of homes and offices more
bearable in summers that will, for decades to come, be getting hotter.
But it is the things that nobody has yet thought of that will be most
consequential. In its radical abundance, cheaper energy will free the
imagination, setting tiny Ferris wheels of the mind spinning with excitement
and new possibilities.
This week marks the summer solstice in the northern hemisphere. The Sun
rising to its highest point in the sky will in decades to come shine down on a
world where nobody need go without the blessings of electricity and where
the access to energy invigorates all those it touches. ■
For subscribers only: to see how we design each week’s cover, sign up to our
weekly Cover Story newsletter.
This article was downloaded by zlibrary from https://www.economist.com/leaders/2024/06/20/the-exponential-growth-of-solar-power-
will-change-the-world
Leaders | The future of combat
THE COMPUTER was born in war and by war. Colossus was built in 1944
to crack Nazi codes. By the 1950s computers were organising America’s air
defences. In the decades that followed, machine intelligence played a small
part in warfare. Now it is about to become pivotal. Just as the civilian world
is witnessing rapid progress in the power and spread of artificial intelligence
(AI), so too must the military world prepare for an onrush of innovation. As
much as it transforms the character of war, it could also prove destabilising.
Today’s rapid change has several causes. One is the crucible of war itself,
most notably in Ukraine. Small, inexpensive chips routinely guide Russian
and Ukrainian drones to their targets, scaling up a technology once confined
to a superpower’s missiles. A second is the recent exponential advance of AI,
enabling astonishing feats of object recognition and higher-order problem
solving. A third is the rivalry between America and China, in which both see
AI as the key to military superiority.
The results are most visible in the advance of intelligent killing machines.
Aerial and naval drones have been vital to both sides in Ukraine for spotting
and attacking targets. AI’s role is as the solution to jamming, because it
enables a drone to home in on targets, even if GPS signals or the link to the
pilot have been cut. Breaking the connection between pilot and plane should
soon let armies deploy far larger numbers of low-cost munitions. Eventually
self-directing swarms will be designed to swamp defences.
But what is most visible about military AI is not what is most important. As
our briefing explains, the technology is also revolutionising the command
and control that military officers use to orchestrate wars.
On the front line, drones embody just the last and most dramatic link in the
kill chain, the series of steps beginning with the search for a target and
ending in an attack. AI’s deeper significance is what it can do before the drone
strikes. Because it sorts through and processes data at superhuman speed, it
can pluck every tank out of a thousand satellite images, or interpret light,
heat, sound and radio waves to distinguish decoys from the real thing.
Away from the front line, it can solve much larger problems than those faced
by a single drone. Today that means simple tasks, such as working out which
weapon is best suited to destroying a threat. In due course, “decision-support
systems” may be able to grasp the baffling complexity of war rapidly and
over a wide area—perhaps an entire battlefield.
The consequences of this are only just becoming clear. AI systems, coupled
with autonomous robots on land, sea and air, are likely to find and destroy
targets at an unprecedented speed and on a vast scale.
The speed of such warfare will change the balance between soldier and
software. Today, armies keep a man “in the loop”, approving each lethal
decision. As finding and striking targets is compressed into minutes or
seconds, the human may merely “sit on the loop”, as part of a human-
machine team. People will oversee the system without intervening in every
action.
The paradox is that even as AI gives a clearer sense of the battlefield, war
risks becoming more opaque for the people who fight it. There will be less
time to stop and think. As the models hand down increasingly oracular
judgments, their output will become ever harder to scrutinise without ceding
the enemy a lethal advantage. Armies will fear that if they do not give their AI
advisers a longer leash, they will be defeated by an adversary who does.
Faster combat and fewer pauses will make it harder to negotiate truces or
halt escalation. This may favour defenders, who can hunker down while
attackers break cover as they advance. Or it may tempt attackers to strike
pre-emptively and with massive force, so as to tear down the sensors and
networks on which AI-enabled armies will depend.
The scale of AI-based war means that mass and industrial heft are likely to
become even more important than they are today. You might think new
technology will let armies become leaner. But if software can pick out tens
of thousands of targets, armies will need tens of thousands of weapons to
strike them. And if the defender has the advantage, attackers will need more
weapons to break through.
That is not the only reason AI warfare favours big countries. Drones may get
cheaper, but the digital systems that mesh the battlefield together will be
fiendishly expensive. Building AI-infused armies will take huge investments
in cloud servers able to handle secret data. Armies, navies and air forces that
today exist in their own data silos will have to be integrated. Training the
models will call for access to vast troves of data.
Which big country does AI favour most? China was once thought to have an
advantage, thanks to its pool of data, control over private industry and looser
ethical constraints. Yet just now America looks to be ahead in the frontier
models that may shape the next generation of military AI. And ideology
matters: it is unclear whether the armies of authoritarian states, which prize
centralised control, will be able to exploit the benefits of a technology that
pushes intelligence and insight to the lowest tactical levels.
If, tragically, the first AI-powered war does break out, international law is
likely to be pushed to the margins. All the more reason to think today about
how to limit the destruction. China should heed America’s call to rule out AI
control over nuclear weapons, for instance. And once a war begins, human-
to-human hotlines will become more important than ever. AI systems told to
maximise military advantage will need to be encoded with values and
restraints that human commanders take for granted. These include placing an
implicit value on human life—how many civilians is it acceptable to kill in
pursuing a high-value target?—and avoiding certain destabilising strikes,
such as on nuclear early-warning satellites.
The uncertainties are profound. The only sure thing is that AI-driven change
is drawing near. The armies that anticipate and master technological
advances earliest and most effectively will probably prevail. Everyone else
is likely to be a victim. ■
For subscribers only: to see how we design each week’s cover, sign up to our
weekly Cover Story newsletter.
This article was downloaded by zlibrary from https://www.economist.com/leaders/2024/06/20/war-and-ai
Leaders | French peril
The signs so far are ominous. The stockmarket has fallen by 4% since he
made his announcement on June 9th, the night of his party’s drubbing in the
European Parliament elections at the hands of Marine Le Pen’s National
Rally. Share prices in France’s three big banks are down by almost 10%.
Bond spreads are widening. Euro-elections tend to be a protest vote, not a
reflection of how people will express themselves when choosing their
national parliament. This time, however, their anger now has barely a week
left to dissipate and the polls show no sign that it will.
The president faces a squeeze between Ms Le Pen’s hard right and a rapidly
created New Popular Front that includes powerful hard-left elements,
especially the Unsubmissive France party dominated by Jean-Luc
Mélenchon, a former Trotskyist. Mr Macron seems to have assumed such an
alliance would not be formed so fast. France’s parliamentary elections use a
two-round system, with a high threshold for going through to the second
round. The danger is that most of the president’s men and women will not
make it that far—leaving a choice between the xenophobic nationalists and
the anti-capitalist radicals. His political group, Ensemble, faces losing half
its seats or more.
Mr Macron will remain in office; his term does not expire until 2027. But
although the president has extensive powers over defence and foreign policy,
new domestic policy, like the budget, needs to be voted through by
parliament. Administering it is the preserve of the government, headed by a
prime minister whom the president picks but whom parliament can dismiss
through a simple confidence vote. In practice, Mr Macron will have little
choice but to offer the job to the nominee of whichever party or alliance
comes top. Mr Macron may hope that his centrists can forge a post-election
alliance with other moderates, but the numbers do not look close to adding
up.
Editor’s note (June 20th 2024): The Supreme Court has ruled in Moore v
United States, upholding the tax at issue (the “mandatory repatriation tax”).
The court declined to weigh in on the constitutionality of a tax on unrealised
gains.
THE RICH are different from other people. They have more money and, in most
places, they pay much less tax. Going by one broad definition of income that
combines consumption and someone’s change in net worth, America’s best-
heeled pay just a few cents on every dollar of their fortunes. Lately, those
fortunes have ballooned, thanks to a soaring stockmarket. One study found
that unrealised capital gains account for $6trn of the $11trn in wealth held by
the richest Americans. Since 2023, as the artificial-intelligence frenzy has
fuelled demand for both Nvidia’s GPUs and its shares, the chipmaker’s
founder, Jensen Huang, made more than $100bn. But until he sells some of
his stocks, all that money is off-limits to the taxman.
Taxes should be simple to administer and collect. Ideally, they should also
raise revenue while distorting behaviour as little as possible. Taxing
unrealised gains fails on each of these counts. Calculating someone’s net
worth is nightmarishly complicated even once, at their death, let alone every
year. America’s Internal Revenue Service took 12 years to put a value on
Michael Jackson’s estate. France, Sweden and a few other European
countries that have tried to levy wealth taxes have abandoned their efforts
after generating lots of administrative headaches but little actual revenue.
Taxing unrealised gains would also cause wild swings in the liabilities of
people who own volatile assets, including Mr Huang and his Nvidia shares.
Mr Biden’s proposal, which assesses the tax over five years, smooths out
some of this volatility. But some taxpayers would still fail to get a rebate for
their unrealised losses. That could discourage angel investors and other risk-
takers from backing promising ventures whose stratospheric valuations
could suddenly collapse, and which can be hard to price. In America taxing
unrealised gains may also be unconstitutional. The Supreme Court is about
to rule in a case in which the plaintiffs claim that a one-off levy on foreign
investments in 2017 was illegal because it taxed their unrealised gains. Even
if the justices issue a narrow ruling that leaves the principle intact, Mr
Biden’s idea will be challenged.
What, then, are the tax authorities to do? In America they could start by
ending the rule that lets inheritors reset the clock for capital-gains each time
someone dies. This provision of the tax code, called “step-up in basis”, was
introduced in 1921, five years after estate taxes, which are assessed on the
market value of assets at the owner’s death. The goal was to avoid double
taxation. If heirs paid estate tax on this fair value, they should not also pay
tax on any further capital gains.
This rationale looks flimsy now that the biggest estates are built not on
earned income, which would have been taxed throughout an estate-builder’s
life, but on assets’ appreciation, which was not. Heirs who get rich thanks to
their benefactor’s buy, borrow and die are therefore treated very differently
from those who inherit a fortune amassed out of taxed income.
Scrapping step-up in basis could yield perhaps a quarter of the $500bn that
Mr Biden hopes to get from his wealth tax, at a far lower administrative cost.
Taxing capital gains at death would raise the same again. He could realise
much of the rest by closing other loopholes, notably the “carried interest”
provision which lets buy-out barons pay capital-gains tax rather than
(usually higher) income tax on their private-equity firms’ investment profits.
Going after unrealised gains is easy to understand and hence good politics.
But it is bad economics. ■
This article was downloaded by zlibrary from https://www.economist.com/leaders/2024/06/19/how-to-tax-billionaires-and-how-not-to
Leaders | Raising Argentina
Very soon Mr Milei must also decide on the future of the central bank and
the peso. Argentina’s awful history of inflation and default means it is right
to explore new ways to anchor the economy. Yet on this front Mr Milei has
so far offered monetary anarchy rather than a new order. On the campaign
trail he promised to dollarise the economy and “blow up” the central bank.
Now he and his team talk of “currency competition”, whereby the peso
would coexist with other currencies. But the details remain worryingly
vague. And he still wants to close the central bank. All this uncertainty has
costs. Investors do not want to sink cash into a country where the monetary
system and currency are up for grabs.
Mr Milei still harbours radical visions, even if some on his team do not. In
May he declared that he wanted “endogenous dollarisation”. Argentines
could use dollars or pesos, but the supply of pesos would be fixed. When the
economy grows (and thus needs more money to circulate) Argentines would
therefore be forced to start using their own dollar savings. The peso, he said,
would become a “museum piece”.
This half-baked scheme raises more questions than it answers. It has never
been tried elsewhere. Freezing the money supply could lead to deflation. Or,
if the goal is to push people away from pesos entirely, even for transactions,
then it could stoke inflation as the supply of pesos outstrips plummeting
demand for them. The IMF, which has a $44bn lending programme to
Argentina, seems worried. Mr Milei has promised to tell the fund all about
his monetary plans by the end of the month. But, if endogenous dollarisation
survives, it would probably be less likely to lend his government new cash.
The opening line of India’s constitution declares that the country “shall be a
union of states”. After independence in 1947, princely realms were folded
into new states, residual colonial territory annexed, and borders reorganised
along linguistic lines. The system continues to adapt. Three new states were
born in 2000. Telangana, the newest, turned ten this month. Today, India’s
28 states are powerful. They employ more people than local and central
governments put together. And they are constitutionally responsible, or
jointly responsible, for most basic functions, including health care,
education, law and order, agriculture and the supply of welfare.
Yet today’s set-up has two problems. One is that India’s mega-cities lack
autonomy: they are typically part of states with large rural populations
whom politicians tend to put first. The other is that many states are too large.
America, with a quarter of the people, has 50 states. China has 27 provinces
and autonomous regions but its administrative energies are concentrated at
the sub-provincial level. Uttar Pradesh (UP), the largest Indian state, has 240m
people, more than Nigeria or Brazil.
This newspaper does not usually argue for more government. But it has no
hesitation in arguing for more governments. True, India has tried this before.
In the 1990s Parliament passed constitutional amendments aimed at
devolving power from states to local governments, but states proved
reluctant to cede control.
Stay on top of our India coverage by signing up to Essential India, our free
weekly newsletter.
This article was downloaded by zlibrary from https://www.economist.com/leaders/2024/06/20/india-should-liberate-its-cities-and-
create-more-states
Letters
Letters to the editor
Letters | On competition law, old people and savings, green belts, New York,
worms, equality, followership
One need only see the unfortunate changes forced upon Google Maps in the
EU, where users can no longer click map locations from their search results, to
The case-by-case approach that prevails under most competition law allows
enforcers to separate the wheat from the chaff and condemn only those
business practices that ultimately prove harmful to consumers. This cautious
approach has arguably helped America to become a global leader in digital
markets, by nurturing promising firms rather than imposing overbearing
rules upon them.
In the same vein, the balance of aggregate demand (all people consume) to
aggregate supply (only those who still work) will shift towards less supply
and hence more price pressures. At the margin, low birth rates helped
explain why inflation and interest rates were so low over the past 15 years
while the baby boomers were still working and saving. But that will be over
very soon. With ever more pensioners around, brace yourself for somewhat
sticky inflation and higher rates for longer.
HOLGER SCHMIEDING
Chief economist
Berenberg
London
Save London’s lungs
It is an unpopular opinion these days, but green belts are doing their job well
(“Labour’s growth plan”, June 8th). The nearest bit of green belt to central
London is about 30 minutes by Tube and most of it is over an hour’s
commute. People don’t want to live out there. They want to live 15 minutes
away from their work, in places with good infrastructure and connectivity.
I sometimes take the train into Paddington. The last 20 minutes of this
journey travels through seemingly endless areas of low density, low-rise
Victorian or post-war housing sprinkled with industrial parks and lonely
office blocks, aka urban sprawl, exactly what the green belt was created to
arrest. Rather than allowing this monotonous concrete kudzu to resume its
inexorable outward creep it is much more sensible to densify and modernise
the urban areas that people already reside in. The quest to build on green
belts has become an end in itself and its proponents have lost sight of the
real aim, which is to provide affordable housing in places where people want
to live.
Britain’s cities don’t need to grow wider, they need to grow taller.
NICK LOTT
In fact, the only ones who are excited about this half-baked idea are affluent
people who don’t need to punch a clock and have the luxury of working
from home. Before we go dipping into the working man’s pocket (again) to
fix the transit authority, how about we conduct a thorough audit to ensure
our money is being spent properly first.
PATRICK LINDIE
New York
In praise of the lowly worm
“Wormageddon” (May 25th) noted that Charles Darwin’s book on worms,
“The Formation of Vegetable Mould”, did not enjoy the same success as his
“On the Origin of Species”. Darwin’s interest in worms was sparked by
reading Gilbert White’s “The Natural History and Antiquities of Selborne”.
In that study White records, in minute detail, the flora and fauna of the
village of Selborne in Hampshire and makes a life-affirming statement about
the lowly earthworm, “though in appearance a small and despicable link in
the chain of nature, yet, if lost, would make a lamentable chasm”.
Boston
Woolly thinking
Bartleby dismissed sheep as passive “followers” (May 18th). In truth, sheep
are highly attuned to the needs of the flock, move around together according
to weather and time, and become audibly distressed when one of them is lost
or in trouble. I lived for many years next to a field of sheep. Human societies
would be greatly improved if they learned to respect, and even imitate, the
animal’s communitarianism.
SYLVIA ROSE
Totnes, Devon
Bülach, Switzerland
This article was downloaded by zlibrary from https://www.economist.com/letters/2024/06/20/letters-to-the-editor
By Invitation
Ray Kurzweil on how AI will transform the physical world
Vladimir Putin’s war against Ukraine is part of his revolution against
the West
By Invitation | Artificial intelligence
After cheap, abundant solar energy, the next component is human labour,
which is often backbreaking and dangerous. AI is making big strides in
robotics that can greatly reduce labour costs. Robotics will also reduce raw-
material extraction costs, and AI is finding ways to replace expensive rare-
earth elements with common ones like zirconium, silicon and carbon-based
graphene. Together, this means that most kinds of goods will become
amazingly cheap and abundant.
This will ultimately replace today’s clinical trials, which are expensive,
risky, slow and statistically underpowered. Even in a phase-3 trial, there’s
probably not one single subject who matches you on every relevant factor of
genetics, lifestyle, comorbidities, drug interactions and disease variation.
Digital trials will let us tailor medicines to each individual patient. The
potential is breathtaking: to cure not just diseases like cancer and
Alzheimer’s, but the harmful effects of ageing itself.
Today, scientific progress gives the average American or Briton an extra six
to seven weeks of life expectancy each year. When AGI gives us full mastery
over cellular biology, these gains will sharply accelerate. Once annual
increases in life expectancy reach 12 months, we’ll achieve “longevity
escape velocity”. For people diligent about healthy habits and using new
therapies, I believe this will happen between 2029 and 2035—at which point
ageing will not increase their annual chance of dying. And thanks to
exponential price-performance improvement in computing, AI-driven
therapies that are expensive at first will quickly become widely available.
The Russian leader’s goal is not just to break Ukraine and stop its quest for a
place in the family of Western democracies, but to dismantle the American-
led security system that emerged after the second world war. In that sense
Mr Putin is fomenting a revolution: using the strategy and tactics of
revolution against the Western system. His war against Ukraine is
inextricably linked to the strategic objective of his revolution.
In the early 1990s Russia’s reformers judged that the country could be
competitive only by integrating itself into the global economy and stepping
away from confrontation with the West. The past 20 years of Mr Putin’s rule
have been characterised by two very different, concurrent patterns: the stage-
by-stage dismantling of democracy and freedoms inside Russia, and an
intensifying campaign to delegitimise the West, its democratic values and
the institutions that uphold them.
Inside Russia the results have been greater repression against the Russian
people, greater power for the security services, greater wealth for Kremlin-
connected business leaders and greater investment in the armed forces.
Outside Russia Mr Putin has increasingly pressured the America-led global
order; sought to undermine norms, principles, and rules of Western
institutions; organised regional and global opposition to the West; and
conducted military action in Georgia, Ukraine and Syria.
Mr Putin now asserts that the Western system poses an existential threat to
the sovereignty of Russia and the values it should hold. He speaks of two
sharply contrasting visions of the future: either the Western system continues
to exist and Russia is strategically defeated, or the Western system is
replaced and Russia continues to exist. He is convinced that Russia has
reached a historical crossroads in its post-Soviet development and that
dismantling the existing global order and building a new one is fundamental
to Russia’s greater-power aspirations. His revolutionary push is motivated
by both internal power-preservation aims and external power-expansion
aims.
His revolution values Russian advantage and gain of power over the West
more than coexistence, mutual security, crisis avoidance and stability with
the West. His security vision requires a Europe without NATO, and without
organisations that uphold the fundamental principles of freedom, democracy
and the rule of law. That vision also involves Russian co-operation with
other countries to curb American power in the Arctic, Euro-Atlantic and
Indo-Pacific regions.
His “all of Russia” revolution and war are now shaping how Russia is
organised, how society is mobilised, how industry is prioritised, how foreign
policy is aligned, how the army is structured and how communications are
conducted. His legitimacy as a leader of Russia—and his place in history—
are now inextricably tied to this revolution. He portrays himself as the only
leader who can guide Russia through this crossroads of history. Mr Putin’s
pursuit of advantage and power is unlikely to be replaced by caution in
pursuit of stability.
Neither his revolution nor his war is near its end. In Ukraine he is pursuing
several strategic actions simultaneously. By intensifying military operations
and attacking Ukraine’s infrastructure he hopes to weaken its defence,
demoralise its armed forces and create among the broader population a sense
of inevitable Russian victory. He is also seeking to divide Ukraine
politically. And he wants to damage the West’s will to continue supporting
Ukraine in the war.
The signs are that Mr Putin will continue to pursue this revolution-and-war
approach, further locking the country’s politics, economy and armed forces
into a structure that can only sustain revolution and war. It is unlikely that he
will stop the revolution, demobilise the armed forces, deconstruct the war
economy or re-embrace acceptance of the Western system. It is equally
unlikely that he will seek political, economic, conflict-resolution or arms
agreements with Western countries. This revolution and war will put
enormous stress on Russian society—a price that Mr Putin appears willing
to pay.
In late 2022, Mr Putin predicted that ahead lay “probably the most
dangerous, unpredictable and, at the same time, important decade since the
end of World War II”—a state of affairs that he said was “fraught with
global conflicts”. His destabilising, calculated revolution and war against
Ukraine—Mr Putin’s choices for Russia—could make his prediction a
reality. He is organising and preparing Russia for this future, not setting a
course to avoid it. ■
This article was downloaded by zlibrary from https://www.economist.com/by-invitation/2024/06/20/vladimir-putins-war-against-
ukraine-is-part-of-his-revolution-against-the-west
Briefing
How AI is changing warfare
Briefing | Model major-general
IN LATE 2021 the Royal Navy approached Microsoft and Amazon Web
Services, a pair of American tech giants, with a question: Was there a better
way to wage war? More specifically, could they find a more effective way to
co-ordinate between a hypothetical commando strike team in the Caribbean
and the missile systems of a frigate? The tech firms collaborated with BAE
Systems, a giant armsmaker, and Anduril, a smaller upstart, among other
military contractors. Within 12 weeks—unfathomably fast in the world of
defence procurement—the consortium gathered in Somerset in Britain for a
demonstration of what was dubbed StormCloud.
Marines on the ground, drones in the air and many other sensors were
connected over a “mesh” network of advanced radios that allowed each to
see, seamlessly, what was happening elsewhere—a set-up that had already
allowed the marines to run circles around much larger forces in previous
exercises. The data they collected were processed both on the “edge” of the
network, aboard small, rugged computers strapped to commando vehicles
with bungee cables—and on distant cloud servers, where they had been sent
by satellite. Command-and-control software monitored a designated area,
decided which drones should fly where, identified objects on the ground and
suggested which weapon to strike which target.
The results were impressive. It was apparent that StormCloud was the
“world’s most advanced kill chain”, says an officer involved in the
experiment, referring to a web of sensors (like drones) and weapons (like
missiles) knitted together with digital networks and software to make sense
of the data flowing to and fro. Even two years ago, he says, it was “miles
ahead”, in terms of speed and reliability, of human officers in a conventional
headquarters.
-enabled tools and weapons are not just being deployed in exercises. They
AI
are also in use on a growing scale in places like Gaza and Ukraine. Armed
forces spy remarkable opportunities. They also fear being left behind by
their adversaries. Spending is rising fast (see chart 1). But lawyers and
ethicists worry that AI will make war faster, more opaque and less humane.
The gap between the two groups is growing bigger, even as the prospect of a
war between great powers looms larger.
There is no single definition of AI. Things that would once have merited the
term, such as the terrain-matching navigation of Tomahawk missiles in the
1980s or the tank-spotting capabilities of Brimstone missiles in the early
2000s, are now seen as workaday software. And many cutting-edge
capabilities described as AI do not involve the sort of “deep learning” and
large language models underpinning services such as ChatGPT. But in various
guises, AI is trickling into every aspect of war.
At the other extreme is the sharp end of things. Both Russia and Ukraine
have been rushing to develop software to make drones capable of navigating
to and homing in on a target autonomously, even if jamming disrupts the
link between pilot and drone. Both sides typically use small chips for this
purpose, which can cost as little as $100. Videos of drone strikes in Ukraine
increasingly show “bounding boxes” appearing around objects, suggesting
that the drone is identifying and locking on to a target. The technology
remains immature, with the targeting algorithms confronting many of the
same problems faced by self-driving cars, such as cluttered environments
and obscured objects, and some unique to the battlefield, such as smoke and
decoys. But it is improving fast.
Between AI at the back-end and AI inside munitions lies a vast realm of
innovation, experimentation and technological advances. Drones, on their
own, are merely disrupting, rather than transforming, war, argue Clint
Hinote, a retired American air-force general, and Mick Ryan, a retired
Australian general. But when combined with “digitised command and
control systems” (think StormCloud) and “new-era meshed networks of
civilian and military sensors” the result, they say, is a “transformative
trinity” that allows soldiers on the front lines to see and act on real-time
information that would once have been confined to a distant headquarters.
AIis a prerequisite for this. Start with the mesh of sensors. Imagine data from
drones, satellites, social media and other sources sloshing around a military
network. There is too much to process manually. Tamir Hayman, a general
who led Israeli military intelligence until 2021, points to two big
breakthroughs. The “fundamental leap”, he says, eight or nine years ago,
was in speech-to-text software that enabled voice intercepts to be searched
for keywords. The other was in computer vision. Project Spotter, in Britain’s
defence ministry, is already using neural networks for the “automated
detection and identification of objects” in satellite images, allowing places to
be “automatically monitored 24/7 for changes in activity”. As of February, a
private company had labelled 25,000 objects to train the model.
Tom Copinger-Symes, a British general, told the House of Lords last year
that such systems were “still in the upper ends of research and development
rather than in full-scale deployment”, though he pointed to the use of
commercial tools to identify, for instance, clusters of civilians during
Britain’s evacuation of its citizens from Sudan in early 2023. America seems
further along. It began Project Maven in 2017 to deal with the deluge of
photos and videos taken by drones in Afghanistan and Iraq.
AIcan process more than phone calls or pictures. In March the Royal Navy
announced that its mine-hunting unit had completed a year of
experimentation in the Persian Gulf using a small self-driving boat, the
Harrier, whose towed sonar system could search for mines on the seabed and
alert other ships or units on land. And Michael Horowitz, a Pentagon
official, recently told Defense News, a website, that America, Australia and
Britain, as part of their AUKUS pact, had developed a “trilateral algorithm” that
could be used to process the acoustic data collected by sonobuoys dropped
from each country’s submarine-hunting P-8 aircraft.
London, would the software used by American spies and special forces in
the war on terror, which turned phone records and other data into huge
spidery charts that visualised the connections between people and places,
with the aim of identifying insurgents or terrorists.
ExplAIn or ordAIn?
What is different is that today’s software benefits from greater computing
power, whizzier algorithms (the breakthroughs in neural networks occurred
only in 2012) and more data, owing to the proliferation of sensors. The
result is not just more or better intelligence. It is a blurring of the line
between intelligence, surveillance and reconnaissance (ISR) and command and
control (C2)—between making sense of data and acting on it.
Consider Ukraine’s GIS Arta software, which collates data on Russian targets,
typically for artillery batteries. It can already generate lists of potential
targets “according to commander priorities”, write Generals Hinote and
Ryan. One of the reasons that Russian targeting in Ukraine has improved in
recent months, say officials, is that Russia’s C2 systems are getting better at
processing information from drones and sending it to guns. “By some
estimates,” writes Arthur Holland Michel in a paper for the International
Committee of the Red Cross (ICRC), a humanitarian organisation, “a target
search, recognition and analysis activity that previously took hours could be
reduced…to minutes.”
The US Air Force recently asked the RAND Corporation to assess whether AI tools
could provide options to a “space warfighter” dealing with an incoming
threat to a satellite. The conclusion was that AI could indeed recommend
“high-quality” responses. Similarly, DARPA, the Pentagon’s blue-sky research
arm, is working on a programme named, with tongue firmly in cheek, the
Strategic Chaos Engine for Planning, Tactics, Experimentation and
Resiliency (SCEPTER)—to produce recommended actions for commanders during
“military engagements at high machine speeds”. In essence, it can generate
novel war plans on the fly.
“A lot of the methods that are being employed” in SCEPTER and similar DARPA
projects “didn’t even exist two to five years ago”, says Eric Davis, a
programme manager at the agency. He points to the example of “Koopman
operator theory”, an old and obscure mathematical framework that can be
used to analyse complex and non-linear systems—like those encountered in
war—in terms of simpler linear algebra. Recent breakthroughs in applying it
have made a number of AI problems more tractable.
Advocates of military AI retort that the sceptics have an overly rosy view of
war. A strike drone hunting for a particular object might not be able to
recognise, let alone respect, an effort at surrender, acknowledges a former
British officer involved in policy on AI. But if the alternative is intense
shellfire, “There is no surrendering in that circumstance anyway.” Keith
Dear, a former officer in the Royal Air Force who now works for Fujitsu, a
Japanese firm, goes further. “If…machines produce a lower false positive
and false negative rate than humans, particularly under pressure, it would be
unethical not to delegate authority,” he argues. “We did various kinds of tests
where we compared the capabilities and the achievements of the machine
and compared to that of the human,” says the IDF’s General Hayman. “Most
tests reveal that the machine is far, far, far more accurate…in most cases it’s
no comparison.”
One fallacy involves extrapolating from the anti-terror campaigns of the
2000s. “The future’s not about facial recognition-ing a guy and shooting him
from 10,000 feet,” argues Palmer Luckey, the founder of Anduril, one of the
firms involved in StormCloud. “It’s about trying to shoot down a fleet of
amphibious landing craft in the Taiwan Strait.” If an object has the visual,
electronic and thermal signature of a missile launcher, he argues, “You just
can’t be wrong…it’s so incredibly unique.” Pre-war modelling further
reduces uncertainty: “99% of what you see happening in the China conflict
will have been run in a simulation multiple times,” Mr Luckey says, “long
before it ever happens.”
“The problem is when the machine does make mistakes, those are horrible
mistakes,” says General Hayman. “If accepted, they would lead to traumatic
events.” He therefore opposes taking the human “out of the loop” and
automating strikes. “It is really tempting,” he acknowledges. “You will
accelerate the procedure in an unprecedented manner. But you can breach
international law.” Mr Luckey concedes that AI will be least relevant in the
“dirty, messy, awful” job of Gaza-style urban warfare. “If people imagine
there’s going to be Terminator robots looking for the right Muhammad and
shooting him… that’s not how it’s going to work out.”
For its part, the ICRC warns that AI systems are potentially unpredictable,
opaque and subject to bias, but accepts they “can facilitate faster and broader
collection and analysis of available information…minimising risks for
civilians”. Much depends on how the tools are used. If the IDF employed
Lavender as reported, it suggests the problem was over-expansive rules of
engagement and lax operators, rather than any pathology of the software
itself.
For many years experts and diplomats have been wrangling at the United
Nations over whether to restrict or ban autonomous weapon systems (AWS).
But even defining them is difficult. The ICRC says AWS are those which choose a
target based on a general profile—any tank, say, rather than a specific tank.
That would include many of the drones being used in Ukraine. The ICRC
favours a ban on AWS which target people or behave unpredictably. Britain
retorts that “fully” autonomous weapons are those which identify, select and
attack targets without “context-appropriate human involvement”, a much
higher bar. The Pentagon takes a similar view, emphasising “appropriate
levels of human judgment”.
Defining that, in turn, is fiendishly hard. And it is not just to do with the
lethal act, but what comes before it. A highly autonomous attack drone may
seem to lack human control. But if its behaviour is well understood and it is
used in an area where there are known to be legitimate military targets and
no civilians, it might pose few problems. Conversely, a tool which merely
suggests targets may appear more benign. But commanders who manually
approve individual targets suggested by the tool “without cognitive clarity or
awareness”, as Article 36, an advocacy group, puts it—mindlessly pushing
the red button, in other words—have abdicated moral responsibility to a
machine.
The quandary is likely to worsen for two reasons. One is that AI begets AI. If
one army is using AI to locate and hit targets more rapidly, the other side may
be forced to turn to AI to keep up. That is already the case when it comes to
air-defence, where advanced software has been essential for tracking
approaching threats since the dawn of the computer age. The other reason is
that it will become harder for human users to grasp the behaviour and
limitations of military systems. Modern machine learning is not yet widely
used in “critical” decision-support systems, notes Mr Holland Michel. But it
will be. And those systems will undertake “less mathematically definable
tasks”, he notes, such as predicting the future intent of an adversary or even
his or her emotional state.
In practice, all these debates are being superseded by events. Neither Russia
nor Ukraine pays much heed to whether a drone is an “autonomous” weapon
system or merely an “automated” one. Their priority is to build weapons that
can evade jamming and destroy as much enemy armour as possible. False
positives are not a big concern for a Russian army that has bombed more
than 1,000 Ukrainian health facilities to date, nor for a Ukrainian army that
is fighting for its survival.
Hanging over this debate is also the spectre of a war involving great powers.
NATO countries know they might have to contend with a Russian army that
might, once this war ends, have extensive experience of building AI weapons
and testing them on the battlefield. China, too, is pursuing many of the same
technologies as America. Chinese firms make the vast majority of drones
sold in America, be it as consumer goods or for industrial purposes. The
Pentagon’s annual report on Chinese military power observes that in 2022
the People’s Liberation Army (PLA) began discussing “MultiDomain Precision
Warfare”: the use of “big data and artificial intelligence to rapidly identify
key vulnerabilities” in American military systems, such as satellites or
computer networks, which could then be attacked.
The question is who has the upper hand. American officials once fretted that
China’s lax privacy rules and control over the private sector would give the
PLA access to more and better data, which would result in superior algorithms
A PHOTOVOLTAIC CELL is a very simple thing: a square piece of silicon typically 182
millimetres on each side and about a fifth of a millimetre thick, with thin
wires on the front and an electrical contact on the back. Shine light on it, and
an electric potential—a voltage—will build up across the silicon: hence
“photovoltaic”, or PV. Run a circuit between the front and the back, and in
direct sunlight that potential can provide about seven watts of electric power.
This year the world will make something like 70bn of these solar cells, the
vast majority of them in China, and sandwich them between sheets of glass
to make what the industry calls modules but most other people call panels:
60 to 72 cells at a time, typically, for most of the modules which end up on
residential roofs, more for those destined for commercial plant. Those panels
will provide power to family homes, to local electricity collectives, to
specific industrial installations and to large electric grids; they will sit
unnoticed on roofs, charmingly outside rural schools, controversially across
pristine deserts, prosaically on the balconies of blocks of flats and in almost
every other setting imaginable.
Once in place they will sit there for decades, making no noise, emitting no
fumes, using no resources, costing almost nothing and generating power. It
is the least obtrusive revolution imaginable. But it is a revolution
nonetheless.
Over the course of 2023 the world’s solar cells, their panels currently
covering less than 10,000 square kilometres, produced about 1,600 terawatt-
hours of energy (a terawatt, or 1TW, is a trillion watts). That represented about
6% of the electricity generated world wide, and just over 1% of the world’s
primary-energy use. That last figure sounds fairly marginal, though rather
less so when you consider that the fossil fuels which provide most of the
world’s primary energy are much less efficient. More than half the primary
energy in coal and oil ends up as waste heat, rather than electricity or
forward motion.
What makes solar energy revolutionary is the rate of growth which brought
it to this just-beyond-the-marginal state. Michael Liebreich, a veteran analyst
of clean-energy technology and economics, puts it this way: in 2004, it took
the world a whole year to install a gigawatt of solar-power capacity (1GW is a
billion watts, or a thousandth of a terawatt); in 2010, it took a month; in
2016, a week. In 2023 there were single days which saw a gigawatt of
installation worldwide. Over the course of 2024 analysts at BloombergNEF, a
data outfit, expect to see 520-655GW of capacity installed: that’s up to two
2004s a day.
This extraordinary growth stems from the interplay of three simple factors.
When industries make more of something, they make it more cheaply. When
things get cheaper, demand for them grows. When demand grows, more is
made. In the case of solar power, demand was created and sustained by
subsidies early this century for long enough that falling prices became
noteworthy and, soon afterwards, predictable. The positive feedback that
drives exponential growth took off on a global scale.
And it shows no signs of stopping, or even slowing down. Buying and
installing solar panels is currently the largest single category of investment
in electricity generation, according to the International Energy Agency (IEA),
an intergovernmental think-tank: it expects $500bn this year, not far short of
the sum being put into upstream oil and gas. Installed capacity is doubling
every three years. According to the International Solar Energy Society, solar
power is on track to generate more electricity than all the world’s nuclear
power plants in 2026, than its wind turbines in 2027, than its dams in 2028,
its gas-fired power plants in 2030 and its coal-fired ones in 2032. In an IEA
scenario which provides net-zero carbon-dioxide emissions by the middle of
the century, solar energy becomes humankind’s largest source of primary
energy—not just electricity—by the 2040s.
All real issues. But the past 20 years of solar growth have seen naive
extrapolations trounce forecasting soberly informed by such concerns again
and again. In 2009, when installed solar capacity worldwide was 23GW, the
energy experts at the IEA predicted that in the 20 years to 2030 it would
increase to 244GW. It hit that milestone in 2016, when only six of the 20 years
had passed. According to Nat Bullard, an energy analyst, over most of the
2010s actual solar installations typically beat the IEA’s five-year forecasts by
235% (see chart). The people who have come closest to predicting what has
actually happened have been environmentalists poo-pooed for zealotry and
economic illiteracy, such as those at Greenpeace who, also in 2009,
predicted 921GW of solar capacity by 2030. Yet even that was an
underestimate. The world’s solar capacity hit 1,419GW last year.
This performance suggests that solar is not like other energy sources.
History shows the same thing. From 1800 to 2020 the amount of energy the
world derived from coal increased by roughly a factor of 400. But as Dr Way
and his colleagues point out, when adjusted for inflation coal’s cost in terms
of its energy content stayed more or less the same. The same is true for the
long-term costs of oil and, later, natural gas. Exploiting these fuels drove lots
of economic growth; that made the fuels more affordable, their use more
valuable and the returns on their production greater. But their costs stayed
broadly stable in real terms.
Since the 1960s what analysts call the levelised cost of solar energy—the
break-even price a project needs to get paid in order to recoup its financing
for a fixed rate of return—has dropped by a factor of more than 1,000, and
the trend is continuing. Now that solar energy is a significant part of the
world’s entire energy portfolio, the world as a whole is going to go on seeing
the energy used in many applications getting cheaper and cheaper. A burst of
innovation aimed at making the most of this bonanza will change the way
many existing industries work and create new ones more or less from
scratch. It will be the steepest drop in the price of one of the basic factors of
production that the world economy has ever seen.
THE CYLINDERS for the first steam engines that Matthew Boulton and James Watt
began to sell in the 1770s were not made in-house at Boulton’s Soho
manufactory, outside Birmingham; they were cast at the nearby foundry of
John “Iron Mad” Wilkinson. But the manufactory provided the fittings that
turned those cylinders into engines, supervised the engines’ building and
owned the patent on their design. As Boulton explained to James Boswell, a
writer, when he visited the Soho works, “I sell here, Sir, what all the world
desires to have—power.”
The silicon foundries of China lack salesmen with Boulton’s verve (“an iron
chieftain…father to his tribe,” as Boswell put it). But when it comes to
exquisite chemical purity and physical flawlessness, the wares they provide
to serve the world’s desire for power should be enough to make anyone
silicon mad.
Until the beginning of this century the only products that were worth this
sort of palaver were the wafers from which the computer industry made its
silicon chips. The solar-cell industry lived on the offcuts. But the subsidies
of the mid-2000s saw demand for photovoltaics rise beyond what the
computer industry could spare. As the price of polysilicon rose, firms in
Asia started to make the investments needed to build polysilicon foundries
for supplying the PV industry.
China quickly took the lead, and kept it. In 2023 Chinese firms made 93% of
all the world’s polysilicon destined for solar cells. Some are vertically
integrated and make photovoltaics themselves (an approach Boulton took
when he invested in a foundry of his own at Soho). Some leave the
diamond-saw slicing of their ingots into wafers, the precise polishing of their
surfaces and the perfectly calibrated “doping” that makes the silicon into a
semiconductor to their customers.
That said, the manufacturers benefit from the fact that they are key to their
country’s industrial strategy. There have been some bankruptcies, but the
Chinese government has extended cheap loans to many overextended firms.
Gregory Nemet of the University of Wisconsin-Madison notes that the solar-
cell market typically catches up with the overcapacity thus created within a
couple of years. The current oversupply will see whether this remains the
case. China’s two biggest producers of polysilicon, GCL-Poly and Tongwei,
each had a production capacity of 370,000 tonnes in 2023, more than enough
to meet demand. Tongwei has said it is investing some $3.9bn in a new
facility that will eventually be able to produce 400,000 tonnes a year.
Johannes Bernreuter, an analyst of the polysilicon market, says China has
facilities capable of 7m tonnes a year in the pipeline, enough to produce an
annual 3.5TW of solar panels.
In terms of polysilicon such amounts are seen as huge. But it is worth noting
that in terms of the material requirements of other energy technologies they
are tiny. Coal production runs at roughly 8bn tonnes a year; add on oil and
gas and you double that.
Chinese firms have other advantages, notably a vast and protected domestic
market and low-cost energy. GCL-Poly and other Chinese firms have several
factories in Xinjiang near huge coal-fired power plants which themselves sit
more or less on top of large coal mines. Electricity accounts for 40% of the
cost of polysilicon production, and burning coal that was mined next door in
a depreciated plant that delivers power to your arc furnaces directly is pretty
cheap. That said, before too long solar power could be cheaper.
In PVs, though, there is no such enduring edge to be found. Solar cells are
standardised products all made in basically the same way; they have no
moving parts at all, let alone the fiendish complexity of a modern turbine.
Manufacturers compete on cost, by either making cells that make
fractionally more electricity out of a given amount of sunshine or which cost
less. “The barriers to entry are capex,” says Jenny Chase, who analyses the
industry at BloombergNEF. “You can buy the machines [needed for
manufacture], it’s not super tech-intensive.”
The commoditised nature of the product does not just lead to relentless
competition on the supply side. It also provides incredibly diverse and deep
demand. Heymi Bahar of the IEA sees this as perhaps the technology’s biggest
advantage. What is revolutionary about solar, he says, is that it “is addressed
to all kinds of investors”. From the teacher in South Africa who buys a $2
charger for her phone to the company developing 10GW power plants,
everyone who uses solar is buying basically the same product. “There is no
other energy-generation tech where you install 1m or one of the same thing
depending on your application,” says Rob Carlson, a technology investor; as
he puts it in a white paper, “The Sun has won”.
The key to the way this demand grows is to be found in the industry’s
“experience curve”. The degree to which processes get cheaper as
production gets larger is frequently expressed in terms of the extent to which
unit costs come down every time cumulative production doubles. From the
mid-1970s to the early 2020s cumulative shipments of photovoltaics
increased by a factor of a million, which is 20 doublings. At the same time
prices dropped by a factor of 500. That is a 27% decrease in costs for each
doubling of installed capacity, which means a halving of costs every time
installed capacity increases by 360%. If you treat the late 2000s, when
subsidies led to the creation of foundries producing polysilicon specifically
for solar cells, as an inflection point, the rate is now over 40%.
THE GREEN members of the German coalition which kicked off the huge demand-
establishing subsidies of the early 2000s liked the decentralisation they
offered; the Social Democrats liked the prospect of developing a new
manufacturing industry devoted to their production. Both sides also saw
solar panels as weapons in the fight to decarbonise the economy—but not
necessarily as particularly powerful ones. They offered a sort of greenness
that only really worked if people radically reduced their consumption.
It took those leading the decarbonisation charge some time to appreciate that
solar could in principle be much more than this. When Adair Turner, a
grandee technocrat, became the first chair of Britain’s Climate Change
Committee, an organisation mandated by parliament to lay out the path to
net-zero emissions, solar was not a large part of its thinking. “We totally
failed to see that solar would come down so much,” he says. “In 2008 we
were thinking that capital costs would come down 19% by 2020. When we
got to 2020 they were down 95%.” In the 2014 report which set the agenda
for the Paris agreement of 2015, the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate
Change placed far more emphasis on carbon-capture at fossil-fuel plants and
on burning biomass than it did on photovoltaics.
Since then, though, solar has proved the stand-out of the pack. In 2015
BloombergNEF estimated that the levelised cost of electricity (LCOE) for solar, on
a global basis, was $122 per MWh, almost half as high again as the LCOE for
onshore wind, then $83. The LCOE for coal in places without carbon prices at
the time was $50-$75. Today both solar and onshore wind are in the low
$40s, while coal remains much where it was.
Not only have solar panels been getting cheaper more quickly than wind
power, they have done so while staying comparatively unobtrusive. For
wind, more efficiency means putting bigger turbines higher into the sky on
more massive pylons. Their two-dimensionality allows solar panels to be a
lot less visible from a distance (and also very easy to ship; you can get 300
into a standard TEU freight container). Though covering tracts of arable
countryside with them upsets some people in some places, by and large solar
panels are popular: research finds they enjoy more “social licence” than any
other form of energy generation, be it renewable, fossil-fuel or nuclear.
This becomes terribly inconvenient when very low-cost power from solar (or
wind) becomes a large factor in electricity supply. When there is a lot of
solar power on a grid the price of electricity in the middle of the day can fall
to zero, or below. Solar-rich grids in Spain, Portugal, Germany, France,
California and Texas have all experienced negative wholesale power prices
in recent months. Eventually all markets which install plentiful solar can
expect something similar, which makes the potential profits of further solar
investment in such markets seem limited.
But there are ways around those limits. They include long-distance
connections; storage (especially batteries); increasing overall demand; and
the innovation low prices always encourage.
Batteries and other storage technologies allow arbitrage across time rather
than space; energy generated at midday, when grid prices are low, can be
sold back when the Sun sets and prices are higher. What is more, batteries,
like solar cells, are mass producible and targets of Chinese industrial policy.
As a result they are moving down an experience curve even steeper than
solar’s. The Rocky Mountain Institute, a think-tank, calculates that the cost
of a kilowatt-hour of battery storage has fallen by 99% over the past 30
years.
By providing an investment case for new solar in markets that are already
seeing zero prices, batteries increase demand for panels. Take California. It
first saw sunshine-driven negative prices on the grid in 2017, when it had
about 19GW of solar installed. It has more than doubled its solar capacity since
then in part because it now has 10GW of battery storage; there have been
evenings recently when batteries have been the largest source of power on
its grid. Things are moving even faster in Texas, where battery operators had
revenues of $532m in 2023.
The company plans to use solar farms in places that have little to
recommend them other than a railway line nearby as filling stations at which
to charge heavy but cheap batteries built into goods wagons. A 100-car train
similar to the ones that currently carry coal east from Wisconsin could
deliver 3 gigawatt-hours to users. Dr Carlson describes a utility-boss’s jaw
hitting the floor when he proposed that, instead of a multi-decade planning
battle to build a high-voltage transmission line, SunTrain could meet the
utility’s power-import needs with a couple of trains a day.
Adani Green Energy, one of the world’s largest solar developers, has
obtained the rights to build solar farms on two vast tracts of land in India,
one in Gujarat, near the border with Pakistan, the other in Rajasthan. Each of
them is large enough to take some 30GW of solar panels, says Sagar Adani, the
company’s boss and the nephew of the larger Adani Group’s founder,
Gautam Adani. At that size they would offer a capacity more than two-thirds
as large as that which Germany has installed over the past 25 years; and
because India has much more sunshine, they will produce more energy in a
given year than all those German cells put together. Mr Adani says the firm
is installing about 5GW of solar on this land every year.
This means that, for the time being, solar power’s growth in sub-Saharan
Africa will be more off-grid than in other regions. Off-grid, its competition
is mostly diesel power, which is much more expensive. Solar with batteries
should be able to replace a lot of diesel generators and reduce the market for
new ones very quickly.
Africa currently has the lowest electricity use per person of any continent;
600m people in sub-Saharan Africa enjoy no access to electricity at all. For
the continent’s average electricity use per person to rise to the level of
India’s, which is more than twice as high, would require 2TW of new solar.
Ten years ago that would have been unthinkable. At today’s prices it is
beginning to look plausible. In ten years time, it should be well on its way to
being done, and ambitions will have increased. And so demand will grow,
and cumulative capacity will grow, and prices will fall.
William Jevons pointed out that when energy gets cheaper people use more
of it
What if, instead, you produce an electrolyser with no bells and whistles that
uses 60% more electricity to produce a unit of hydrogen but requires much
less capex. And then you site it right next to the simplest sort of solar system
imaginable—one which provides power in the direct-current (DC) form that
photovoltaics produce and electrolysers use, and thus does not need the
inverters most systems use to put electric power onto the grid in the form of
alternating current (AC). You may need much more electricity to produce a
unit of hydrogen than fancy-electrolyser systems do. But with very cheap
electricity and huge savings on capital expenditure you can still come out
ahead.
Once you start to think in terms of energy being really copious and all-but
free, at least at some times and in some places, brute-force approaches to all
sorts of problems begin to appear. One way to drastically reduce the spread
of airborne disease is to speed up the rate at which the air in the world’s
buildings is vented and refreshed. If energy is expensive this is not feasible.
But what if…? One way to remove carbon dioxide from the atmosphere is to
grind certain sorts of rock into fine dust that is then dispersed across the
oceans. Given that this needs to be done at a scale of billions of tonnes a
year, again the energy requirement is incredible. And again, what if…?
Energy is not the only expense; any given scheme along these lines could
fail. But that human ingenuity finds useful things to do with better access to
energy is one of the clearest messages of the past 200 years. If real energy
costs drop dramatically across the global economy, and access to energy
expands, to bet against great things is to bet against the innovative engines
of capitalism. It is not a wager history encourages. ■
This article was downloaded by zlibrary from https://www.economist.com/interactive/essay/2024/06/20/solar-power-is-going-to-be-
huge
United States
Republicans are favoured to win the Senate. What would they do?
Are America’s leading presidential candidates up to it?
America is educating a nation of investors
Lauren Boebert’s primary is a window into everyday Trumpism
New research exposes the role of women in America’s slave trade
Legal immigration to America has rebounded
Donald Trump has finally got it right about the January 6th
insurrectionists
United States | Preparing for a takeover
Donald Trump’s visit to Capitol Hill on June 13th served as a reminder that
—whatever the candidate promises—Congress will have a critical role in
shaping policy if he returns to the White House. Although Republicans
largely support their presumptive nominee and his programme, the finer
points of a potential second-term agenda remain up for debate.
Rate cuts for individuals and estates, along with several changes for
business, will lapse by the end of 2025. Some 60% of American households
would then send bigger cheques to the taxman each year. Simply extending
the law would increase the deficit by around $4trn over the next ten years,
according to the Joint Committee on Taxation. The seemingly impossible
task is to deliver a politically viable bill that encourages growth without
expanding America’s already massive deficit, which exceeded 6% of GDP in
2023.
A relatively young but growing faction emphasises support for workers. Jim
Banks, a congressman expected to win Indiana’s Senate race this year, has
expressed dissatisfaction that the corporate-rate cut was permanent whereas
reductions for individuals were not. And Marco Rubio, a Republican senator
from Florida and long-time child-tax-credit advocate, says: “Allowing
families to keep more of their hard-earned money is not only fair, but
absolutely essential to helping them recover from the Biden years.” Jason
Smith, chairman of the House Ways and Means Committee, said in May that
“very well-known conservative” Republicans are even open to increasing
the corporate rate.
The fiscal question could affect another priority, defence spending. John
Kennedy, a Republican senator from Louisiana, sees these as inextricably
linked. On the one hand, America must deal with “authoritarians throughout
the world who want to kill us and drink our blood out of a boot”. On the
other, “You’re trying to control your debt, grow your economy and pay for
an older population.” He says reducing wasteful spending is essential.
The judicial stakes help explain the most notable development from Mr
Trump’s visit to the Capitol on June 13th: the former president burying the
hatchet with Mr McConnell after years of acrimony. (At the moment the
race to succeed Mr McConnell as the Republicans’ leader in the Senate
seems a toss-up between John Thune of South Dakota and John Cornyn of
Texas, although if Mr Trump were to throw his weight behind an alternative,
such as Steve Daines of Montana, that could prove decisive.)
All three of Mr Trump’s first-term Supreme Court picks are under 60.
Clarence Thomas and Samuel Alito, who would be in their late 70s by the
end of a second Trump term, could retire. No one knows what America’s tax
system or defence budget will look like in 20 years. But anyone wondering
why Republicans stick by Mr Trump through everything need only
remember that, if he wins, a majority of Supreme Court justices could be
Trump appointees well into the 2040s.■
This article was downloaded by zlibrary from https://www.economist.com/united-states/2024/06/17/republicans-are-favoured-to-win-
the-senate-what-would-they-do
United States | Freezing time
“I really hate doing this, but I cannot not do it,” announced the conservative
host Hugh Hewitt on his online show. This was a preface to a montage of
video clips showing “President Biden’s obvious and increasing infirmity”.
Stay up to date with our new daily update, The US in brief, and our
presidential poll tracker.
Selective editing of the clips makes them look more devastating than they
are. A longer recording of the Los Angeles episode shows Mr Biden waving
to one side of the audience and clapping before turning and standing still for
about seven seconds—possibly to try to hear what was being shouted (Mr
Obama intervened before anything more awkward could occur). A fuller clip
of the Italian incident shows that Mr Biden did not wander off into the
distance but rather to greet a skydiver who had landed off-screen (though
Giorgia Meloni, the Italian prime minister, similarly intervened to bring him
to centre stage).
The fracas gives a preview for what the next five months of campaigning
will look like. Donald Trump and his allies will relentlessly scrutinise the
president’s public appearances for signs of senility and distribute clips
purportedly showing this (there is little need for AI-generated disinformation
when simple editing tools do so well). Mr Biden’s campaign will be anxious
not to give them too much material to work with, reinforcing a bunker
mentality.
Democrats are right about the difference in standards. Such utterances are
barely news stories for Mr Trump; Democrats might forcibly commit Mr
Biden to an elder-care facility for a monologue like that. Yet the difference
in standards is the point. Mr Biden’s pitch is competent, rational leadership,
whereas Mr Trump has been a surrealist from the start.
Mr Trump is sure that he has the cognitive advantage. His campaign has
pushed for holding multiple debates, on the theory that Mr Biden would not
be able to keep up either rhetorically or physically. While president, Mr
Trump memorably bragged about his high marks on a mental-acuity test
(meant as a diagnostic tool for early dementia, not admission to MENSA).
Speaking in Detroit this week, Mr Trump challenged Mr Biden to take the
same test he had “aced”. While issuing the blustery challenge, Mr Trump got
confused about the name of the White House physician who administered it
to him: he was Ronny Jackson, not “Ronny Johnson”. ■
This article was downloaded by zlibrary from https://www.economist.com/united-states/2024/06/20/are-americas-leading-
presidential-candidates-up-to-it
United States | School of stocks
Pupils in these classes learn not only how to buy and sell shares, but how to
save their earnings in order to have something to invest in the first place.
Courses teach how to properly bank, budget, manage credit and pay for
college. They cover comparison shopping and the basics of how to plan and
track daily expenses. (“I save all my money and spend my parents’ money!”
one future hedge-fund manager said.)
Young people badly need these courses. According to the Programme for
International Student Assessment, an international survey, only 10% of 15-
year-olds in the OECD, a club of mostly rich countries, score highly on
financial-literacy assessments. Are personal-finance courses the answer? For
a long time, the research said no. Many studies, including a meta-analysis
from 2014 that was cited over 2,500 times, claimed that financial-literacy
courses were ineffective. The finding made intuitive sense; many teenagers
have yet to work or manage a household.
But more recent findings have changed the picture. “Research has gotten
better,” explains Carly Urban, an economics professor at Montana State
University. The courses themselves have also improved. Studies that use the
gold standard of investigation—a randomised controlled trial—have found
that the courses are effective in improving financial knowledge and
behaviour. A meta-analysis of 76 randomised experiments in 33 countries
found that people who take these courses learn the content, save more and
budget better.
Other studies have found that pupils who take personal-finance courses in
high school borrow less money. If they do borrow for college, they choose
low-cost options. And low-income borrowers exposed to personal-finance
coursework are more likely to pay down their balances and steer clear of
exploitative, high-interest pay-day loans. They are also less likely to have
credit-card debt, and they have higher credit scores and fewer defaults.
“When I was 20, it would have been nice to have this class,” Ms Varga says
after the pupils she was educating about the S&P 500 have gone to lunch. She
got into some financial trouble as a young adult before she learned the
subjects she now teaches and improved her own money management. “I
want them to be better than my generation.” ■
Stay on top of American politics with The US in brief, our daily newsletter with
fast analysis of the most important electoral stories, and Checks and
Balance, a weekly note from our Lexington columnist that examines the state
of American democracy and the issues that matter to voters.
This article was downloaded by zlibrary from https://www.economist.com/united-states/2024/06/20/america-is-educating-a-nation-
of-investors
United States | On the trail in Colorado
Stay up to date with our new daily update, The US in brief, and our
presidential poll tracker.
They didn’t know how bad it was. That was how James Redpath, a northern
journalist who toured the South in the 1850s, explained white southern
women’s support for slavery to his readers. He reckoned that women were
shielded from the “most obnoxious features” of the trade—rarely witnessing
the auctions and the lashes doled out as punishments on plantations—and
were oblivious to the “gigantic commerce” that it had become. Over time
historians came to agree that slavery was the business of men.
These are the first hard numbers building on a growing body of qualitative
work by Stephanie Jones-Rogers, a historian at the University of California,
Berkeley, showing just how instrumental women were to the slave economy.
In the travel logs of foreigners she uncovered descriptions of southern belles
bidding at the slave markets dressed in their finest silks and “glittering in
precious jewels”. And in interviews conducted by the federal government in
the 1930s she found that former slaves frequently reported belonging to the
“mistis” and told stories of being beaten by her with stinging nettles or
coming home to find their child missing and the mistress counting a “heap
of bills”.
For the ladies of the antebellum South, slavery was more than business—it
was their ticket to economic freedom. Coverture laws compelled women to
relinquish property and money to men when they married, but exceptions
were made for slaves. As with furniture and clothing, a bride could hold on
to the humans she owned and take them with her to her new husband’s
estate. Fathers hoping to secure their daughters’ futures gave them slaves at
baptisms, birthdays and engagements.
On the eve of the civil war Southern women came to understand that the
Union army threatened to strip them not just of their material wealth but of
their independence. As men went off to battle and Congress passed the
Confiscation Acts of the early 1860s, which authorised the government to
seize slaves, women panicked. Before the war, half of the South’s wealth
was in slaves. The fall of the Confederacy left many Southerners destitute.
Freed slaves later recounted giving their former mistresses grits and potatoes
to subsist on after emancipation.
It would be decades before the women of the South gained the right to
control their earnings, own property, take custody of their children and vote.
Ms Jones-Rogers contends that their fight for segregation into the 20th
century was fuelled by the sense of power they had known and lost. In the
subjugation of others they had tasted freedom.■
Stay on top of American politics with The US in brief, our daily newsletter with
fast analysis of the most important electoral stories, and Checks and
Balance, a weekly note from our Lexington columnist that examines the state
of American democracy and the issues that matter to voters.
This article was downloaded by zlibrary from https://www.economist.com/united-states/2024/06/18/new-research-exposes-the-role-
of-women-in-americas-slave-trade
United States | Beyond the border
Liberty’s lure
Legal migration took time to recover: consulates reopened slowly, and visa
backlogs were huge. But in 2024 it has returned to pre-pandemic, and indeed
pre-Trump, levels. Nearly 1.2m green cards were issued in the fiscal year of
2023, a 68% increase from 2020 and slightly more than the number doled
out during Mr Trump’s first year in office. The government is projected to
resettle at least 90,000 refugees in 2024, potentially short of Mr Biden’s
125,000 allotment but far more than the 11,000 or so settled during the
doldrums of the pandemic.
Non-immigrant visas, the kind that temporary workers and students get,
have also made a comeback. This is good news for firms wanting to hire
skilled workers. The H-1B lottery system, which allots visas to high-skilled,
mostly tech, workers, was rife with fraud. Hundreds of thousands of
applicants compete for just 85,000 spots, a number set by Congress in 2004.
Sometimes dozens of applications were submitted on behalf of one person.
A tweak to the lottery system is intended to fix that.
Although more students are again coming to study in America, more than
ever are also being denied visas. The same factors encouraging border
crossings—a hot labour market, violence and instability at home, and a more
welcoming president—may also be pushing young people abroad to seek
their education in America. Cecilia Esterline of the Niskanen Centre, a
think-tank, suggests that students may be failing to convince consulates that
they will return to their home country after studying.
What has all this meant for the workforce? At its peak in 2021, the shortfall
of foreign-born workers identified by Mr Peri and Ms Zaiour reached about
2m people. That hole has now disappeared, partly due to the number of
people who streamed across the border and found work. But Mr Peri reckons
the rebound has also been fuelled in part by the return of college-educated
legal migrants. Some 45% of recent immigrants have a college degree,
compared with 38% of native-born Americans and 33% of those who
arrived in the 1990s.
One thing that has not changed is the immigration system itself. Congress
has repeatedly failed to create new legal pathways for migrants, to increase
caps for limited visas and to make the system more responsive to the needs
of America’s economy. The result is a monumental backlog for green cards,
long waiting times at consulates, frustrated families who worry they will
never be reunited, and irritated businesses and states eager for more labour.
The process is next to impossible, says Mr Bier. “There are the people who
are screwed, people who are really screwed, and then the people who are
just going to die before they get a chance to come,” he adds, bleakly.
Americans do not share Congress’s allergy to reform. They increasingly
support more deportations and the border wall, but the desire for stricter
enforcement has not yet shaken their approval of immigration overall. A
majority of Democrats and a plurality of Republicans support more legal
pathways. Some 61% of registered voters surveyed by Pew in April maintain
that America’s openness to people from elsewhere is essential to its national
character. But in an election year, with the black hole sucking up so much
attention, reform of the legal system is unthinkable. ■
Stay on top of American politics with The US in brief, our daily newsletter with
fast analysis of the most important electoral stories, and Checks and
Balance, a weekly note from our Lexington columnist that examines the state
of American democracy and the issues that matter to voters.
This article was downloaded by zlibrary from https://www.economist.com/united-states/2024/06/18/legal-immigration-to-america-
has-rebounded
United States | Lexington
Here is a thought experiment. Try to put politics and the presidential race out
of your mind and give Donald Trump the benefit of the doubt about the
attack on the Capitol on January 6th 2021. Accept that he believed the
election was stolen and that he meant it when he told the crowd that day to
march from the White House to Capitol Hill “peacefully and patriotically”.
Accept that he believed none of his supporters was carrying weapons or
intended violence of any sort. Accept that he has since come to conclude, as
he has claimed, that Nancy Pelosi, then the speaker of the House, somehow
“caused” the violence, that the police “ushered in” the crowd, that they were
“a loving crowd”, indeed, “patriots” who have since become not just
“victims” but even “hostages” of a weaponised system of justice.
Then ask yourself this: after embracing all of those assumptions and
assertions, why would you celebrate the rioters as “warriors”, as Mr Trump
did during a rally earlier this month?
To call them warriors is not simply to insist their cause was just and that
they were somehow tricked into entering the Capitol with the guns, bats,
knives and other weapons that Mr Trump once maintained they did not have;
it is not just to ignore or minimise the violence that day, which resulted in
five deaths; it is not even to shift the blame for that violence to others,
whether police officers (some 140 of whom were assaulted), or Ms Pelosi
(whom the rioters were hunting, and who can be seen on video from that day
urging Mr Trump’s acting secretary of defence to dispatch troops to the
Capitol). It is instead to praise the people who attacked the Capitol precisely
—definitionally—for their capacity to wage war. That is to move the
understanding of what happened on January 6th, at least for Mr Trump’s
supporters, onto new and even darker ground.
There was a moment, back in the mists of 2021, when just about everyone in
the mainstream of American politics recoiled in shock from the mayhem of
January 6th. They agreed that attacking the Capitol was wrong, and that Mr
Trump, to some degree, was responsible. Even Mr Trump said so, the leader
of the House Republicans, Kevin McCarthy, told colleagues at the time,
according to the exacting report delivered in 2022 by the House select
committee that investigated the attack. That was briefly Mr McCarthy’s
view, too, as it was that of Mitch McConnell, the Senate Republican leader,
who called Mr Trump “practically and morally responsible for provoking the
events of that day”. During her campaign for the Republican presidential
nomination this spring, Nikki Haley called January 6th a “terrible day” and
said Mr Trump “will have to answer for it”.
But the times when Republican leaders would say they wanted Mr Trump
held accountable for the riot appear to be over. A few days after Mr Trump
praised the “J6 warriors”, Mr McConnell joined other Republican legislators
in welcoming the former president back on Capitol Hill for the first time
since the attack, for a meeting Mr McConnell called “entirely positive”. And
yet even as they absolve Mr Trump of responsibility, other Republican
politicians at least still seem to see attacking the Capitol as a bad thing to do.
“No real Republican with any credibility in the party is still blaming him”
for January 6th, Senator J.D. Vance of Ohio told reporters. That construction
implies the conduct of the crowd was blameworthy. By contrast, Mr Trump
is valorising it.
Mr Trump faces federal charges over his efforts to overturn the last election,
but that case is on hold. Meanwhile, the exhaustive work of the January 6th
committee somehow already smells of mothballs and reads like the relic of a
different era, back before polarisation had done its work of rallying
Republicans to Mr Trump. Based on sworn testimony from witnesses who
were almost all Republicans, the committee showed that Mr Trump ignored
repeated assurances from top aides that he had lost legitimately and instead
trumpeted lies about electoral fraud; ignored warnings that the crowd he
summoned to Washington was primed for violence; used that word
“peacefully” just once, as scripted by his speechwriters, but ad-libbed the
word “fight” 18 times; and then sat on his hands for more than three hours as
staff and family members implored him to call a halt to the riot.
Stay on top of American politics with The US in brief, our daily newsletter with
fast analysis of the most important electoral stories, and Checks and
Balance, a weekly note from our Lexington columnist that examines the state
of American democracy and the issues that matter to voters.
This article was downloaded by zlibrary from https://www.economist.com/united-states/2024/06/20/donald-trump-has-finally-got-it-
right-about-the-january-6th-insurrectionists
The Americas
Javier Milei has turned Argentina into a libertarian laboratory
The Americas | No pain, no gain
Javier Milei, Argentina’s president, has enjoyed the best week of his term.
At dawn on June 13th the Senate passed two bills aiming to boost growth
and raise revenue, giving Mr Milei his first legislative victory since he came
to power in December. Hours later he travelled to the G7 in Italy, where he
giggled with Giorgia Meloni, the prime minister, embraced Pope Francis and
palled around with Kristalina Georgieva, the head of the IMF. “I always love
our meetings,” he gushed to Ms Georgieva. Yet the relationship between Mr
Milei and the fund, which has a $44bn lending programme with Argentina,
may soon become less chummy. Uncertainty about the president’s plans for
the central bank is worrying investors and the IMF alike.
Mr Milei’s early successes are impressive given the mess he inherited. For
years, the central bank had created money to finance the fiscal deficit,
fuelling inflation. It also had no foreign reserves. Another default seemed
almost inevitable.
Some Argentines are angered by the accompanying pain. The night the
Senate voted on the reforms, protesters hurled Molotov cocktails outside and
set a car alight. Unions have organised huge marches. Yet despite the
excruciating recession, over half of Argentines still approve of Mr Milei.
Jorge Juliano, a 72-year-old taxi driver in Buenos Aires, gives a simple
reason: “With the other lot we were living in Walt Disney, a fantasy.”
Opposition legislators may think they have given Mr Milei enough. “It’s
going to be more and more complicated,” says Luis Juez, a senator who
supported the reforms. The lower house is already fighting back. It recently
passed a pension formula that could cost almost 0.5% of GDP this year. Mr
Milei attacked those who voted for it as “fiscal degenerates” and vowed to
veto it. But if it is passed with a two-thirds majority in both houses—a
distinct possibility—he will be unable to change it.
The effects are obvious from atop the Andes. On a single long weekend in
April some 40,000 Argentines crossed the mountains into Chile to buy
everything from trainers to car tyres because, surreally, Chile has become
cheaper than Argentina. Mr Milei slams those who say the peso is
overvalued as “intellectually dishonest”. Yet when an Argentine president
says there won’t be a devaluation, taxi drivers know there is a good chance
there will be one, quips Nicolás Gadano of Empiria Consulting in Buenos
Aires.
A pricey peso scares off tourists, makes exports expensive and deters
investors. An overvalued currency often eventually crashes. “If you see
Argentina appreciating, this is always a sign of worse things to come,” says
Eduardo Levy Yeyati of Torcuato Di Tella University in Buenos Aires.
Falling exports make it harder for the central bank to accumulate dollars,
which it needs to pay off foreign debts and to build up its safety buffers.
The government could allow the peso to float or accelerate the 2% crawling
peg. But either would probably push up inflation, thus endangering Mr
Milei’s popularity and undermining some of the benefits of the devaluation.
For now, Mr Milei is able to keep a tight grip on the exchange rate because
of capital controls.
Money madness
What happens next? Mr Milei has promised to ultimately remove capital
controls as part of his plan to restore investor confidence. He insists that
inflation will soon be 2% a month, the same as the rate of devaluation. This,
he says, would allow him to slowly ease the restrictions and float the peso
without its value plunging.
Looming over all this is a thornier issue: what to do with the central bank
and the peso. Mr Milei campaigned on a promise to blow up the former and
scrap the latter, declaring that the local currency “is not worth crap”. These
days his team prefers to talk about currency competition, in which dollars
and pesos would both be legal tender. But no one knows the details of the
plan or the monetary programme to stabilise the peso that would go with it.
“Further work is needed in defining some of the key underpinnings,” the IMF
diplomatically concluded on June 17th.
Mr Milei, though not his economic team, seems particularly enthusiastic
about a scheme he calls “endogenous dollarisation”. This would involve
fixing the supply of pesos. When the economy grows, and more cash is
needed, Mr Milei expects Argentines to use their own dollar savings for
transactions. “The peso will become like a museum piece,” he said in mid-
May. He would then close the central bank.
The IMF seems worried. If Argentines believe the peso will end up in a
museum, its supply could outstrip demand, stoking inflation. It is also
unclear what would happen to the peso-denominated financial system. The
IMF instead enthuses about currency competition. Peru has such a system, with
the sol and dollars both used. If Mr Milei insists on his scheme, it would
surely be harder for his government to get new cash from the fund.
Mr Milei has done a remarkable job so far of discarding the fiscal baggage
that has been weighing Argentina down. But mess up the big
macroeconomic questions and that will count for little.■
KIM JONG UN has a new best friend. Out is Donald Trump, who
exchanged saccharine letters but spurned him at a summit in Hanoi in 2019.
In is Vladimir Putin, who has courted Mr Kim for weapons to fuel his war in
Ukraine. Mr Kim has made two trips to Russia’s Far East to meet Mr Putin
since 2019. On June 19th Mr Putin arrived in Pyongyang for his first visit
since 2000, the year he made his debut as president. Though he landed at
close to 3am local time, Mr Kim was waiting on a red carpet on the tarmac
to meet him. The two leaders later signed a strategic partnership agreement,
promising to come to each other’s aid when facing aggression.
The relationship has blossomed thanks to geopolitical shifts. Mr Kim turned
away from talks with America following the failed summit in Hanoi and
began making fresh overtures to Russia. The response was lukewarm—until
Mr Putin’s full-scale invasion of Ukraine floundered and Russia came to
need munitions, one of the few things Mr Kim’s regime has in abundance.
But the implications of the realignment go beyond the weapons trade. “It’s a
mistake to think about it simply as an arms deal,” says Jenny Town of the
Stimson Centre, an American think-tank.
Russia has proved a godsend in a time of need for North Korea. Mr Kim was
isolated abroad and diminished at home following the debacle in Hanoi;
years of sanctions and the covid-19 pandemic had not helped, either.
Summitry with Mr Putin has burnished Mr Kim’s image and improved his
diplomatic position. With both Russia and China behind it, North Korea has
little incentive to engage with America. It can also play the two powers off
against each other. “It is the biggest strategic opportunity for North Korea
since the end of the Cold War,” says Ankit Panda of the Carnegie
Endowment for International Peace, a think-tank in Washington. Trade with
Russia has also helped stabilise the North Korean economy. The new
agreement includes a range of economic and cultural measures, including
the construction of a bridge across the river that forms their border, the first
for cars.
What Russia has given in return stirs much speculation. South Korea’s
government estimates that at least 9,000 containers have been sent from
Russia to North Korea since last September. North Korea’s wish-list
probably includes nuclear-weapons designs, re-entry vehicles for
intercontinental ballistic missiles, as well as technology related to satellites,
submarines and hypersonic weapons. Russia could also provide less flashy
but still important support for North Korea’s conventional forces, such as
spare parts for aircraft or ships, and more modern air defences.
South Korean officials say that Russia has yet to transfer sensitive
technology related to ballistic missiles or nuclear weapons. One area of more
immediate concern is space. Mr Panda reckons that a recent North Korean
satellite launch attempt may have deployed a variant of an engine used in
Russia’s Angara system, which Russia has at a cosmodrome that Mr Kim
toured last autumn. For now, food and fuel probably make up the bulk of the
trade. Mr Putin also gave Mr Kim a Russian-made limousine in February,
and a second one during his latest trip—in pointed defiance of UN sanctions,
which bar the export of luxury goods to North Korea.
Yet such seeming affection belies the limits to the friendship. While Russia
may flout international sanctions, that does not mean it will rush to help
North Korea expand its nuclear arsenal. Russia can extract concessions
without giving up its most sensitive technology; as its own production ramps
up, its need for North Korean shells may wane. South Korea, in turn, can
threaten more support for Ukraine to enforce its red lines.
The partnership will probably last as long as the war in Ukraine. But it may
not endure beyond it. In the long run, South Korea is a more attractive
economic partner; it was Russia’s fifth-largest export destination in 2021.
Russia seems keen to keep the door open: its ambassador to Seoul recently
said he expects South Korea to be “first among unfriendly countries to return
to the ranks of friendly countries”. Few Russians want to be associated with
North Korea, which they consider a synonym for dysfunction, in contrast to
the economic powerhouse that is China.
China itself can also shape how deep Russia’s and North Korea’s co-
operation grows. “It’s not a bilateral relationship—big brother is always
watching from Beijing,” says Fyodor Tertitskiy of Kookmin University in
Seoul. China’s feelings appear mixed. Its diplomats did not stop Russia from
killing off the UN sanctions panel. But during a recent summit with South
Korea and Japan, China endorsed a call for the denuclearisation of the
Korean peninsula, drawing a rebuke from Mr Kim’s regime. China’s primary
interests are to maintain North Korea as a stable buffer state between itself
and American-allied South Korea, as well as to retain influence over
Pyongyang; closer military ties between Russia and North Korea could
threaten these aims.
China also appears keen to avoid the appearance that the three belong to a
single bloc. “China wants to be a global leader, not a rogue,” says Lee Sang-
hyun of the Sejong Institute, a think-tank in Seoul. Mr Putin reportedly
wanted to travel on to Pyongyang earlier, immediately after a visit to Beijing
last month, but China suggested that he should wait. The picture that
emerges is less of a neat authoritarian axis and more of a messy love
triangle. ■
This article was downloaded by zlibrary from https://www.economist.com/asia/2024/06/16/vladimir-putins-dangerous-bromance-with-
kim-jong-un
Asia | Marriage of equals
On June 18th government bigwigs, LGBT activists and stars of popular Thai
television shows about gay love partied on the lawn in front of the prime
minister’s offices in Bangkok. Hours earlier the Thai senate voted through a
sweeping marriage-equality bill. Thailand will soon be the first South-East
Asian country to legalise same-sex marriage.
The attendees, some of whom left the party in a motorcade of rainbow tuk-
tuks, helped bring about comprehensive legislation. In Thailand’s civil code
marriage will be described as a pact between two persons, rather than a man
and a woman. Married LGBT couples will also get inheritance and adoption
rights. The Thai king is expected to endorse the bill soon; it becomes law
120 days later.
couples across Asia hope the Thai bill accelerates acceptance in their own
LGBT
countries. Some are making strides towards pride. Australia, New Zealand,
Nepal and Taiwan have legalised same-sex marriage in the past decade or so.
India, Hong Kong and Singapore have repealed colonial-era laws
criminalising gay sex. But regional progress is uneven and often slow.
Thailand’s bill passed for several reasons. Most were on show at the
celebration. First is social acceptance, which is boosted in Thailand by
activists, social-media influencers and TV dramas about gay romance dubbed
“Boys’ Love”. Much of Thai society is conservative and discrimination
persists. But some 60% of people support same-sex marriage, among the
highest shares in Asia, according to Pew Research Centre, a pollster.
Even during long years in exile Mr Thaksin, at the head of his populist Pheu
Thai movement, has been enemy number one. The charge has to do with a
claim he made nearly a decade ago that the king’s powerful Privy Council
was complicit in yet another coup, in 2014, when his sister was prime
minister.
But the indictment is striking because only last year both sides made a
grubby-looking pact, following a general election in May 2023. The ex-
generals then running the country hoped to manage the election. But a more
liberal movement than Pheu Thai, the Move Forward Party, easily won the
most seats on a platform of breaking up monopolies, ending conscription
and reforming the lèse-majesté law. Pheu Thai came second, and the main
army-backed party a distant third.
The deal made with Mr Thaksin has not been divulged. But his indictment
suggests that he has since crossed a line. Perhaps the establishment thought
he would steer clear of politics. Instead, he has eagerly re-entered political
life, travelling about the country as if campaigning. Meanwhile, a separate
case heard on the same day by the constitutional court was against his ally,
Mr Srettha, brought by a group of conservative senators. They claim that Mr
Srettha broke the law by appointing a convicted man (and another Thaksin
ally) to his cabinet. They call for the prime minister’s removal.
In the event, the courts granted Mr Thaksin bail and called for another
hearing on Mr Srettha for July 10th. That puts off, for now, an immediate
political crisis. Yet the cases, at the least, represent a warning to Mr Thaksin
and his allies that they should not take for granted the political space they
have carved out.
The outcome of a third case, against Move Forward, is perhaps the most
predictable, yet it offers the greatest reflection on the future of Thailand’s
dismal politics. In this case the election commission is seeking to dissolve
the party, on the grounds that its call to change the lèse-majesté law was
treason.
Dissolution would be a slap in the face for over 14m voters. The ban on
Future Forward was the catalyst for widespread student-led protests that
lasted months. Since then, democracy advocates have been hounded. Some
2,000 Thais have been charged or prosecuted, among them over 270 for
lèse-majesté. If not in prison, many activists lie low or have fled abroad.
Even so, others Banyan spoke to said they would continue to fight, largely
through grassroots campaigns for greater democracy and representation.
A DECADE AGO the Union of India welcomed into the fold its newest member: the
state of Telangana. Of India’s then 29 states, it ranked 12th by population,
11th by area and 10th by per-person income. One of those rankings has since
changed dramatically. By last year Telangana had shot up to boast the
highest per-person income of any decent-size state, behind only tiny Sikkim
and Goa.
That is not all. In the past decade the state’s GDP growth has outperformed
India as a whole. With just 2.7% of India’s population, its share of the
country’s annual output has increased nearly a fifth, to 4.8%. Hyderabad, its
economic powerhouse, is a multilingual, multireligious metropolis with an
abundance of high-tech jobs, including the largest Amazon office anywhere.
Microsoft and Google are expanding their already substantial presence in the
city. It is also a pharma hub. What is Telangana’s recipe for success?
The very fact of being new is one benefit of state formation. In 2000 India
created three new states, hiving off chunks from unwieldy giants. For several
years the new entities did better economically than the rumps they left
behind. Yet that Telangana would thrive was not foretold (none of the other
newish states sustained their early momentum). It was the poorer part of the
state from which it was carved out. Unlike other prosperous southern states,
it is landlocked. It still has only one airport. With the exception of
Hyderabad, it lacks any cities of size. Many foresaw economic difficulties,
even unrest.
K. Chandrashekar Rao, better known as KCR, had led the movement for
statehood. But as the first chief minister of the new entity, he had to
transition to governing. “There were a lot of apprehensions,” says K.T.
Rama Rao, KCR’s son and a minister in that government (he is known,
inevitably, as KTR). People worried that “these guys were running amok in the
street… can they actually come govern?” The new government proved
practical, reassuring businesses that their interests were safe. There were no
reprisals against the Andhraite-dominated business community.
Another advantage of new states is that they may have greater leeway to
experiment. Upon creation, Telangana immediately set about making itself
attractive to investors. Many Indian states eager to rise up ease-of-doing-
business rankings promise “single-window clearance” for businesses to deal
with the bureaucracy. But the process is still a painful mess, with multiple
departments working to their own timelines. Telangana’s innovation was to
do away with many requirements and promise approvals within 15 days.
Such ideas were “only possible because we were a new state, and there was
no legacy to pull you down”, says Jayesh Ranjan, a senior bureaucrat who
was involved in drafting the policies. “Everything was a clean slate.”
Stay on top of our India coverage by signing up to Essential India, our free
weekly newsletter.
This article was downloaded by zlibrary from https://www.economist.com/asia/2024/06/20/why-india-should-create-dozens-of-new-
states
China
China and Russia have chilling plans for the Arctic
China wants to export education, too
China doesn’t want people flaunting their wealth
China’s revealing struggle with childhood myopia
China | Picking through the ice
Four hundred kilometres north of the Arctic Circle, in the Norwegian port of
Kirkenes, there are still some who dream that this sleepy town will one day
become an important shipping hub. They see it as the western end of a new,
faster sea route from China to Europe, made possible by the impact of global
warming on ice-filled waters off the Siberian coast. With war raging in
Ukraine, this ambition now sounds fanciful. China’s support for Russia is
fuelling Western distrust of the Asian power’s “polar silk road” plans. But
China is not retreating from the Arctic. It still sees a chance to boost its
influence there, and to benefit from the area’s wealth of natural resources.
Rising temperatures in the Arctic are slowly opening up new possibilities for
transport. But geopolitics are changing the region faster. Kirkenes feels this
strongly. It is just 15 minutes’ drive from the Russian border. Tourists can
enjoy a “king crab safari” that takes them by boat right up to it, with
eponymous crustaceans caught along the way and cooked for the visitors
(the massive non-native species was introduced by the Soviets). Russians,
though, no longer cross into Kirkenes for shopping and crab feasts. On May
29th Norway closed the border crossing to day-trippers from the other side.
The conflict in Ukraine has cast a chill over the town. There were “tensions
in the air” in October when Russia’s envoy in Kirkenes laid a wreath at a
monument to the Soviet troops who liberated the town from the Nazis
towards the end of the second world war, the Barents Observer, a local
online newspaper, reported. Politicians in Kirkenes had urged him not to do
so.
Frosty relations
Western governments have long been cautious about China’s Arctic
activities, worrying that the country’s growing economic influence in the
region might give it political sway and open doors to a Chinese security
presence that would add to the Arctic challenge that Russia already poses.
RAND, a think-tank in Washington, notes that since 2018 China’s “diplomatic
The war in Ukraine has compounded Western scepticism about any big
project involving China, which calls itself neutral but also boasts a “no-
limits” friendship with Russia and is giving huge support to Russia’s defence
industry. The conflict has led to the freezing of activities of the Arctic
Council, a talking-shop involving the eight countries with Arctic territory,
which China joined as an observer in 2013. (In a white paper in 2018 China
called itself a “near-Arctic state”, though its northernmost provincial capital,
Harbin, is on the same latitude as Venice.) All of the council’s members,
except Russia, are now members of NATO, Finland and Sweden having joined
the defence pact in the past 15 months. In Arctic affairs, China finds itself
even more of an outsider.
Russia controls about half of the Arctic’s shoreline and a huge share of its oil
and gas reserves. For now, Chinese ships may not be pushing to use the
Northern Sea Route (Russia charges stiff fees for the use of its icebreakers).
Shippers prefer predictable schedules: for all the Arctic’s warming, journey
times along that passage can vary as a result of ice and fog. Chinese firms,
however, see gains to be made in Russia as it turns to Asia to make up for
the loss of Western markets. They include involvement in port construction,
oil and gas projects and the building of ships for Russia to sail such
resources eastward (China is a big buyer of Russian energy). Russia may
once have been wary of getting China involved in developing its Arctic
coast. Now it welcomes Chinese help. “Russia is very keen to have them,
because they have no other options,” says Kjell Stokvik of the Centre for
High North Logistics in Kirkenes. “So in a way for China, they’re in a very
good seat.”
There are risks, as Messrs Yue and Gu noted, such as fallout from Western
sanctions. They urged China to be “cautious and low-profile” in its approach
to Arctic co-operation with Russia. However, during a visit by Russia’s
leader, Vladimir Putin, to Beijing in May the two countries vowed to
“promote the Arctic route as an important international transport corridor”
and encourage their companies to “strengthen co-operation in increasing
Arctic route traffic volume and building Arctic route logistics
infrastructure”. The silk road on ice is slippery, but it retains its allure. ■
ABOUT 500 pupils study at the Chinese School Dubai. Most are children of
Chinese expatriates who have moved to the United Arab Emirates for work.
At the school’s swish suburban campus, pupils follow much the same
curriculum they would at home. On one wall hangs a bland quote from
China’s leader, Xi Jinping, picked out in shiny gold. The institution, which
has more than doubled in size since its opening in 2020, is a pilot project:
the first of several international schools the Communist Party talks of setting
up in big cities. In 2019 officials said they had asked Chinese diplomats in
45 countries, including Britain and America, to explore the possibility of
creating such institutions.
American, British and French schools are easy to find in most big capital
cities. But ones that teach the Chinese curriculum remain sparse, even
though more than 10m Chinese nationals are thought to live abroad. The
government fears this is discouraging Chinese from working for its
companies overseas. Children who swap domestic classrooms for foreign
ones, even for a bit, can struggle when they go back to China. That mattered
less when high-fliers all clamoured for spots in Western universities (which
are best won with Western qualifications). But clever kids are increasingly
competing for places in top Chinese colleges, so they seek out Chinese
credentials.
Government-backed projects such as the school in Dubai are just one of the
ways Chinese activities in international schooling are expanding, according
to a report by Venture Education, a consultancy. Lately overcapacity at home
has prompted companies that run private schools in China to invest abroad,
particularly in Asia. The schools they create tend to offer whichever flavour
of education is most in demand in their target markets. In time it seems
likely that these companies will run more experiments with Chinese-
language instruction or Chinese curriculums—especially if the party
encourages it.
All this means growing competition for existing international schools. Many
of them enroll a lot of Chinese pupils, says Julian Fisher of Venture
Education. There is no guarantee that the Chinese interlopers will play fair.
It is possible to imagine state-owned firms incentivising employees to enroll
their children in state-favoured institutions. If it were insinuated that Chinese
international schools offer privileged access to the best Chinese universities,
that might give them an additional boost.
MAO ZEDONG persecuted the rich. But his successor as paramount leader,
Deng Xiaoping, decided to “let some people get rich first”, as he launched
market-oriented reforms. Now a growing number of Chinese are rich—and
the pendulum has swung back, with the government cracking down on
ostentatious displays of wealth.
Online influencers are the state’s main target. Until recently, these (mostly
young) men and women flaunted their luxury goods to millions of followers.
In recent months, though, many have had their social-media accounts
suspended by China’s internet regulators.
Among the most famous of these personalities is a man called Wang
Hongquanxing. Known as “China’s Kim Kardashian”, he has reportedly said
that he would never leave his house without clothes, jewellery and
accessories worth less than 10m yuan ($1.4m). In May state media reported
that he had been banned from China’s top social-media platforms along with
dozens of other influencers.
This is not the first time that influencers have found themselves in the
government’s cross-hairs. They were also targeted in 2021, when China’s
leader, Xi Jinping, launched his “common prosperity” campaign. That effort
aimed to chasten the ultra-rich and reduce inequality. People and companies
with a lot of money were encouraged to contribute more to society. The
slapping down of Jack Ma, China’s best-known billionaire, was seen as a
warning to the country’s other plutocrats.
Yet luxury brands are lowering prices as unsold inventory piles up. This
probably has little do with the crackdown on influencers. Amid a sluggish
economy, Chinese consumers are simply becoming more frugal, spending
less on Balenciaga bags and Gucci wallets.
Some luxury brands are putting on a brave face. Louis Vuitton, a French
fashion house, has just reopened its renovated boutique in the city of
Guangzhou. The CEO of Tissot, a Swiss luxury-watch company, was recently
in Shanghai for a product launch. Zegna, a stylish clothing brand, has
opened a posh new café in Shanghai. Don’t expect Chinese influencers to do
much promotion though.■
The results are in and they are “dramatic”, says Lan Weizhong, an
ophthalmologist at Central South University in Changsha. After pandemic
lockdowns ended, mass eye tests in several Chinese cities detected spikes in
rates of childhood myopia, or fuzzy sight at a distance. That confirms the
widely held scientific belief that the healthy growth of young eyes is
impeded by too much “near work”, including time spent reading books or
watching screens, and by a lack of time outdoors, says Professor Lan.
The findings are being studied closely in China, where rates of myopia have
surged over the past quarter-century. More than half of Chinese children and
adolescents are short-sighted, with rates exceeding 80% among high-school
graduates, though numbers have dipped a bit of late. In 2018 Xi Jinping, the
supreme leader, declared myopia a “major concern” that threatens children’s
health and China’s strength (fighter pilots and firefighters need perfect sight,
state media noted).
An eye-opening visit
Lei Peng, the headmaster of Feicheng’s Shiyan Primary School, leaves little
to chance. Chaguan is welcomed by saluting security guards to the large
campus, with 2,800 pupils. Your columnist is shown a well-equipped science
block, complete with a drone-flying arena. He watches art and music
lessons, and is swiftly beaten at ping-pong by a small girl with a killer top-
spin. Not one of the children on show is wearing glasses: a surprise given
that over a quarter of Feicheng primary-school pupils have myopia.
Pupils’ eyes are getting better and better, Mr Lei assures his foreign visitor,
smoothly. He credits Mr Xi with showing the way on eye health. Then he
offers a moment of candour, explaining how important it was when
authorities changed how schools, teachers and education officials are
evaluated. Shandong province was a pioneer when it included children’s
health—including eye health—in school-performance reviews. Now eye
health is a metric used nationwide. Only once exams are no longer the sole
basis for judging success will teachers, students and their parents “dare to
ease up”, says Mr Lei. It is a revealing comment from this shrewd 38-year
veteran of the teaching profession. Even in quiet spots like Feicheng, China
is a ferociously competitive place. Understand that and the country comes
into focus. ■
IN THE diplomacy around the forever war between Israel and the
Palestinians, it is customary to describe a Palestinian state as a necessity.
Consider the latest Gaza ceasefire proposal, backed by America and all the
other countries on the UN’S 15-strong Security Council bar Russia, which
abstained. It outlines the global community’s “unwavering” commitment to
a two-state solution “where two democratic states, Israel and Palestine, live
side by side in peace”. It also insists that Gaza must be unified with the West
Bank under the authority of the Palestinian Authority (PA). Most countries
believe that Palestine should be recognised as a full-fledged state
immediately, before any peace deal is struck between Israel and the
Palestinians. On May 10th 143 countries at the UN supported this idea. On
May 28th they were joined by Ireland, Norway and Spain.
Some visions of this new state are inspiring. Palestine Emerging, a study by
100 experts released in April, foresees Gaza and the West Bank by 2050 as a
single entity of 13m people, up from around 5m today, connected by a
railway, replete with nature reserves and an airport. The devastation in Gaza
creates a clean slate on which a new city will be built, with a seaport on an
island linked to the mainland by a causeway. Palestine would prosper as a
trading entrepot, its currency pegged to the dollar, underwritten by the rich
Gulf states. Yet when you look away from such hopeful blueprints, the gap
between the dream and reality is crushingly large.
When talks brokered by America over a two-state deal broke down in 2000,
a second intifada (uprising) erupted, which burned until 2005 and saw Israeli
tanks return to Palestinian cities. Then in 2007, almost two years after Israel
had dismantled its settlements in Gaza and withdrawn its troops, the armed
Islamists of Hamas, who won a general election covering both territories in
2006, took control of the coastal enclave. Yet the PA has limped on as a
political mutant, partly as a government and partly an instrument of Israeli
occupation, its remit limited to the West Bank. Many countries recognise
Palestine as a state, but the UN Security Council does not. Without clear
borders or its own army and police in sole charge of security, it lacks some
essential characteristics.
Since Oslo the Palestinian territories have changed a great deal, even before
the destruction of Gaza. In some respects these changes make it a more
credible state than it was in the 1990s. For example, Palestinians spend 2.4
more years in education than they did two decades ago, making them one of
the most literate populations in the Middle East. In the early 1990s Gaza and
the West Bank scored 0.53 on the UN’s Human Development Index (one is the
highest), based on health, wealth and education. By 2022 it had climbed to
0.716, ahead of Morocco.
The share of imports that come from Israel has fallen from 79% in 1995-99
to 57% in 2022, making the West Bank less dependent on Israeli inputs. On
the ground and at international forums like the World Economic Forum in
Davos, the PA has acquired institutional heft. In May it marked 30 years in
existence. Its tenacity in the face of adversity has heightened its aspirations.
“The jacket [of Oslo] no longer fits us,” says Husam Zomlot, the Palestinian
ambassador in London. But 30 years after Oslo, the would-be state faces
glaring problems: a faltering economy, territorial fragmentation, lack of
security and autocracy.
Start with the economy. With a GDP of around $18.6bn in 2023 the Palestinian
territories are the world’s 127th biggest economy. In areas of the West Bank
under the PA’s control income per person is 43% of the global average, on a
par with Iraq. There are islands of prosperity. In Ramallah, the seat of
government, gated communities and shopping complexes abound and plenty
of new houses and apartment blocks have risen up. And however flawed the
PA has been, its economic performance far exceeds Hamas’s in its besieged
enclave of Gaza. On the eve of Hamas’s attack on October 7th, incomes per
person in the West Bank were five times higher than those in Gaza.
Unemployment in the third quarter of 2023 was 13% in the West Bank,
compared with 45% in Gaza.
Yet for all that, the economy is fragile and dominated by Israel. In a report
before the October 7th attacks the IMF described a “fiscal crisis” in which the
PA was massively in arrears. The Palestinian territories recorded a current-
account deficit of around 12% of GDP, with imports far exceeding formal
exports.
The Palestinian economy depends heavily on Israel. Though the PA has
improved its own tax collection, some 8% of its 15bn shekels ($4bn) of
annual revenue comes from foreign aid and 67% comes from taxes that
Israel gathers on its behalf. About 90% of exports go to Israel and more than
180,000 Palestinians, around 23% of the West Bank’s workforce, were
employed there before October 7th. After the Hamas attack Israel cancelled
almost all the work permits previously granted to Palestinians, suspended
the transfer of tax revenue and tightly restricted movement out of and within
the West Bank. “It’s the Palestinians’ worst economic crisis since 1967,”
says Yitzhak Gal, an Israeli economist. To these immediate hits should be
added the costs of rebuilding Gaza, which the UN reckons could be $40bn
(estimates vary widely), and providing for its people. Foreign donors may
pay for much of this. Even so, the PA’s finances might buckle if it were to
assume responsibility for Gaza.
Security is just as bad. The PA has survived in part because Israel needs it to.
In 1987, when the Palestinians unleashed their first intifada, Israel had to
send in lots of troops to suppress the unrest. For most of the past three
decades, however, the Palestinians have largely policed themselves and
maintained order in the West Bank.
Unsteady state
Yet if one definition of a state is determined by whether it has defined
borders and a monopoly on the use of force within them, then the PA may be
further away from statehood than it was in the years after Oslo. The number
of Israeli settlers living in the West Bank and East Jerusalem has risen from
roughly 250,000 to about 695,000 today. Maps show the West Bank is far
more densely peppered with settler outposts. Palestinians are cut off from
East Jerusalem, their putative capital, and from Gaza. They are splintered by
Oslo’s division of the West Bank into Areas A, B and C (see map), denoting
differing levels of control by Israel and the PA. “They’re increasingly
fragmented into bantustans,” says Alon Cohen Lifshitz, director of an Israeli
planning watchdog, Bimkom, referring to the nominally self-governing
territories under apartheid in South Africa.
Since the Hamas attack last October, Israel has killed over 500 Palestinians
in the West Bank and Israeli checkpoints have stifled movement around
Palestinian cities. Journeys that should take half an hour can take three.
Israel has suspended security co-ordination with the PA. And increasingly
Israel treats Area A, where the PA is supposed to have full control, as if it were
Area C, where Israel has it. Israel regularly sends troops on raids into cities
such as Ramallah and Jenin to suppress militant groups the PA has struggled
to control, including those loyal to Hamas. Palestinians say these raids are
intended to weaken the PA’s hold and erode public confidence in it.
Then there is the PA’s autocratic leadership. Superficially the political system
is stable and looks more or less legitimate. “Of course partial occupation is
better than full occupation,” says a Palestinian official. Many appreciate the
sense of order that the PA brings. Yet there is a vast lack of accountability and
the legitimacy is questionable. In November Mahmoud Abbas, the supine
88-year-old Palestinian president, will have ruled for 20 of the PA’s 30 years.
Under Mr Abbas, Fatah, the main faction in the West Bank, forsook the
violence of the second intifada.
Since the attacks of October 7th there have been changes. In March Mr
Abbas appointed a new prime minister, Mohammad Mustafa, a former
economics adviser. But America has backed away from trying to force Mr
Abbas to surrender some of his powers to his prime minister and
government. The prospect of elections is remote. Mr Abbas and his Arab
and Western backers are wary of democracy in the West Bank. In a survey
published on June 12th by PSR, a Palestinian research body, only 8% of West
Bankers say they have been satisfied by Mr Abbas’s performance in this
war; 94% want him to resign. Some 41% of respondents say they support
Hamas, a notably higher share than before the war, compared with 17% who
support Fatah.
For some Palestinians the status quo is a lesser evil than provoking their
foes. “It’s not the time for resistance,” says the owner of a new café in the
West Bank city of Nablus who was once a militant. “We’d just give the
settlers an opportunity to destroy what we’ve built.” For others, though, the
attractions of violence are rising. “If the result of peaceful resistance is
continued occupation, then we should reconsider our options,” says one of
Ramallah’s biggest businessmen. “It’s the first time anyone forced Israel
back from the border and got 200 soldiers to surrender,” says an Abbas
loyalist of the Hamas attack. The target of violence could be Israel, the
settlers or the PA. And the latest impulses of the Palestinian electorate are
alarming. A recent PSR survey found that 62% of West Bankers favoured an
armed struggle. Two-thirds of Palestinians thought the Hamas attacks were
“correct”; 91% denied that Hamas had committed atrocities against civilians.
security forces. Small groups are plotting attacks on Israel and its settlers.
If violence is one way for Palestinians to disrupt the status quo, another is
diplomacy and, in particular, the calls for the immediate international
recognition of a Palestinian state. Though three-quarters of the world’s
countries have recognised Palestinian statehood, America and most main
European powers have not. One argument for recognition is symbolic.
Governments also argue that by signalling support for the two-state plan
they can prevent extremists on both sides from killing off a two-state
settlement. It is less plausible that recognition will have any immediate
effect on the ground.
State of change
Michael Sfard, an Israeli lawyer, sees little changing. “Recognition of
Palestine doesn’t end the occupation or change the validity of the Oslo
accords,” he says. Yet others think it would have rapid effects, including on
the settlers. “All nationalities including Israelis would have to apply to live
in our state and abide by our laws. This can’t happen as a fait accompli,”
says Mr Zomlot. “The resources—land, water, minerals—are taken from our
state and must be taxed.” With clearer legal sovereignty, Palestinians could
seek to tap their own resources, like offshore gas, and sign defence pacts.
Some argue a new state could even seek to take control of the border
crossings with Jordan and Egypt.
Yet the interconnectedness of Israel with its settlements and the West Bank
means that a unilateral act of separation could be incendiary, provoking an
Israeli response. “If the UN [Security Council] recognises a Palestine state, the
Oslo accords would be rendered irrelevant because they deal with something
less than a state,” says Itzik Bam, a settler lawyer and ally of Bezalel
Smotrich, Israel’s ultranationalist finance minister. “We’ll stop transferring
tax money that we collect for you, cancel all your VIP cards for freedom of
movement and watch you collapse.”
As the war in Gaza drags on, the prospect of a Palestinian state is at once
more relevant than ever and yet more distant. Trust on both sides has been
shattered by the Hamas attacks and the Israeli response. The path towards
statehood would require new leadership of the PA (or a successor organisation)
and the rebuilding of its democratic credentials; a plan for what to do in
Gaza when Israel’s invasion ends and for its reunification with the West
Bank; and a new centrist government in Israel ready to negotiate an end to
the conflict with the Palestinians. Outsiders would have to apply heavy
pressure on both sides to work towards an agreement. Israel and the
Palestinians would have to compromise. The notion of a democratic
Palestinian state alongside Israel is still a dream. But the alternative, of
ceaseless Palestinian atrophy, is one that offers the region only misery,
extremism and war. ■
Sign up to the Middle East Dispatch, a weekly newsletter that keeps you in
the loop on a fascinating, complex and consequential part of the world.
This article was downloaded by zlibrary from https://www.economist.com/middle-east-and-africa/2024/06/18/is-a-palestinian-state-
a-fantasy
Middle East & Africa | War in the Middle East
RED BANNERS that hang across bridges above the main roads leading
north in Israel contain one word: “Abandoned”. It is repeated by the few
residents remaining in the near-deserted towns and villages near the border,
which have been under fire for eight months from Hizbullah, the Iran-
backed movement that controls much of Lebanon. It is also an accusation
levelled at the government of Binyamin Netanyahu, Israel’s prime minister,
which has failed to find a way to stop the barrage of missiles and drones that
Hizbullah began firing on October 8th, the day after Hamas’s attack on
Israel. Hassan Nasrallah, the leader of Hizbullah, recently vowed to continue
the attacks, insisting that his group is a “support front” for Hamas.
“We’re like ducks in Nasrallah’s shooting-range,” says Gidi Sayada, a
winemaker from Safsufa, a village that has not been evacuated. “My
daughters have been sleeping in the safe-room of our house for the past eight
months.” Hizbullah has shelled mainly targets close by the border and
military bases. Israel has responded with targeted strikes on Hizbullah
people, in some cases deep inside Lebanon.
Though neither side has unleashed anything near its full arsenal, the cross-
border fire has increased since mid-May and last week reached its most
intense level since the start of the war. Using data from a NASA satellite system
and a machine-learning algorithm to track war-related fires, The Economist
has counted the number of strikes occurring on both sides of the border (see
map and chart). In the week ending on June 16th there were 640 such
strikes, 254 of them on June 13th alone.
Though a measure of calm has returned in recent days, perhaps due to Eid
al-Adha, a Muslim holiday, the fighting has upended lives in Lebanon and
Israel. Early in the war Israel evacuated people living within 2km of the
border. Some 60,000 have yet to return. Across the border in southern
Lebanon more than 90,000 have also fled.
In numerical terms, Israel has caused more damage to Hizbullah, killing
over 300 of its operatives during this period as well as around 100 civilians;
28 people have been killed in Israel. On June 12th an Israeli air strike killed
Taleb Sami Abdallah, a senior Hizbullah member in command of its forces
in southern Lebanon. But these strikes have not lessened the desperation
among Israelis in the north.
Israel’s American allies have been urging it to hold fire. Amos Hochstein, an
adviser to President Joe Biden, has been trying to craft a ceasefire between
Israel and Hizbullah. Mr Netanyahu seems open to this idea, though he is
less keen on agreeing to stop fighting in Gaza.
Israeli generals insist that the IDF can fight on two fronts. But they admit that
doing so would drastically stretch the army. “To take over southern Lebanon
we’ll need a lot more troops, but meanwhile most of the units are in or
around Gaza,” says one reserve commander who has been on exercises
preparing for such an operation. “The plans feel incomplete.”
The IDF would like to pause the war against Hamas, preferably through a
ceasefire that would also secure the release of the 120 hostages still in Gaza.
But a truce in Gaza would probably prompt Hizbullah also to stop firing.
That would leave Israel’s leaders with the dilemma of whether to start a new
war to push the group away from the border or to allow it to remain in a
position to threaten Israeli communities.
Sign up to the Middle East Dispatch, a weekly newsletter that keeps you in
the loop on a fascinating, complex and consequential part of the world.
This article was downloaded by zlibrary from https://www.economist.com/middle-east-and-africa/2024/06/17/israels-northern-
border-is-ablaze
Middle East & Africa | The light continent
than doubling the actual rate, according to one academic paper. Since then
South Africa has also had erratic electricity. So-called “load-shedding” is
probably the main reason why the economy has shrunk in four of the past
eight quarters.
Solar power is increasingly seen as the solution. Last year Africa installed a
record amount of photovoltaic (PV) capacity (though this still made up just
1% of the total added worldwide), notes the African Solar Industry
Association (AFSIA), a trade group. Globally most solar PV is built by utilities,
but in Africa 65% of new capacity over the past two years has come from
large firms contracting directly with developers. These deals are part of a
decentralised revolution that could be of huge benefit to African economies.
Ground zero for the revolution is South Africa. Last year saw a record
number of blackouts imposed by Eskom, the state-run utility, whose
dysfunctional coal-fired power stations regularly break down or operate at
far below capacity. Fortunately, as load-shedding was peaking, the costs of
solar systems were plummeting. Between 2019 and 2023 the cost of panels
fell by 15%, having already declined by almost 90% in the 2010s.
Meanwhile battery storage systems now cost about half as much as five
years ago. Industrial users pay 20-40% less per unit when buying electricity
from private project developers than on the cheapest Eskom tariff. In the
past two calendar years the amount of solar capacity in South Africa rose
from 2.8GW to 7.8GW, notes AFSIA, excluding that installed on the roofs of
suburban homes. All together South Africa’s solar capacity could now be
almost a fifth of that of Eskom’s coal-fired power stations (albeit those still
have a higher “capacity factor”, or ability to produce electricity around the
clock). The growth of solar is a key reason why there has been less load-
shedding in 2024.
Other Africans often point out that they have had load-shedding for much
longer than South Africans. About half of African firms rely on diesel
generators; in Nigeria their capacity is almost four times what the grid can
reliably supply. But change is afoot: nearly two-thirds of mines in sub-
Saharan Africa produce renewable energy or are in the process of installing
renewables. In Nigeria, the phasing out of petrol subsidies last year
accelerated a shift to cleaner energy. In a symbolic acquisition in 2022,
Shell, an oil giant present in Nigeria since 1937, bought Daystar Power, a
startup that has provided solar-power systems to many large domestic
businesses.
Ignite, which operates in nine African countries, has products that include a
basic panel that powers three light bulbs and a phone charger, as well as
solar-powered irrigation pumps, stoves and internet routers, and industrial
systems. Customers use mobile money to “unlock” a pay-as-you-go meter.
Yariv Cohen, Ignite’s CEO, reckons that the typical $3 per month spent by
consumers is less than what they previously paid for kerosene and at phone-
charging kiosks. He describes how farmers are more productive because
they do not have to get home before dark and children are getting better test
scores because they study under bulbs. One family in Rwanda used to keep
their two cows in their house because they feared rustlers might come in the
dark; now the cattle snooze al fresco under an outside lamp and the family
gets more sleep.
In April the World Bank and the African Development Bank launched a
flagship scheme to expand electricity access in sub-Saharan Africa to 300m
additional people by 2030. The World Bank suggests that under its most
cost-effective scenario roughly half of those would be connected via off-
grid, DRE systems. But since the costs of solar kits are still prohibitively
expensive for some of the poorest people in the world, the bank and donors
are planning to subsidise the upfront costs through programmes that pay DRE
firms to set up in remote rural areas. The bet is that this, together with more
policy certainty from governments (around, say, repatriation of profits and
future plans for the grid), can bring in more private investment.
Yet there is a limit to how much can be done by avoiding legacy utilities.
The World Bank reckons that the most cost-effective way to electrify the
other half of its 300m target is by extending existing grids. Many African
utilities have monolithic structures—in the jargon, they control the
generation, transmission and distribution of electricity—long “unbundled” in
other parts of the world. Most are, in effect, insolvent: more than half in sub-
Saharan Africa cannot cover their operating expenses, partly because
governments insist on setting consumer tariffs below the cost of supply.
The spread of solar may make things even worse for them. Some analysts
suggest Eskom could enter a “death spiral” as its best customers go off-grid.
Other utilities are perhaps even more vulnerable. Kenya Power receives 54%
of its revenues from roughly 700 entities, less than 0.01% of its total
customers.
A few utilities are changing with the times. Namibia, one of the sunniest
countries, last year made it easier for private producers to sell electricity into
the regional power pool. It sees its future role as more of a platform for the
buying and selling of electricity than as a generator and distributor. But
others are resisting change. Senegal, Mozambique and Tanzania, for
instance, still tangle up DRE firms in red tape. Other countries are hoping that
the “geopolitics of solar” will mean that foreign powers seeking influence in
Africa will pay to build the solar plants that their bankrupt utilities cannot
otherwise afford, argues one industry veteran. In May Mali, which last year
welcomed the Wagner Group of Russian mercenaries, announced that a
subsidiary of Rosatom, a Russian energy giant, would build west Africa’s
largest solar plant. It is hard to see any purely commercial investor having
gone for such a project.
That is one eye-catching aspect of Africa’s solar revolution. But most of the
continent is undergoing a more subtle—and significant—experiment in
decentralised, commercially driven solar power. It is a trend that could both
transform African economies and offer lessons to the rest of the world. ■
Sign up to the Analysing Africa, a weekly newsletter that keeps you in the
loop about the world’s youngest—and least understood—continent.
This article was downloaded by zlibrary from https://www.economist.com/middle-east-and-africa/2024/06/18/private-firms-are-
driving-a-revolution-in-solar-power-in-africa
Middle East & Africa | The rainbow nation’s election
Editor’s note (June 15th 2024): This article has been updated.
DESMOND TUTU once wrote that “we in South Africa…sell ourselves short.” In a
country with many problems it is easy to forget its “remarkable
achievements”, argued the late Nobel peace laureate. He felt that the world
had much to learn from the largely peaceful transition to democracy in 1994;
the Truth and Reconciliation Commission he chaired that shed light on the
darkness of apartheid; and the forgiveness of ordinary black people scarred
by decades of white rule.
If Archbishop Tutu were still alive, he might have added the events of June
14th to his list of feats. Members of parliament re-elected Cyril Ramaphosa
as South Africa’s president at the head of a “government of national unity”.
The coalition, anchored by Mr Ramaphosa’s African National Congress (ANC)
and the erstwhile official opposition, the Democratic Alliance (DA), was
necessitated by the results of elections held on May 29th. The ANC won just
40.2% of the vote, depriving it of its parliamentary majority for the first
time. To gain the support of most MPs Mr Ramaphosa could have joined with
dangerous populist parties. Instead he and his new partners have swiftly
opted for a government that adheres to the values of the 1994 settlement and
has a chance of overseeing vital reforms. Its formation reflects well on the
rainbow nation’s fledgling democracy.
The outcome was not inevitable. In the aftermath of the result, many figures
in the ANC were against a deal involving the DA, which won 21.8% of the vote.
Gwede Mantashe, the powerful party chair, reportedly preferred a tie-up
with a few smaller parties and the “devil we know”: the Economic Freedom
Fighters (EFF), a race-baiting hard-left party run by former leaders of the ANC’s
Youth League, which won 9.5%. Others wanted to work with uMkhonto
weSizwe (MK), a new party led by the former president, Jacob Zuma, which
won a stunning 14.6%.
If that was the case, it worked. Both MK and EFF made such unreasonable
demands that, in effect, they ruled themselves out. The EFF wanted the finance
ministry and insisted it would not be part of the same government as the DA,
which its deputy leader suggested was a puppet of the “white capitalist
establishment”. MK, which has been spouting Trumpian lies about the election
being rigged, demanded Mr Ramaphosa’s resignation—a stipulation the ANC
quickly ruled out.
Mr Ramaphosa was probably relieved by the hubris. He could tell his caucus
he had at least tried to talk to the populists. But while he never publicly
stated his preferences, they were strongly implied. After the ANC meeting he
spoke of coalition partners needing to respect the constitution (ruling out at
least MK, which wants to ditch the “colonial” document) and non-racialism
(excluding at least the EFF, whose leader has spewed vitriol against whites and
Indians). In a newsletter sent on June 10th he wrote of the importance of
Operation Vulindlela, a presidential initiative to accelerate market-friendly
reforms. It was an unsubtle nod: by this point DA negotiators had already
highlighted the same scheme as a priority.
To its credit the DA was conscious of the time constraints (the vote for
president took place just 12 days after the election results were formally
announced, a 54th of the time it took Belgium to form a government in
2018-20) and the gravity of the moment. Rather than get bogged down in
policy detail or demand specific cabinet jobs, the DA focused on ensuring it
would not be railroaded by the ANC. A coalition agreement hammered out just
before this crucial vote stipulates that government decisions need the support
of parties with 60% of seats in parliament. In effect this gives the ANC and DA a
veto. Another clause ensures that Mr Ramaphosa will have to assign seats in
his cabinet roughly in accordance with the vote shares of the coalition
partners.
Warrior deal
The third key partner is the Inkatha Freedom Party (IFP), a Zulu nationalist
party but one that believes in democracy and the constitution, unlike MK. The
involvement of the party, which won just 3.9% of the national vote, in the
coalition is an important nod to the interests of Zulus, the country’s largest
ethnic group. Velenkosini Fiki Hlabisa, the IFP’s leader, may get a prominent
cabinet job. On June 12th he spoke of how the coalition could also heal
wounds between his party and the ANC; the two fought an undeclared civil war
in the early 1990s that killed thousands. For the ANC the presence of the IFP and
a few tiny parties in the government is crucial as it makes the coalition look
less like just a tie-up between it and the DA, which some of its base see as a
“white party”.
The ANC, IFP and DA have also agreed to work together in the two largest
provinces, Gauteng and KwaZulu-Natal, after no party gained a majority in
regional elections. In KwaZulu-Natal, where MK won 45.4% of the vote, the
coalition will have a wafer-thin majority: parties other than MK and EFF have 41
of the 80 seats.
There is much that could go wrong. There will be tensions within the
administration. Moderates in the ANC share many of the same goals as liberals
in the DA. But they come from different political cultures: the former sees
itself as a movement, the latter more like a Western political party. And they
will not see eye to eye on issues such as race-based policies. There is also
the risk that the sheer dysfunction of the state will make it hard for even
well-meaning ministers to get results.
Then there are the challenges from outside the government. MK and EFF will
argue that—like 1994—this is a shady deal cooked up by black and white
elites who are the puppets of big business. Julius Malema, the EFF’s leader,
said he would work with MK to oppose the new government. He called the DA
“Zionists” and the “enemy”. Mr Zuma is showing himself to be a Zulu
Robert Mugabe, implying that his backers will turn violent unless “satisfied”
with the election. In KwaZulu-Natal, the epicentre of mass unrest in 2021
encouraged by Mr Zuma’s henchmen, the police must be vigilant. Even if
things are peaceful, Mr Zuma will want to destabilise the fragile coalition
that will run the province.
Mr Ramaphosa will have the hard task of keeping the support of the ANC.
Some in the party blame him for its disappointing election result. Without a
majority he has fewer cabinet jobs with which to buy loyalty. If his
government’s policies threaten the interests of important constituencies, such
as civil servants and trade unions, he will come under pressure. Since he is
expected to step down as party leader at the next major ANC conference,
probably in 2027, senior figures will be biding their time before trying to
nudge him out of the presidency, too.
The DA will have to square its participation with its base. At present it can
make a convincing case that keeping EFF and MK out of power is worth it. But
as time passes, that threat will fade. If the DA does badly in its stronghold of
Cape Town in local elections due in 2026, the party might have second
thoughts.
Yet all these potential pitfalls are for the future. Whatever happens next, the
incoming government has already achieved something profound: it has kept
Mr Zuma and the EFF away from power. This coalition may not be imbued
with the optimism and idealism of the one Nelson Mandela ran with his
former enemies from 1994 to 1997. But it is also impressive proof that there
is a pragmatic and principled centre in South African politics. Thirty years
after the end of apartheid in 1994, the Rainbow Nation has shown it still has
lessons for the rest of the world in how to handle a multi-ethnic democracy .
■
Sign up to the Analysing Africa, a weekly newsletter that keeps you in the
loop about the world’s youngest—and least understood—continent.
This article was downloaded by zlibrary from https://www.economist.com/middle-east-and-africa/2024/06/14/a-remarkable-new-era-
begins-in-south-africa
Europe
Emmanuel Macron faces heavy losses after a short campaign
A hard-right 28-year-old could soon be France’s prime minister
Hard-right parties are entering government across Europe
Russia’s latest crime in Mariupol: stealing property
Why southern Europeans will soon be the longest-lived people in the
world
Europe today is a case of lots of presidents yet nobody leading
Europe | France’s parliamentary election
The two-round vote for the National Assembly, on June 30th and July 7th,
has turned into one of the most crucial in post-war French history. At stake
is the serious possibility of a government led by either the hard right or hard
left. Marine Le Pen’s National Rally (RN) is the better known. But the
reconstituted left-wing alliance, the New Popular Front (NFP), is now hot on
its heels, with an equally drastic tax-and-spend programme.
Three main political blocs have emerged after Mr Macron’s decision on June
9th to dissolve parliament, which took everybody by surprise. Even his own
government, including the prime minister, Gabriel Attal, was informed only
at the last minute. Voting at this election concerns only the lower house of
parliament; Mr Macron, short of a surprise resignation, remains president
until 2027.
Polls show the leading bloc to be the RN, which held only 88 seats out of 577
in the old parliament. Its candidate for the job of prime minister is Ms Le
Pen’s 28-year-old protégé, Jordan Bardella (pictured). The RN has been joined
by a scattering of candidates from the centre-right Republicans (LR), after
their leader, Eric Ciotti, jumped in with them. Ms Le Pen’s niece, Marion
Maréchal, has also lent her support, prompting her expulsion from the ultra-
right Reconquest party. Alone, the RN remains ahead in first-round polls, on
33%, according to Ifop, a pollster, on June 18th. Its new LR friends, running in
62 constituencies, could bring it a further 4%. (Anti-Ciotti Republicans are
putting up 400 of their own candidates.)
The third bloc, Mr Macron’s centrist alliance Ensemble, trails far behind in
third place, with just 18%. It is hoping to find future allies for an anti-
extremist “republican front”, on the left and centre-right, by standing aside
in some 60 constituencies.
Given polling trends, the likeliest outcome currently looks to be a hung
parliament, with either the hard right or hard left in a position to try to form
a government. If either succeeded, France would then face an attempted
reversal of much of the economic agenda that Mr Macron has pursued since
he was first elected in 2017.
Mr Bardella has promised “immediately” to lower the level of VAT from 20%
to 5.5% on energy bills and motor fuel, and to use tax breaks to raise salaries
by up to 10%. After the French stockmarket, the world’s sixth-biggest, fell
by 6% in the first five days after the election was called, Mr Bardella took
fright. Other measures, he suggested, could wait until the autumn. These
include his pledge to strike down Mr Macron’s pension reform, which raised
the minimum retirement age from 62 years to 64. Mr Bardella also vows to
restore a wealth tax and abolish the right to French nationality for those born
to foreign parents on French soil.
The best hope for Mr Macron is that, after the vote, a union of moderate
parties might agree to work together under a technocratic leader. More
probable is that France enters the uncharted territory of parliamentary
instability: exactly what Charles de Gaulle sought to avoid when he founded
the modern French republic. ■
To stay on top of the biggest European stories, sign up to Café Europa, our
weekly subscriber-only newsletter.
This article was downloaded by zlibrary from https://www.economist.com/europe/2024/06/20/emmanuel-macron-faces-heavy-losses-
after-a-short-campaign
Europe | The French parliamentary elections
This backstory, as well as his unusual poise, grabbed Ms Le Pen’s eye early
on. Both assets were politically valuable for a party that, under her
stewardship since 2011, has been trying to transform itself from a fringe
xenophobic protest outfit into a party that speaks for the people and
promises to govern on their behalf. At the age of 16, Mr Bardella joined the
party because of Ms Le Pen’s takeover. Seven years later—after he had
dropped out of a geography degree at the Sorbonne university and gone into
local politics—she picked him to lead her party into elections in 2019 to the
European Parliament. A year earlier, she had changed its name from the
tainted National Front she inherited from her antisemitic, xenophobic father
to the National Rally (RN), a name with more mainstream associations.
Not everyone within the party was happy with Mr Bardella’s hasty rise.
Rivals considered him too young, inexperienced and disconnected from core
party loyalists. Mr Bardella’s formal consecration came in 2022, when he
beat Ms Le Pen’s former romantic partner, Louis Aliot, to be elected
president of the RN. That freed Ms Le Pen from daily party affairs (she
remains head of its bloc in parliament, and will undoubtedly be its nominee
for the next presidential race, in 2027). Since then, Mr Bardella has earned
respect among a generation of younger RN figures. “He has an impressive
work ethic and maturity,” says Jean-Philippe Tanguy, an outgoing RN deputy,
adding that Mr Bardella’s asset is that he is open to criticism but “ruthless
with pointless whiners.”
Yet the trouble for centrist voters hoping to obstruct his path to the
Matignon, as the French prime minister’s office in Paris is known, is that Mr
Bardella has so far managed to shrug off inconvenient details or failings.
That he grew up in Seine-Saint-Denis is widely known; less so, that he
attended a private Catholic school there, not the public lycée.
Voters seem no more bothered by his loose grasp of policy detail. During a
recent live debate against Gabriel Attal, Mr Macron’s 35-year-old prime
minister, Mr Bardella was forced to confess that he had not read the text of a
bill in the European Parliament that he had voted against. A poll the next
day, however, suggested that the debate had convinced more people to vote
for Mr Bardella’s party than Mr Attal’s. If Mr Bardella represents anything
in these populist times it is that reasoned argument and rational debate are
flimsy weapons against the force of simplistic promises and narrative
politics. ■
To stay on top of the biggest European stories, sign up to Café Europa, our
weekly subscriber-only newsletter.
This article was downloaded by zlibrary from https://www.economist.com/europe/2024/06/17/a-hard-right-28-year-old-could-soon-be-
frances-pm
Europe | Crumbling firewalls
How quaint it seems now. When Mr Michel’s son Charles, who presides
over the European Council, scans the table at the EU summits he chairs, he
sees eight leaders from right-wing populist parties or dependent on their
support. Many of the 19 other countries have had a similar experience, or
could soon face it (Austria among them; the FPÖ may rejoin government after
an election in September). The cordon sanitaire is fraying even at EU level.
Mr Michel’s counterpart at the European Commission, Ursula von der
Leyen, has flirted with the Brothers of Italy, a post-fascist party, in her bid
for a second term.
But the most important exception is Germany. The hard-right Alternative for
Germany (AfD) came second at the recent European elections, with a record
16%. Yet the AfD remains firmly beyond the Brandmauer (“firewall”). It has
never come close to power in any of Germany’s 16 states and is shunned at
federal level. Any hint that the centre-right Christian Democrats (CDU) might
consider working with it invites huge backlash.
The AfD conveys both rank amateurism and a whiff of brownshirtery, making
it easy to ignore. At national level, it remains small enough to work around.
True, it may come first in three east German state elections due to be held in
September. But although that will make forming centrist coalitions in those
states hard, the firewall is likely to hold. National hostility to the AfD is such
that, overall, the CDU stands to lose more by working with it in the east than by
holding the line.
The CDU does, though, hope to blunt the appeal of the AfD by talking tough on
irregular migration. Some find this upsetting. Mainstream parties
considering aping the populist right are warned that, in the words of Jean-
Marie Le Pen, founder of a xenophobic party in France, voters prefer the
original to a copy. In last year’s Dutch election the leader of the ruling
liberals tilted right, hoping to undercut Geert Wilders’s populist Party for
Freedom. The gambit backfired, and Mr Wilders won.
Yet in many countries the hard right has simply grown too big to disregard.
What to do? “This is the €1m question,” says Léonie de Jonge of the
University of Groningen. Of three possible tactics—ignore, demonise or
accommodate—none has consistently succeeded. Excluding far-right parties
bolsters their argument that they represent the only genuine alternative.
Little wonder many creep into government.
Elsewhere change can take more dramatic form. In France the “republican
front” against the hard-right National Rally (RN), led by Jean-Marie’s
daughter Marine, has so far kept the party from power. That may be about to
change as France heads into a snap parliamentary election. But even if it
doesn’t, Ms Le Pen has performed steadily better in presidential elections
over the past decade; in 2022 she took 41.5% of the run-off vote. If she wins
a majority at the next, in 2027, the game will be up. ■
To stay on top of the biggest European stories, sign up to Café Europa, our
weekly subscriber-only newsletter.
This article was downloaded by zlibrary from https://www.economist.com/europe/2024/06/20/hard-right-parties-are-entering-
government-across-europe
Europe | The spoils of war
OVER THE past few months, little white notices have appeared on
doorways to residential blocks all over Mariupol, a city besieged, wrecked
and then seized by Russia in May 2022. “An inventory of your block will be
carried out to identify ownerless property; the owner of the apartment should
be at home with documents and a Russian passport.” The print is small, the
implications large. Unless the apartments are re-registered with the Russian
occupying authorities and people are living in them, the properties will soon
be declared ownerless and sold.
Estimates suggest that over 90% of the housing blocks in central Mariupol
were damaged in the invasion of 2022. Some have been repaired, others
demolished. Some Mariupolans have been given flats in shoddy newly built
blocks. Leo, who doesn’t want to use his real name, says his parents’ new
apartment has wobbly door handles and a mouldy balcony, windows won’t
close properly and the bathroom fixtures had to be replaced after a month.
New commercial buildings have priority over social housing, though
developers are putting up residential blocks with big government grants and
loans. Russia’s government offers a cheap mortgage rate of just 2% to
buyers in the occupied territories, so local agents are touting for business.
To get around the new rules, some have tried to transfer ownership (often to
relatives still in Mariupol) by getting documents notarised by Russian
embassies abroad. But the overlapping jurisdictions of the DNR and the
Russian Federation in Mariupol can snarl up the regulations.
Mr Andryushchenko thinks such questions are moot. “We don’t know what
kind of condition Mariupol will be in after de-occupation,” he points out. “It
could be absolutely destroyed again.” ■
To stay on top of the biggest European stories, sign up to Café Europa, our
weekly subscriber-only newsletter.
This article was downloaded by zlibrary from https://www.economist.com/europe/2024/06/19/russias-latest-crime-in-mariupol-
stealing-property
Europe | Growing old together
The Calle de Jordán, a short street in central Madrid, encompasses the entire
cycle of human life. On one block is a fertility clinic, an increasingly
common sight in a country obsessed by its shortage of babies. A block
further down is a day centre for pensioners, advertising services like
memory training and help with mobility. It is common to see women in their
60s gently leading their 90-something mothers up to the door.
Four of the world’s most walkable cities are in Spain. See our full ranking of
the world’s most, and least, active cities.
Why do Spaniards move so much? Spanish cities, and even tiny pueblos, are
densely populated; hit the city limits and you are often in empty countryside.
Neither culture nor regulation favour sprawling suburbs, so even with
abundant land, Spaniards live on top of each other. Paris and other places
aiming to create “15-minute cities”, where most necessities are within
walking radius, could learn much from Spain. The same study that looked at
“activity inequality” examined urban America, finding that dense cities like
New York and Boston had greater (and more evenly distributed) levels of
activity than sprawling places like Atlanta and Phoenix.
But stressing diet and exercise misses a piece of the puzzle. Spain’s
walkability is also good for social life. Cities are built around plazas where
friends, family and co-workers sit, eat, drink and talk. That turns out to be
good for you even if you sip vermouth and eat crisps at noon. Reams of
research show that social contact is critical for physical and psychological
well-being.
According to a recent survey by Gallup, a pollster, and Meta, a social-media
company, 76% of Spaniards say they feel “very” or “fairly” socially
supported. That is above average, though not top of the table. Jon Clifton,
head of Gallup, says his firm’s research shows that Spaniards are fairly
unhappy and disengaged at work. He quips that a headline in El País, a
newspaper, got it more or less right: Spain is “the best country to live in and
the worst to work in”.
But work is not everything. Spaniards are fourth in the world when asked
whether they have seen friends or family who live near or with them in the
past week (Greece was second). This may be the unexpected upside of the
fact that many young southern Europeans cannot get good enough jobs to
afford to move out of their parents’ homes. Family bonds remain tight,
including in trying times like the financial crisis and the pandemic.
To stay on top of the biggest European stories, sign up to Café Europa, our
weekly subscriber-only newsletter.
This article was downloaded by zlibrary from https://www.economist.com/europe/2024/06/20/why-southern-europeans-will-soon-be-
the-longest-lived-people-in-the-world
Europe | Charlemagne
For several years in the early 1990s Deng Xiaoping ran China despite having
no formal title other than Most Honorary President of the Chinese Bridge
Association. The European Union today is roughly the opposite: a place
crawling with presidents, yet nobody in charge. An unexpected power
vacuum has befallen the continent in the midst of ongoing war, a budding
trade spat with China and a nerve-jangling election in America. Whether in
Brussels or in national capitals, those on hand are otherwise engaged,
usually with their own domestic difficulties. Can someone—anyone—step
up to lead Europe?
It has long been hard to work out whom to call if you want to speak to
Europe. But that is in fact one of its charms. In centuries gone by,
establishing who had the upper hand on the continent used to involve
gauging whose troops had made the furthest inroads into its neighbours’
territory (Germany, often). After the second world war, when fighting gave
way to EU meetings convened to discuss the format of future EU meetings, the
question of “Who runs Europe?” usually gave rise to a cacophonous answer.
Federalists like to think it is the leaders of the bloc’s main institutions in
Brussels. Brits always suspected it was the Franco-German axis, which they
never managed to crack. The French think the EU is led by, naturellement, the
French; Germans stand knowingly in the corner, happy to let them believe it.
Nationalist types like Viktor Orban of Hungary or Giorgia Meloni of Italy
are quite sure their time has come, given a recent rightward shift in
European elections. Members of the European Parliament are adamant it
should be them. The correct answer is in permanent flux, keeping Brussels-
based journalists gainfully employed.
Alas, all the putative leaders are currently hobbled. The most swiftly
debased leader of Europe is Emmanuel Macron. Upon re-election to the
French presidency two years ago, he stood as the union’s standard-bearer.
Here was a national leader from a large country proud to stand in front of an
EU flag, always willing to opine (often at some length) about the future of
Europe. That his fading popularity at home would dent his credibility in EU
circles was always expected. But his calling of a snap parliamentary election
due on June 30th and July 7th has raised the prospect of a messy
“cohabitation” between Mr Macron and a prime minister from a rival party,
quite possibly from the hard right. What then for Europe? Nobody is quite
sure, given how much the EU has evolved since 1997-2002, when France last
split its top jobs. Although the president would maintain his purview on
foreign affairs and keep attending summits of European leaders, that is only
part of the story. The nitty-gritty of EU legislation is hammered out at
meetings of ministers, which would be attended by French representatives
from that rival team. France seems likely to export its domestic gridlock to
the continental level, even ahead of the presidential poll in 2027.
(the term is used loosely in Brussels) to lead the commission, chair meetings
of EU leaders and preside over the parliament. They were expected to give the
nod to Ursula von der Leyen for another five-year term heading the
commission. Yet agreement proved strangely elusive. Most probably she
will be nominated when leaders meet again on June 27th. But even assuming
the parliament backs her next month—which is not yet guaranteed—Mrs
von der Leyen will spend much of the rest of the year haggling with national
capitals and MEPs to build a team of commissioners.
To stay on top of the biggest European stories, sign up to Café Europa, our
weekly subscriber-only newsletter.
This article was downloaded by zlibrary from https://www.economist.com/europe/2024/06/20/europe-today-is-a-case-of-lots-of-
presidents-yet-nobody-leading
Britain
Britain’s Conservatives rule the Thames Estuary. Not for long
What taxes might Labour raise?
Child poverty will be a test of Labour’s fiscal prudence
Climate change casts a shadow over Britain’s biggest food export
Jeremy Corbyn wants more nice things, fewer nasty ones
The silence of the bedpans
Britain’s Conservatives are losing as they governed. Meekly
Britain | Britain’s general election
Rainham, Rehman Chishti, did not turn up. He skipped another hustings four
days later. If he loses the seat on July 4th, it will be partly for lack of trying.
Sir Keir Starmer launched Labour’s election campaign in Gillingham, east of
London in the Thames Estuary. He pronounced the name correctly (the first G
is soft) and cracked a lame joke about the local football team. A
constituency poll for The Economist by WeThink suggests he will be amply
rewarded. It puts Labour on 55%, the Conservatives on 23% and Reform UK,
an anti-immigration party, on 15% (see chart). If there is a glimmer of hope
for the Tories, it is that many undecided voters plumped for them in 2019.
See our other coverage of Britain’s election, including our poll tracker,
updated daily
That Labour has any chance is extraordinary. Mr Chishti won 61% of the
vote in 2019, against only 28% for Labour. Gillingham and Rainham is part
of an almost solid block of Tory seats east of London (see map). But this
part of England has seen violent political swings before. Its willingness to
abandon the Tories this year points to a problem with the government’s
regional strategy. It also hints at a change in the politics of immigration.
The Thames Estuary is not, to put it politely, the prettiest corner of England.
Things that London needs but does not want end up there: power stations,
wind farms, sewage-treatment works. Its flat grey-brown marshes are filled
with rotting boats and a rare creature known as a tentacled lagoon worm.
The opening scene in Charles Dickens’s novel “Great Expectations”, in
which Magwitch emerges from the marsh to terrify Pip, is set in the seat next
to Gillingham and Rainham.
Its abiding appeal is cheapness. Property values drop quickly as you travel
east from the capital. Semi-detached houses go for £346,000 ($440,000) in
the Medway local authority area compared with £640,000 in London,
according to the Office for National Statistics. As the expectation of
commuting five days a week crumbles, city workers are drifting out.
Spencer Fortag, the director of Dockside estate agents, says that about half
of the buyers in Kitchener Barracks, a new housing development just west of
Gillingham, are Londoners.
The Thames Estuary is a place without snobbery, where you can refashion
yourself superficially or profoundly. Gillingham is not short of nail and
tanning salons, and it contains so many barbers that some of the candidates
in St Margaret’s mused about limiting the numbers. Modified cars roar along
the roads. Mr Chishti, who was born in Pakistan, talks about arriving at the
age of six with only a few words of English, and succeeding through
education.
This rootless, ambitious culture might explain something about the politics
of the area. Gillingham voted for Labour when it was fashionable, in 1945
and 1997. As the country moved right after the millennium, so did local
voters, but more enthusiastically than elsewhere. A forthcoming book by
Jamie Furlong and Will Jennings, “The Changing Electoral Map of England
and Wales”, describes the Thames Estuary as peculiarly Conservative—
more than you would expect from looking at things like its age profile and
the jobs people do. It is like the rest of England, only more so.
Another unusual thing about the estuary is how fast its population is
changing. Of the five local authorities in England and Wales where the
proportion of white Britons declined most between the censuses of 2011 and
2021, three abut the River Thames. Jason Warner, a teacher who works for a
charity called Medway Culture Club, says that local schools are far more
diverse than the overall population, partly because ambitious black and
Asian parents in suburban London send their children to Kent’s selective
grammar schools.
Gareth Harris and Eric Kaufmann, two political scientists, have argued that
white Britons’ anxieties about immigration and ethnic change often take the
form of a “halo effect”. Those who live in ethnically diverse areas are
relaxed; those who live in more homogeneous areas nearby are not. They
may express their anxieties by voting for parties to the Conservative Party’s
right: the British National Party (BNP), the UK Independence Party (UKIP), the
Brexit Party and now Reform UK.
As the Thames Estuary grows more mixed, the zone of anxiety seems to be
concentrating to the east. Two decades ago the BNP won 12 council seats in
Barking and Dagenham, in east London. A decade ago UKIP won a by-election
in Rochester and Strood, next to Gillingham and Rainham. Now Nigel
Farage of Reform UK pins his hopes on Clacton, on the coast north-east of the
estuary. Anti-immigration fervour, like silt, has piled up downriver. ■
For more expert analysis of the biggest stories in Britain, sign up to Blighty,
our weekly subscriber-only newsletter.
This article was downloaded by zlibrary from https://www.economist.com/britain/2024/06/18/britains-conservatives-rule-the-
thames-estuary-not-for-long
Britain | Filling the fiscal hole
To win big in general elections, the Labour Party needs to convince fretful
voters that it can be trusted with the economy. Clement Attlee sold post-war
nationalisations with the mien of a staid bank manager. Ahead of the party’s
landslide win in 1997, New Labour pledged to copy years of restrictive Tory
spending targets. Rachel Reeves, the shadow chancellor, has adopted a
similar tactic ahead of Labour’s widely expected election win on July 4th.
Squaring that with Labour’s pledge not to return to austerity will be tricky.
The commitments that New Labour inherited were a squeeze; those that Ms
Reeves has signed up to are suffocating. They imply hefty real-terms cuts to
frayed courts, policing and local government. The Institute for Fiscal Studies
(IFS), a think-tank, reckons that it would cost around £30bn extra annually by
2028 to prevent them.
Labour says that growth, not tax, is the answer. But it takes time for growth-
enhancing policies to have an effect and the OBR’s GDP projections are already
bullish compared with those of other forecasters. Falling interest rates could
also help a little by pulling down debt-servicing costs. Year-on-year inflation
stood at 2% in May, back in line with the Bank of England’s (BoE’s) official
target. The IFS estimates that a one-percentage-point decline in gilt yields
would boost fiscal headroom by £12bn. But rates will not reliably fall.
That leaves two other options: more borrowing or higher taxes. Labour is
likely to opt for a bit of both. Britain’s fiscal rules are pretty loose for those
willing to stretch them. The binding fiscal rule governs borrowing only in
the last year of the OBR forecast. A short-term borrowing spree spent on public
investment would comply with the rules Ms Reeves has committed to. A
more radical option would be to change how the BoE books its quantitative-
easing (QE) losses, which are projected to cost around £20bn per year until
2032. Most rich countries realise them more gradually, reducing their fiscal
impact.
Still, too large a borrowing splurge would be foolish when interest rates are
so high. Labour will also be especially wary of denting its aura of fiscal
credibility. That leaves taxes. Post-election tax hikes are a well-worn
political formula. Within a year of being elected British governments have
raised taxes by 0.5% of GDP on average since 1979, The Economist calculates
(see chart). That would be around £14bn today.
three, as well as of corporation tax (though it may have left some room in its
manifesto wording to fiddle with income-tax thresholds).
Capital-gains tax (CGT) looks a more likely target. Labour has said it has no
plans to raise CGT but ruled it out firmly only for primary homes. Secrecy here
has a valid economic rationale: asset-holders could cash out early if an
increase were pre-announced. And there are also some grounds for raising it:
capital gains are taxed at a much lower rate than salary or dividend income.
But Labour should tread lightly; capital can be flighty and a high CGT rate may
deter investment. Increases should also be coupled with reforms to ensure
that only returns above inflation are taxed. Fully equalising CGT with income
taxes, and taxing only non-inflationary gains, would raise £16.7bn annually,
says Arun Advani of Warwick University.
Labour will probably opt for a jumble of smaller levies, too. “The Treasury
is quite creative,” says Thomas Pope of the Institute for Government,
another think-tank; mandarins won’t struggle to conjure up new taxes. The
challenge is doing so without further distorting the economy and
complicating the tax code.
Thankfully, however, Ms Reeves has ruled out another stealth tax: tiering
Bank of England reserves so that banks are paid interest on only a fraction of
them. That proposal is central to the economic plans of Reform UK, Nigel
Farage’s populist outfit. It is in effect a tax on banks, but far more
convoluted than a direct levy. It risks gumming up the transmission of
monetary policy as well as turning QE into a reliable money-spinner for the
Treasury.
It looks likely that a Labour government would try to muddle through with a
bit more borrowing, a sprinkling of tax rises and a little trimming to
spending, in the hope that growth will eventually change the fiscal picture.
But it will struggle to skirt tougher choices. If Labour wants to make swift
progress on improving public services and alleviating poverty, more money
will be needed. And although the forces squeezing the British state—most
obviously, the impact of an ageing population—have featured only
sporadically in the campaign, they will be inescapable in government. ■
For more expert analysis of the biggest stories in Britain, sign up to Blighty,
our weekly subscriber-only newsletter.
This article was downloaded by zlibrary from https://www.economist.com/britain/2024/06/20/what-taxes-might-labour-raise
Britain | Expectation management
For a taste of the pressures that Labour will almost certainly soon be
grappling with, watch a recent interview with Sir Keir Starmer on Sky
News, a broadcaster. Pushed on how he would help families struggling with
rising taxes and high energy bills, the Labour leader asked voters to trust his
instincts: “It’s about who do you have in your mind’s eye?” The interviewer
moved swiftly onto child poverty: could Sir Keir pledge to remove the two-
child limit, which means families on benefits get no extra support beyond
their second child? “I’m not going to make promises that I can’t keep,” he
said.
Sir Keir and his shadow chancellor, Rachel Reeves, have spent years
building a reputation for fiscal prudence. As a result they now face the
prospect of being elected by millions of voters they are bound to disappoint.
Tackling poverty would not be the only let-down but it is a good case study
of how a Labour government would struggle without money. There are few
more urgent causes for the party’s core voters, many of whom work in
public services and charities. It is the reason many activists and MPs—and
several members of the shadow cabinet—got involved in politics. But the
best the party can offer, at least for now, is modest change.
See our other coverage of Britain’s election, including our poll tracker,
updated daily
It is true, as Sir Keir likes to point out, that the last Labour government was
successful in reducing poverty, particularly among children and pensioners.
But that government made little progress in its first term between 1997 and
2001 because, as now, it had committed to tight Conservative spending
plans. When it did start lifting people out of hardship, it was due to a
booming economy spurred by global tailwinds. That allowed it to “throw
money at the problem”, says Mike Brewer of the Resolution Foundation, a
think-tank.
Set against this backdrop, Labour’s proposals are timid. None of its five
missions focuses on poverty. Its manifesto calls the mass dependence on
food parcels a “moral scar on our society” but says little about fixing it. The
party wants to develop an “ambitious strategy to reduce child poverty” but
so far it has pledged an extra £315m ($400m) for free breakfast clubs
(around 90p per pupil per day, depending on take-up). It will review
Universal Credit, a welfare payment, so that it “makes work pay and tackles
poverty”. Even if growth does tick up, there is little prospect that Sir Keir
will find himself atop a government flush with cash, as happened in the
2000s.
The manifesto does offer one clue about how Labour may be thinking about
squaring this circle, although it is not a promising one. The party says it will
enact the socio-economic duty in the Equality Act of 2010, which would
require public bodies to “have due regard” to the outcomes of all their
decisions on inequality. That is more likely to gum up decision-making than
to tackle poverty. A review of its implementation in Scotland and Wales
found it had just created more paperwork.
In the near term the two-child limit is likely to become a totemic issue.
There is plenty of evidence that this policy, which came into force in 2017
and was designed to encourage parents on low incomes to work more or
have fewer children, has simply pushed children in large families into
poverty. That ends up costing the state more. According to the Institute for
Fiscal Studies, another think-tank, scrapping it would lift around 500,000
children out of poverty and cost £3.4bn per year by the end of the
parliament. For now Sir Keir is making no promises. It is hard to see that
position being tenable for long. ■
For more expert analysis of the biggest stories in Britain, sign up to Blighty,
our weekly subscriber-only newsletter.
This article was downloaded by zlibrary from https://www.economist.com/britain/2024/06/20/child-poverty-will-be-a-test-of-
labours-fiscal-prudence
Britain | Death and salmon
Spend time on the west coast of Scotland and it won’t be long before you
spot them. Dotting the region’s lochs and bays, salmon farms are big
business. Tourists and locals grumble that they spoil the views. But
according to the Scottish government, the industry is worth more than £1bn
($1.3bn) annually and supports around 12,000 jobs. Last year salmon—
almost all of it reared in Scotland—was Britain’s biggest food export, well
ahead of cheddar and lamb.
A shadow lies across the industry, however. Data from Scotland’s Fish
Health Inspectorate show a sharp increase in the number of premature
salmon deaths in saltwater farms in recent years. More than 10m farmed
salmon died offshore in both 2022 and 2023, well above the average for the
previous six years. (Include freshwater farms, where vulnerable juveniles are
reared, and the figure is higher.) Figures from Salmon Scotland, a trade
body, show that the mortality rate roughly doubled between 2018 and 2023,
from 1.18% to 2.35%. Mass die-offs, in which many salmon perish in a
short period, play a big role in boosting these numbers; last autumn one farm
near the Isle of Colonsay reported more than 200,000 deaths in a week.
Salmon farmers are trying out a variety of solutions. Some are putting
sturdier enclosures further offshore. Deeper, cooler waters and stronger
currents could offer fish a healthier environment, though these sites are
harder to monitor. One firm is trying to build huge underground tanks on the
Isle of Lewis for farming salmon onshore, but such projects are costly. Other
methods—such as placing nets in protective mesh sacks—have had mixed
results.
Scottish salmon farmers are not the only ones hit by rising mortality rates.
Gerald Singh, the co-author of a new paper on salmon deaths, says that mass
die-offs are occurring elsewhere. Everywhere he and his fellow authors
looked, they “saw these increased trends, both in terms of the frequency of
these major events and the increased scale of them”. But few countries have
as much riding on the health of the industry, and of the fish within it. ■
For more expert analysis of the biggest stories in Britain, sign up to Blighty,
our weekly subscriber-only newsletter.
This article was downloaded by zlibrary from https://www.economist.com/britain/2024/06/17/climate-change-casts-a-shadow-over-
britains-biggest-food-export
Britain | Oh, Jeremy Corbyn
Jeremy Corbyn is a good man. You can tell because he has a beard and
sandals and he writes poetry. His writings brim with goodness. In his
manifesto he preaches “compassion”, “peace”, “equality”, “democracy” and
other nice abstract nouns. But he has a stern side: he does not like
“injustice”, “cruel” things or “greed”. He is stalwart: such feelings have
made him again run for election to be the MP for “the people of Islington
North”, though presumably not for the greedy ones.
Mr Corbyn used to stand not just for abstract nouns but also—though his
manifesto falls a little quiet on this point—for the Labour Party, which he
led between 2015 and 2020. In that time he presided over not only Labour’s
worst election defeat by number of seats since 1935 but also an alleged rise
in antisemitism, which critics felt smacked less of “equality” and
“compassion” than of rather nastier things. Under his successor, Sir Keir
Starmer, Labour first banned him from being a candidate and later booted
him out of the party. In this election, Mr Corbyn is offering himself as an
independent. He is also offering “hope”, for hope is “very precious”. Which
is a little piece of poetry in itself.
See our other coverage of Britain’s election, including our poll tracker,
updated daily
George Orwell wrote that at one point all socialist thought was Utopian. You
can see the sunlit uplands gleaming in Mr Corbyn’s prose. But for most
Britons the far-leftie who might have been prime minister feels dystopian, a
token of quite how unhinged British politics became in recent years. Other
reminders lurk. Liz Truss is still standing for election; Boris Johnson still
writes a weekly newspaper column. There is nothing in the rules to stop
them, save perhaps a sense of embarrassment. As Pericles wrote, unwritten
rules bring “undeniable shame to the transgressors”.
But then Pericles hadn’t encountered Mr Corbyn. And so, on a brisk June
day, a small gaggle of supporters has gathered in north London to canvas for
him. There are elderly men with grey beards and fleeces, and elderly women
with low heels and high principles. When Mr Corbyn arrives, they clap.
Jeremy, one says, has a “good heart”.
His goodness is also evident in the things for which he campaigns, such as
“our NHS”, “our schools” and “our ticket offices”. A politician of the
possessive pronoun, he speaks of “our” this and “our” that a lot. (“The rich”
are not embraced in this way; they possess enough already.) He is
campaigning for democracy, which brings “inclusivity” and “co-operation”.
Though when The Economist arrives, his reaction—“Could you stand back,
please?” and “Can you leave it then?”—doesn’t feel that inclusive. The
whole of the press, says a canvasser, is against Mr Corbyn. Which is
unfathomable. As he is a good man. ■
For more expert analysis of the biggest stories in Britain, sign up to Blighty,
our weekly subscriber-only newsletter.
This article was downloaded by zlibrary from https://www.economist.com/britain/2024/06/19/jeremy-corbyn-wants-more-nice-things-
fewer-nasty-ones
Britain | Without a care
Some politicians have made efforts to fix the problem. The last prime
minister but one, Boris Johnson, deserves rare credit for introducing a health
and social-care levy to raise money for the ailing sector. He also pledged a
cap on the costs of care that people bear for themselves—one in seven over-
65s face bills of more than £100,000 ($126,700). But in this election, social
care is conspicuous mainly by its absence.
See our other coverage of Britain’s election, including our poll tracker,
updated daily
The Conservative Party, having delayed the cap and scrapped the levy at the
same time as they jettisoned Mr Johnson, would rather avoid the subject.
Labour’s “Ming vase” strategy involves treading as cautiously as if carrying
priceless porcelain across a slippery floor. The silence around social care is a
good way to understand the shortcomings of the campaign as a whole.
Self-imposed fiscal constraints are one reason why the topic is being
dodged. Both big parties pledge not to raise broad-based taxes; the
Conservatives are committed to further cuts to national insurance, the
payroll tax that Mr Johnson had wanted to raise. As a result neither party
promises lots of extra spending on adult social care, even though the
outgoing Tory government’s spending plans would probably mean further
cuts for local councils and an ageing population will only increase demand
for care.
Public ignorance about how the system works also enables the parties to
paper over the subject. Since no one knows how long they will live or how
great their needs will be, the current system is like “standing in a road with a
lorry driving towards you and hoping you die before the lorry hits you”, says
Andrew Dilnot, an economist who first proposed a cap on care costs way
back in 2011. Most Britons do not realise—or do not care—how much
financial risk they are running until they or a relative has to navigate the
system.
These factors explain why the Conservatives and Labour have given social
care only cursory attention. The Tory manifesto offers a paragraph with no
new commitments, though it does repeat the promise to implement Mr
Dilnot’s cap on care costs. Labour’s manifesto is similarly flimsy; Wes
Streeting, the shadow health secretary, admitted on June 16th that it could
have been “more ambitious”. Among other things it promises to crack down
on poor-quality providers as part of a vaguely defined “National Care
Service”. It is offering “a plan for a plan”, says Simon Bottery of The King’s
Fund, a think-tank.
The Liberal Democrats, whose leader, Sir Ed Davey, is himself a carer for
his disabled son, are the only party aside from the Greens to have offered a
substantive plan. But the Lib Dems’ proposal for free personal care would
require much more funding than the £2.7bn (0.1% of GDP) they have set aside;
in Scotland, which has already implemented a similar policy, personal care
appears to be being rationed. And smaller parties can in any case afford to be
bolder.
Squint a little and the letters “UwU” resemble someone with large,
cartoonish eyes and a serene smile. The cutesy emoticon is a staple of a
certain corner of the internet, in which grown-ups speak to each other in an
infantile tone (“I’m just a smol bean”) and adopt feigned helplessness.
Helplessness has now become an electoral strategy. Some polls suggest that
Labour could end up with a majority bigger than any in the modern era.
Grant Shapps, the defence secretary, has worried aloud about the threat of a
Labour “supermajority”. “It doesn’t do the country any good to have that
kind of size majority,” he chided. Party elders joined in. “It would be
parliamentary democracy in its weakest form since the 1930s,” warned Lord
Hague, a former party leader turned columnist. Pwease halp.
If the Conservatives are puny in their own minds, then Labour is mighty.
The Conservatives have taken to warning of two decades of socialist
imperium under Sir Keir Starmer’s Labour Party. Fears that a government
will go wild with executive power, gerrymandering the voting system and
stacking the House of Lords, are as much projection as anything else. The
Conservatives repeatedly tried to drag authority to the centre. Brexit-related
legislation, for example, was littered with “Henry VIII” powers, designed to
allow government ministers to hack away laws at will. But they have gone
largely unused by the Conservatives. A new government may be more
ruthless. If Labour does decide to run amok, the Tories will be partly to
blame.
Even the lightest legislation proved too heavy for a smol government. A
proposed ban on foie gras never became law. Limits on plastic wet wipes
also went nowhere. When asked about his legacy, Rishi Sunak, the prime
minister, alighted on his plan to ban smoking for anyone born after January
1st 2009. Yet the smoking bill is not law because Mr Sunak himself abruptly
halted its progress by calling an election he will surely lose. “That’s the type
of leadership that I bring,” he said, altogether too accurately. This lack of
legislative legacy is, naturally, someone else’s fault. “Blairite legislation has
tied the hands of the government,” complained Miriam Cates, a backbench
Tory MP. Less UwU, more (>_<).
For more expert analysis of the biggest stories in Britain, sign up to Blighty,
our weekly subscriber-only newsletter.
This article was downloaded by zlibrary from https://www.economist.com/britain/2024/06/19/britains-conservatives-are-losing-as-
they-governed-meekly
International
Brainy Indians are piling into Western universities
International | Attending university abroad
OVER THE past two decades the number of people studying in countries
other than their own has tripled, to more than 6m. International students
from China have caused most of that increase. Youngsters flocked to
universities in English-speaking countries to expand both their minds and
their opportunities. In return they brought valuable brainpower and large
piles of foreign cash. Governments have sometimes viewed this bounty as a
reason to put less of their own money into higher education. Institutions in
Australia, Britain and Canada have grown increasingly reliant on foreign
flows to subsidise research and to cover the costs of educating local
scholars.
Now the market for international study is about to undergo a huge change.
Chinese school-leavers are growing gradually less keen to travel; in their
place, Indian students are becoming the main engine of growth. In 2022
Britain issued more student visas to Indian citizens than they doled out to
Chinese ones (see chart 1). So did America. In both countries, it was the first
time in years that had occurred.
These newcomers have different demands from their East Asian forerunners.
For one thing, Indian students as a group are much more likely to want to
carry on living and working in their host countries even after their courses
end. Economically this could be a boon to labour markets. Politically it
could provoke more heated reactions about foreign students in countries
already riven by immigration debates.
Yet swift expansion has done nothing to improve the poor quality of
teaching and research in many Indian institutions. No Indian university
ranks among the world’s top 100, judged by any of the most rigorous league
tables. These take into account things like the quality of research output. The
higher-education system has “islands of excellence”, says N.V. Varghese of
the National University of Educational Planning and Administration in
Delhi. But it also has an “ocean of mediocrity”. Competition for spots at the
best places is furious. Several Indian institutions have rejection rates higher
than America’s Ivy League, including the formidable Indian Institutes of
Technology.
Many Indian students see better prospects abroad. They are finding it ever
easier to finance their ambitions. Banks are growing more willing to issue
student loans for foreign study. This is in part because of examples set by a
fast-expanding gaggle of non-bank financial firms, says Aman Singh of
GradRight, which helps students pick between them.
These new outfits are less likely to require collateral. Instead they are more
inclined to make lending decisions using data about a student’s chosen
subject and destination, rather than seeking out information about their
family wealth. But plenty of people still end up making big sacrifices.
Farmers sometimes sell fields to fund their children’s travels, says Saif Iqbal
of ApplyBoard, a Canadian edtech firm.
Western universities also think Indian students may help to maintain demand
for their expensive degrees even as migrations from China plateau. For years
analysts have warned that a decades-long boom in Chinese arrivals might be
nearing its peak; the pandemic may well have accelerated that. China’s
youth population is shrinking. Its own universities are improving fast. And
as relations with the West grow more tense, Chinese students abroad may no
longer feel as welcome as they once did. There are also related concerns that
Chinese employers will stop seeing Western degrees as an asset.
Yet if the newcomers bring opportunity, they also present new risks. The
single largest threat is that shifts in the countries that send international
students affect how willing voters in receiving countries are to accept them.
Debates about immigration in rich countries are increasingly toxic. As the
numbers of international students rise, the more often they are drawn into
these rows.
Indeed, Indian students differ from their Chinese counterparts in ways that
seem likely to inflame these fights. The Indians are far less wealthy, for a
start. They usually favour more affordable, lower-tier universities and
incline towards shorter courses. They are much more likely, for example, to
study at postgraduate level than as undergraduates. That is because funding a
one- or two-year master’s is more manageable than funding a full bachelor’s
degree overseas. In Britain, a typical Indian student spends only about half
as much on tuition fees as a Chinese one.
Indian students are also much keener than Chinese ones to remain in the
countries where they have studied after graduation. Most big destination
countries operate some kind of “post-study” visa scheme, which permits
youngsters to stay on for a few years after they graduate, often with few
strings attached. The Chinese, who tend to head home quickly, did not make
great use of these. Indians, by contrast, are very keen on them. They look for
these schemes when deciding where in the world to study. Their terms can
affect how willing lenders are to give Indian students the money they need to
pay course fees.
Class action
Such measures are not unprecedented as governments frequently blow hot
and cold about international students. Some think the latest round of
tightening is simply another swing in that same old cycle. But Matt Durnin
of Nous, a consultancy with offices in Australia, Britain and elsewhere,
reckons something more fundamental is afoot. For years Western countries
grew accustomed to students who were cash rich, and who headed home the
day after graduation. Now they are realising that “the game is completely
different”.
The risk is that rich countries will increasingly shun their opportunities to
snaffle bright young things. And, worse, that they do so without revisiting
the funding settlements that have made their universities ever more reliant
on income from overseas. Given the growth-boosting power of big, zingy
universities, that would be a foolish mistake. ■
Stay on top of our India coverage by signing up to Essential India, our free
weekly newsletter.
This article was downloaded by zlibrary from https://www.economist.com/international/2024/06/20/brainy-indians-are-piling-into-
western-universities
Business
China’s giant solar industry is in turmoil
Floating solar has a bright future
India’s electronics industry is surging
The cautionary tale of Huy Fong’s hot sauce
European airlines are on a shopping spree
Nvidia is now the world’s most valuable company
Are manufacturing jobs really that good?
Palmer Luckey and Anduril want to shake up armsmaking
Business | Solar coaster
China’s solar industry is dominant across every stage of the global supply
chain, from the polysilicon to the finished product. Module production
capacity in the country reached roughly 1,000 gigawatts (GW) last year, almost
five times that of the rest of the world combined, according to Wood
Mackenzie, a consultancy. What is more, it has tripled since 2021,
outgrowing the rest of the world, despite efforts by America and others to
boost domestic production. China is now able to produce more than twice as
many solar modules as the world installs each year.
This massive expansion in supply has helped drive down the cost of
renewable energy for consumers, acting as a counterweight to the rising cost
of capital needed to develop solar farms. During the covid-19 pandemic the
price of solar modules spiked owing to a shortfall in the supply of
polysilicon. Since then, however, the global price has fallen to a record low
of less than 10 cents per watt, according to PVInsights, a data provider (see
chart 1).
Yet the rapid growth of Chinese capacity, which has outpaced global
demand, has also squeezed much of the profit out of the industry.
Polysilicon, wafers, cells and finished modules now sell below their average
production cost. Collapsing prices caused Chinese solar export revenues to
fall by 5.6% last year, according to Wood Mackenzie, even as volumes
soared. LONGi’s share price has slumped by some 60% since the start of 2023.
In March the company said it would fire 5% of its workers, citing an
“increasingly complex and competitive environment”. The share prices of
other Chinese solar giants, including Trina Solar, JA Solar and Jinko Power,
have also been battered (see chart 2).
Smaller companies have been hit even harder. Yana Hryshko of Wood
Mackenzie explains that the big firms are typically diversified, helping them
weather the collapse in solar prices. Others are not so lucky. Lingda, a
smaller manufacturer of solar cells, recently cancelled plans to build a
$1.3bn factory. An executive at one Chinese solar company reckons that at
least half of the businesses across the supply chain will go under.
There are signs such support has been growing more generous, notes Ms
Haley. Some local governments are financing and building solar factories
that they then lease and later sell to companies. Many will be tempted to step
in to prevent local solar champions from going under. That is especially so
given the downturn in China’s property sector, which has strained the
finances of local governments that relied on selling land to developers to
generate income. One industry insider in the inland city of Zhengzhou notes
that officials there have grown more willing to aid solar companies that run
into trouble.
That support may dry up. Many of China’s provinces are struggling to
service their debts. Solar companies must also compete for government
largesse with firms in other industries that are grappling with overcapacity as
China’s economy slows. More than a fifth of Chinese industrial firms were
unprofitable last year, according to analysis by Rhodium, another
consultancy. Efforts to export away China’s overcapacity problem are
encountering resistance abroad. Last month Ursula von der Leyen, the
European Commission’s president, declared “the world cannot absorb
China’s surplus production.” On June 12th the EU announced it would slap
provisional tariffs of between 26% and 48% on Chinese electric vehicles
(EVs).
China’s cut-price solar modules could come in for similar treatment.
America has levied anti-dumping duties on Chinese solar manufacturers
since 2012. Although the EU abandoned similar measures in 2018, some fret
over the continent’s dependence on Chinese solar companies (see chart 3). In
April the bloc agreed to expand subsidies and other support for local solar
manufacturers that have been pummelled by Chinese imports.
Although China’s leaders have contested claims that the country is grappling
with excess supply, there are signs they are aware of it. In a meeting with
business executives and economists last month, Xi Jinping, China’s ruler,
cautioned against focusing resources solely on EVs, batteries and solar
modules—or, as a recent slogan describes them, “new quality productive
forces”—and noted that investments must “have their own merits”.
All this suggests a period of consolidation looms for China’s solar industry.
Jenny Chase of BloombergNEF, a research group, has seen this play out
before. “There are slight profits, then longer periods of terrible margins, then
bankruptcies and exits. We call it the solar coaster.” Demand may eventually
catch up with supply, as lower module prices encourage developers to install
more solar power. In the meantime, China’s solar industry should prepare for
a bumpy ride. ■
To stay on top of the biggest stories in business and technology, sign up to
the Bottom Line, our weekly subscriber-only newsletter.
This article was downloaded by zlibrary from https://www.economist.com/business/2024/06/17/chinas-giant-solar-industry-is-in-
turmoil
Business | Dam good
Drive a few hours from Lisbon towards Spain, past the olive farms, and you
will arrive at Europe’s largest artificial lake, at the Portuguese town of
Alqueva. The first thing that catches the eye is the large hydroelectric dam.
But look closer and you will also spot a bright patch of floating glass. It is
the floating solar-power plant built by EDP, a Portuguese utility that is one of
the world’s biggest developers of renewable energy. Critics have long
dismissed such projects as a costly and trouble-prone experiment. The
technology, however, is now ready to shine.
In this first phase of the project at Alqueva, engineers have stationed some
12,000 photovoltaic (PV) modules on floating pontoons made from partially
recycled plastic and locally sourced cork. These are connected to an energy-
storage system incorporating lithium-ion batteries and integrated with the
hydroelectric dam’s power station.
Floating solar projects like this one do face plenty of challenges. The kit has
to be water-, wave-, wind- and storm-resistant, which adds complexity and
cost. When located on salt water, corrosion can be a problem, though inland
projects in fresh water fare better. The fish in lakes attract plenty of birds,
whose droppings can block the sun. To deal with this, engineers for the
project at Alqueva have developed remote-controlled cleaning robots and
are working on autonomous ones. “Like a Roomba for the panels,” explains
one.
Yet floating solar projects also enjoy several advantages. When they are
located at existing hydroelectric dams they do not require any additional
land, thus evading NIMBY opposition, and can be connected to the grid without
the multi-year wait common for solar projects. The cooling effect of being
on water boosts the efficiency of the modules, with studies suggesting gains
of between 5% and 15% over land-based PV, while the shade they produce
slows the evaporation of the reservoir.
EDPconsiders floating solar one of its “biggest bets”. The five megawatts (MW)
of capacity built in the first phase of its project at Alqueva is, admittedly,
tiny. The company, however, is planning a second phase that would add 70MW
more by 2025. Wood Mackenzie, a consultancy, reckons the technology
could provide 60 gigawatts of renewable-power capacity globally by 2031.
That may not seem much next to the 1.6 terawatts of solar capacity installed
as of last year. But every bit counts.■
Bangalore, home to many of India’s IT giants, is better known for its software
than its hardware. However, the new factories suggest that, in one industry at
least, India’s efforts to transform itself into a manufacturing powerhouse are
bearing fruit. Electronics manufacturing—the business of building mobile
phones, televisions and other gadgets—is thriving in India. The value of
electronics it produced rose from $37bn to $105bn (3% of GDP) between the
fiscal years ending in March 2016 and March 2023 (see chart). The
government wants to triple this again by fiscal 2026. Although India’s
production of electronics accounts for just 3% of the global total, its share is
growing faster than any other country’s.
Nowhere is this boom more evident than in the production of phones, which
makes up nearly half of India’s electronics industry. The country is the
world’s second-largest maker of the devices, trailing only China. In fiscal
2015 India imported almost four-fifths of its phones. It now imports barely
any. Apple sources about one in seven of its iPhones from India, double
what it did a year ago. Samsung, a South Korean rival, has its largest phone-
making facility in the country.
It is not only foreign firms that have piled in. Tata first entered phone-
making in 2021 by building parts for older models of the iPhone. After
initial issues with quality control, the company has found its footing. In
November it acquired the Indian operations of Wistron, a Taiwanese firm,
and began assembling iPhones. Tata now plans to expand its factories to nab
a larger share of business with Apple.
Sunil Vachani, Dixon’s boss, credits the government for its belief in India’s
manufacturing potential, which he says has brought about “a change in the
mindset” of the country. India’s government has certainly been busy wooing
foreign manufacturers. In January it awarded the Padma Bhushan, the
country’s third-highest civilian award, to Mr Liu of Foxconn. Pranay
Kotasthane of the Takshashila Institution, a think-tank in Bangalore, says the
government has been courting companies such as Foxconn to lure in “anchor
investors” around which supply chains can form.
The hope is that India will one day be able to dislodge China as the world’s
electronics factory. Narendra Modi’s electoral setback earlier this month, in
which the prime minister lost his parliamentary majority, does not appear to
have dampened enthusiasm for that goal. His new government has signalled
continuity in its support for manufacturing.
For his part, Mr Vachani of Dixon is bullish. He believes that “this a Y2K
moment” for India’s electronic manufacturing, a reference to the panic over
a computer bug at the turn of the century that put the wind in the sails of
India’s IT industry. Perhaps, in time, the term “Bangalored” could refer not, as
today, to the draining of white-collar jobs away from America, but of blue-
collar ones from China. ■
Sweet and spicy with a sour tinge, sriracha sauce was an instant hit when
David Tran, a Vietnamese refugee, brought it to America in the 1980s under
the brand Huy Fong Foods. Asian eateries were the first to snap up Mr
Tran’s hot sauce, but before long the green-nozzled bottle, with its
distinctive rooster logo, had become a staple in restaurants and pantries
alike. Within just a few years Mr Tran went from hawking his wares out of a
Chevy van in Los Angeles to walking the floor of a 20,000-square-metre
factory. By 2020 his business was worth $1bn.
For decades Huy Fong set its sriracha apart with fresh jalapeños reddened on
the vine, a difficult commodity to grow at scale. Competitors turned to dried
chillies. Mr Tran turned to Craig Underwood, a Californian with a penchant
for peppers. For 28 years Underwood Ranches, his company, met all Huy
Fong’s jalapeño needs, at one point producing close to 45,000 tonnes a year.
To fill Huy Fong’s bottles, Underwood Ranches expanded its acreage ten-
fold. The two men became chums. In 2017, however, the relationship soured
following a disagreement between Mr Tran and Mr Underwood over
financial terms.
Competitors have been all too willing to step into the gap left by the sriracha
pioneer. McIlhenny, which makes Tabasco, a rival hot sauce, began peddling
its own sriracha product with a campaign promising “no shortage of flavour
inspiration”. In the second half of last year its condiment was the bestselling
sriracha sauce in America. Other brands have had a boost, too. Even
Underwood Ranches has piled in with its own product, trading on its
reputation as Huy Fong’s erstwhile supplier. If there is one lesson from Mr
Tran’s debacle, then, it is to keep your friends close—and your jalapeños
closer.■
Some corporate tie-ups delight investors. Others make them groan. The
purchase of a 41% stake in ITA, Italy’s national airline, by Lufthansa, a
German carrier, for €325m ($350m) is an example of the latter. Rumours
that the EU is close to blessing the deal have contributed to a slump in
Lufthansa’s share price.
, once called Alitalia, is hardly a crown jewel. Since its founding in 1946 it
ITA
has turned an annual profit only three times. The Italian government
privatised the company in 2009—then renationalised it in 2020, rebranding
it as ITA in the hope of a fresh start. Air France-KLM and Etihad, two airline
businesses that had taken minority stakes in the carrier, wrote off their
investments. The Italian government spent around €3.5bn during the covid-
19 pandemic to keep the company aloft, equivalent to roughly €300,000 per
employee.
Why, then, is Lufthansa pursuing a deal? It argues that Italy is one of the
company’s biggest markets, and that ITA’s routes to Africa and South America
complement Lufthansa’s routes to North America and East Asia. It adds that
it already owns another small Italian airline, Air Dolomiti, which means it is
familiar with the market. A further motivation may be Lufthansa’s fear that
ITA could fall into the hands of a rival.
All this worries the European Commission, the EU’s executive arm. It is
concerned that consolidation will lead to higher fares and less choice for
European consumers, which is why it has been probing the ITA and Air
Europa deals. A decision on the first of these is expected by July 4th, and on
the second by August 20th. Both IAG and Lufthansa have been dangling
concessions. IAG has offered to relinquish just over half of Air Europa’s
landing slots. Lufthansa has reportedly said it will cede around 40 slots at
Linate airport in Milan to EasyJet and Volotea, another low-cost airline. It
has proposed to keep a number of ITA’s short-haul flights to Austria, Belgium,
Germany and Switzerland that compete with its own flights. And it plans to
delay integrating ITA into its transatlantic joint venture with United Airlines,
an American carrier, for two years.
Such concessions will only make the ITA deal worse for Lufthansa’s investors.
The German carrier looks to be buying itself a giant headache. Although
ANPAC, the Italian pilots’ union, is supportive of the deal, it is notoriously
difficult to work with. What is more, Italy’s government will remain the
largest investor in the Italian carrier after the deal, at least initially.
Lufthansa will have the option to buy the rest of the company at a later date.
Its investors may pray it doesn’t. ■
The argument that manufacturing jobs are better than other sorts has a long
pedigree. Adam Smith believed that manufacturing was “productive”, unlike
services such as banking, retail or hospitality. The factories of the Industrial
Revolution transformed living standards in Europe and America in the 19th
century. Yet they were also awful places for workers, managing to be both
horribly dangerous and tremendously boring. Things did not get much better
with the rise of mass-production in the early 20th century. Workers in Henry
Ford’s carmaking plants, though relatively well paid, complained that work
was stultifying. As one Ford worker noted, “If I keep putting on Nut
Number 86 for about 86 more days, I will be Nut Number 86 in the Pontiac
bughouse.”
Even during the post-war period—paradise lost, in the eyes of many Western
politicians—people were hardly thrilled about working in factories. In 1970
Fortune magazine coined the phrase the “blue-collar blues” to describe the
alienation many manufacturing workers felt in an impersonal industrial
system. One pundit noted that such a worker would be “easy prey for
demagogues who appeal to his resentment and his desire for revenge”,
which sounds familiar.
Manufacturing enthusiasts will no doubt counter that jobs in the sector are
much better today. Workplace accidents occur a fraction as often as they
once did. Most factories are air-conditioned. Robots do many of the heaviest
and most repetitive tasks. And around a third of those who work in
manufacturing never go near a rivet, performing white-collar roles such as
design and engineering.
All that may be so, but compare workers of a similar education level and
there is little evidence they would gain by moving from services to
manufacturing. One paper by statisticians at America’s Bureau of Labour
Statistics found that, across a variety of measures including pay, benefits, job
security and safety, “many industries within services equal or exceed
manufacturing.” This Bartleby’s analysis of British data similarly shows that
job quality in the manufacturing sector is no better than average.
For decades economists observed that manufacturing workers enjoyed a
wage premium over comparable workers in other industries. A recent paper
published by the Federal Reserve, however, shows that this premium has
“disappeared” in recent years. Those who point to the insecurity of gig jobs,
such as delivering takeaway meals, would do well to remember that
manufacturing jobs are often more cyclical than those in services. They are
also more likely to be automated away. It is not immediately obvious that a
job tending to an industrial robot is more satisfying than one operating an
espresso machine at Starbucks, especially for workers who enjoy some
human interaction.
According to Mr Biden, “A job is about a lot more than a pay cheque. It’s
about your dignity. It’s about respect.” That is true. Yet dignity and respect
should be available for workers wherever they are employed. If not,
politicians should focus their attention on ensuring the right regulations are
in place, instead of spending billions of dollars trying to recreate a past that
was far less rosy than they imagine.
A breakthrough came in April when the US Air Force awarded the firm a
contract for the Collaborative Combat Aircraft (CCA) programme, which will
eventually consist of more than 1,000 advanced drones supporting American
fighter jets. For the Pentagon to hand a flagship programme to a startup, and
to jettison the traditional prototype phase, is “extraordinary”, he says. The
war in Ukraine has been a proving ground for these sorts of weapons—and
for Mr Luckey’s company. He visited Kyiv two weeks into the war. “What
we’ve been doing was tailored for exactly the type of fight that’s going on
and exactly what we predicted was going to happen,” he argues, pointing to
three lessons.
One is the importance of drones that can navigate and strike autonomously,
even in the face of heavy jamming of their signals and obscurants like metal-
filled smoke clouds. Many existing drones have struggled with this, says Mr
Luckey, because they lack “multi-modal” sensors, such as optical and
infrared cameras, to substitute for GPS, and do not have enough built-in
computing power to use the latest object-recognition algorithms.
Second is the observation that software is eating the battlefield. Imagine that
Russia begins using a new type of jammer. Mr Luckey says that the data can
be sent back immediately to generate countermeasures, which are then
remotely installed on weapons at the front line without having to change any
hardware. A recent study by the Royal United Services Institute, a think-
tank in London, noted that drones in Ukraine needed to have their software,
sensors and radios updated every six to 12 weeks to remain viable. Anduril,
claims Mr Luckey, is “literally pushing new updates…every single night”.
His third lesson from Ukraine is that weapons must be built in vast
quantities—and therefore cheaply. He laments that Russia produces shells
and missiles far more cheaply than America does: “The US is now on the
wrong side of an issue that we were on the right side of during the cold war.”
Anduril makes much of the fact that its production processes are modelled
not on big aerospace firms, but automotive ones. Its head of manufacturing
is a veteran of Toyota and Tesla, two carmakers. Its submarine drones are
made using welded metal plates rather than a pressure vessel “because that
can be made in something that looks a lot like a General Motors plant rather
than a Lockheed Martin aircraft-assembly facility or a naval shipyard”.
The CCA contract is a huge boost, but it covers only the first, limited tranche of
the project. Moreover, some Ukrainians grumble that software updates have
been slow to arrive, leaving Anduril’s high-end Altius drones bamboozled
by jamming, like other American offerings. Another person familiar with the
firm’s products in Ukraine says that although the company’s software is
impressive, its hardware is less so. Some in the Pentagon are keen to
separate the two so that Anduril’s software can be plugged in more easily to
competitors’ kit. For his part, Mr Luckey complains that America’s
government retains a “caveman mentality” in which it will spend wodges of
money on a high-tech product with remarkable built-in software, but will
recoil in horror at the notion of paying far smaller sums for “just some
code”.
Not droning on
Behind that frustration is a sense of urgency. Many defence bosses revert to
euphemistic blather when asked about their products. Mr Luckey is one of
the rare ones who embraces the fact that they exist to blow things up. He
points to the slogan of one of his teams, “China 27”: products or features
that are not ready for a conflict with America’s rival in 2027 are cast aside.
Mr Luckey’s vision of the future of war fuses two ideas: the centrality of
technology and the need for vast numbers of weapons. “Fifty years from
now the seas are going to be transparent. The skies are going to be
transparent. We’re going to know where every sub is, every airplane is,” he
says. “So then it’s a matter of: who’s going to make enough stuff to beat the
other guy’s stuff.” America is not in a good place, he concludes. “We’re
quite screwed.” Anduril, however, stands ready to help. ■
Is a fresh housing boom under way? In April a house-price index for the
world, excluding China, rose by more than 3% year on year (see chart 1 ).
American house prices are 6.5% higher than a year ago, Australian ones
have increased by 5% and Portuguese ones are soaring. In other countries,
the market looks surprisingly strong given years of high interest rates (see
chart 2).
These figures follow a tough period. Adjusted for inflation, prices have
fallen by 20% in Canada, Germany and New Zealand. They are well off
their peaks in some American cities, including San Francisco and Phoenix.
In Boise, Idaho, where prices soared during the covid-19 pandemic as
people sought living space, values are down by over a tenth. Meanwhile,
higher interest rates, and mortgage costs, have made people worried about
their spending on housing: the share of Britons who say they find it “very”
or “somewhat” difficult to make rent or home-loan payments has risen from
24% in early 2022 to 41%.
Yet it is surprising that things have not been more difficult still. Since a
trough in 2021, the rate on a typical 30-year mortgage in America has risen
by about four percentage points. Rules of thumb derived from the academic
literature indicated that nominal house prices would fall by 30-50%. In fact,
they have hardly fallen at all in nominal terms. In real terms (ie, adjusted for
inflation) global house prices are down by 6% from their peak—but that puts
them in line with their pre-pandemic trend. The downturn also claims the
crown as the shortest ever, lasting just a few months.
Some worry that high rates will eventually cause a proper crash. Rohin
Dhar, a housing expert, has pointed out that many listings in Florida feature
the phrase “motivated”, which implies people are selling in a hurry. But in
America as a whole, the share of mortgages in delinquency has never been
so low, at 1.7%, compared with more than 11% at the height of the global
financial crisis of 2007-09. Elsewhere the situation appears to be similarly
benign. In New Zealand, the rich country that was hit hardest by the housing
downturn, arrears are in line with the pre-covid norm. With the exception of
Germany, there is less distress in the euro zone, too.
But fixed-rate mortgages are not the only reason for housing-market
resilience and recent price growth. After all, applications for new mortgages
remain reasonably strong across much of the world, even if they have fallen
from pandemic highs. And the National Association of Realtors, an
American lobby group, finds surprisingly little evidence that higher rates are
dissuading people from buying a first home or moving into a new one.
According to its recent research, only 8% of people said that “getting a
mortgage” was one of the “most difficult steps” of the home-buying process,
marginally up from 7% in 2021.
Three further factors may explain why house prices are once again rising:
immigration, sacrifices by mortgage-holders and the strength of the
economy. Take immigration first. The rich world’s foreign-born population
is rising by about 4% year on year, its fastest on record. Official figures on
which such calculations are based probably understate the shift, since illegal
immigration has also surged, especially in America. This, in turn, is pushing
up both house prices and rents, argues Mark Zandi of Moody’s Analytics, a
consultancy, as the new arrivals need somewhere to live. Estimates by
Goldman Sachs, a bank, imply that Australia’s current annualised net
migration rate of 500,000 people will raise house prices by around 5%.
The second factor concerns sacrifices. People in the rich world are dealing
with higher mortgage costs by cutting back on other sorts of expenditures. A
recent survey by YouGov, a pollster, found that one in five variable-rate-
mortgage holders in Britain say they are making “large” cuts in household
spending, even as those on fixed-rate deals are less perturbed. Others are
reaching behind the sofa. A recent report by the Norwegian central bank
noted that many households “have drawn on accumulated savings” to
service debt.
Mortgage moaners
The most important factor relates to the economy. True, households are
paying out more in interest, but there is also more coming in. Some benefit
from higher interest income on their savings, which in the EU has risen by
nearly ten times as much as interest payments have since 2020. Unlike in the
housing crash of 2007-09, the labour market is also helping (and the banks
have not imploded). Since 2021 average wages across the rich world have
gone up by about 15%, while unemployment remains close to an all-time
low. In every country for which we can find data, the increase in
households’ labour income in recent years dwarfs increases in interest costs.
No one likes higher mortgage payments, but the vast majority of people can
afford them.
For more expert analysis of the biggest stories in economics, finance and
markets, sign up to Money Talks, our weekly subscriber-only newsletter.
This article was downloaded by zlibrary from https://www.economist.com/finance-and-economics/2024/06/16/why-house-prices-are-
surging-once-again
Finance & economics | Bardella’s potential burden
It was a French politician, Valéry Giscard d’Estaing, who coined the term
“exorbitant privilege” in the 1960s. He was referring to benefits received by
America as issuer of the world’s reserve currency—namely, the ability to run
high deficits comfortably. These days France is reminded it has no such
privilege. Ahead of parliamentary elections on June 30th and July 7th, its
hefty deficit and growing debt are central to the campaign. On June 19th the
European Commission said it was preparing to put France into an excessive-
deficit procedure, the EU’s fiscal torture chamber, meaning the country’s
politicians will have to come up with a plan to fix things.
Now markets are worried. The yield on French debt is similar to that on
Portugal’s and its spread over German bunds, Europe’s benchmark, has
widened to 0.7 percentage points. France’s stockmarket is down by 5% since
the European Parliament elections on June 9th, which prompted Mr Macron
to gamble. Share prices of companies focused on the domestic market have
been hit especially hard. France’s two largest banks, BNP Paribas and Crédit
Agricole, have lost 11% of their value.
How bad will things get? No big political party wants to quit the euro or the
EU. Nor, as French analysts rush to point out, is the country on the brink of a
“Liz Truss moment”, referring to the blowout of British gilt yields after a
mini-budget in September 2022. Foreign buyers of sovereign and corporate
French bonds are staying put. Contrary to warnings from Bruno Le Maire,
the finance minister, even a victory for the hard right or left would be
unlikely to prompt a crisis. France benefits from decent economic growth,
which the OECD expects to be 1.3% next year, and manageable debt-servicing
costs, at 2% of GDP.
The problem is that, without spending cuts, France’s deficit will widen to
5.7% this year and 5.9% next, according to the French senate’s finance
committee. Even if this is not crisis-inducing, it is a large and growing
problem. Mr Le Maire has already cut around €20bn (0.7% of GDP) from state
spending this year, reducing outgoings on things such as energy subsidies
and state aid. Further reductions were put off until after the European
elections.
Both the RN, polling in first place with over 30% of voters, and the left bloc,
at just under 30%, are far ahead of Mr Macron’s centrist alliance, and have
spending plans that would add to the deficit. The right-wingers want to cut
levies on electricity and petrol, and exempt employers from paying taxes if
they raise salaries. The leftists’ ideas are strikingly similar: they want to
raise the minimum wage and bring down energy and food prices. Both
groups also want to repeal Mr Macron’s pension reforms that raised the age
of retirement to 64 from 62, although the RN has rowed back on plans to do so
straight away.
This could lead to a clash with the European Commission and the markets.
Yet if the RN is victorious it might be reined in by the need to attract centre-
right voters, who tend to favour lower deficits, at the crucial presidential
election in 2027. It would also have to negotiate the EU’s next budget, and
would want to keep generous agricultural subsidies, for which it would need
the support of allies. The hope is that, once in power, the RN would mellow in
the manner of Giorgia Meloni, Italy’s hard-right prime minister.
A clash with the commission is thus likely, but also likely to end in
compromise, says Jeromin Zettelmeyer of Bruegel, a think-tank. More
problematic is the fact that even if a party wins a majority in the forthcoming
elections, it will inherit a poisoned chalice. The victor will have to oversee
spending cuts that will harm growth and prove unpopular, or risk chaos.
Although there is no such thing as a bad election to win, the celebrations of
France’s next prime minister may not last long. ■
For more expert analysis of the biggest stories in economics, finance and
markets, sign up to Money Talks, our weekly subscriber-only newsletter.
This article was downloaded by zlibrary from https://www.economist.com/finance-and-economics/2024/06/18/how-bad-could-things-
get-in-france
Finance & economics | Gridlock
As solar panels and wind farms take over Europe, the question facing the
continent’s policymakers is what to do with all the power they produce.
Ultra-low—and indeed negative—prices suggest that it is not being put to
good use at present, reflecting failures in both infrastructure and regulation.
There are three main ways that firms and regulators could establish a more
efficient market: sending energy to areas where there is no surplus, shifting
demand to hours when energy is plentiful, and storing energy as electricity,
fuel or heat.
The need to make such shifts will only become more pressing. Europe’s
renewables boom is bigger than elsewhere in the rich world. Last year the
continent installed roughly twice as much fresh capacity as America, with 56
gigawatts (GW) of new solar power and 17GW of new wind power, which the
latest figures suggest will be exceeded this year. By 2030, 43% of the EU’s
total energy consumption will have to come from renewables, according to
the latest rules, up from 23% in 2022.
The problem is that grid extensions take time and meet local opposition. As
a result, energy firms have resorted to putting them underground, which
raises costs. Extensions also prompt arguments. When a connection is
established, the market with lower electricity prices will inevitably export
power to the one with higher prices. Even if both sides benefit from the
transaction overall, on one side the beneficiary may be electricity producers
and on the other side it may be consumers, with the other group losing out in
both places. On June 18th Sweden cancelled the Hansa PowerBridge, a 700-
megawatt connection to Germany, over fears it would raise electricity prices
for domestic consumers.
The next option for policymakers is to shift demand. This does not mean
persuading everyone to take showers during their lunch breaks, when the sun
is at its brightest. Instead, the idea is to move flexible sources of demand,
such as electric-vehicle (EV) charging and district-heating buffers, into hours
of abundant energy. Doing so requires smart meters that measure not only
how much energy is used, but also when it is used, and which thus allow
prices to vary accordingly. So far, however, countries are making slow
progress installing these devices. Although almost everyone has a smart
meter in Spain, hardly anyone does in Germany.
Could better storage solve the problem? In Vantaa, Finland, the local energy
company is about to dig a hole the size of 440 Olympic swimming pools into
the bedrock beneath the town. This will be filled with water heated to
140°C, which will store 90 gigawatt-hours of heat, an amount sufficient to
keep the town toasty for a year. Other firms are making greater use of
batteries for shorter-term storage. Unfortunately, such schemes are once
again hindered by existing energy-market structures. When it comes to
things such as congestion management and frequency control, markets are
typically built on the expectation that backup capacity will arrive from
conventional gas-fired plants. “The efficient use of surplus electricity is not
considered and not encouraged in Europe,” sighs Julian Jansen of Fluence,
which makes energy-storage products.
For more expert analysis of the biggest stories in economics, finance and
markets, sign up to Money Talks, our weekly subscriber-only newsletter.
This article was downloaded by zlibrary from https://www.economist.com/finance-and-economics/2024/06/20/europe-faces-an-unusual-
problem-ultra-cheap-energy
Finance & economics | Leviathan bound
India’s stockmarket swooned upon the news that Narendra Modi, the
country’s business-friendly prime minister, would return to power
diminished and in a coalition after a recent general election. One benchmark,
though, fell especially sharply and has yet to recover: the Bombay Stock
Exchange’s index for Public Sector Undertakings (BSE PSU). It comprises 56
companies that have some private ownership but remain mostly owned, and
entirely controlled, by the state.
Killing off the leviathan has proved difficult, however. When Mr Modi
entered office in 2014, he vowed to accelerate divestment. His signature
achievement has been the sale in 2021 of Air India to Tata, a vast
conglomerate from which the airline had been expropriated in the 1950s.
More often, deals have stalled owing to suspicion the buyer will be ripped
off by the state or because of objections from vested interests, including
powerful unions, employees who receive benefits such as housing from the
firm in question and politicians who like being able to influence hiring at
state-controlled companies.
The consolation, at least until the election, has been the excellent
performance of many state-owned firms (see chart). Profits at the dozen
state-run banks that are included in the broader PSU index have risen from
$123m in the fiscal year that concluded just before the covid-19 pandemic to
$18bn in the most recent one. Half have a return on equity in excess of 15%,
a rate better than many big global banks, reflecting government-prompted
consolidation and reforms to bankruptcy procedures. Other state-owned
companies have also been run more efficiently.
Why are the stocks now suffering? In part it is because investors fear India’s
new government will be less likely to impose reforms and to insulate the
companies from regional political pressures on matters such as hiring,
lending, factory openings and closings, and even the pricing of sensitive
commodities like electricity, gas and petrol. More voices in government may
also slow down further privatisation.
For more expert analysis of the biggest stories in economics, finance and
markets, sign up to Money Talks, our weekly subscriber-only newsletter.
This article was downloaded by zlibrary from https://www.economist.com/finance-and-economics/2024/06/20/indian-state-capitalism-
looks-to-be-in-trouble
Finance & economics | Sweet gains, bro
Editor’s note (June 20th 2024): The Supreme Court has ruled in Moore v
United States, upholding the tax at issue (the “mandatory repatriation tax”).
The court declined to weigh in on the constitutionality of a tax on unrealised
gains.
WHAT IS INCOME, really? Ask an economist and they might describe “Haig-
Simons” income—the value of a person’s consumption of goods and
services, plus the change in their net worth over a certain period. A lawyer
might refer to Section 61(a) of the IRS Code 26, which defines “gross” income
as “all income from whatever source derived”, including but not limited to
commission, interest, property deals and wages. An accountant might talk
about how to reduce that gross income, via deductions or carve-outs, to a
skinnier “taxable income base”.
Taxman confounded
Low interest rates and booming stockmarkets make a “buy, borrow, die”
strategy particularly attractive. At Morgan Stanley and Bank of America
(BoA), both of which run large wealth-management businesses, the total value
of securities-backed loans to clients leapt from around $80bn in 2018 to
almost $150bn in 2022. Banks are more than happy to make such loans. As
lending tends to be collateralised by securities that can be easily seized and
sold, it is treated as low-risk by regulators.
During the past few years of high interest rates, however, borrowing against
assets has become a riskier proposition. At Morgan Stanley such loans are
structured as revolving lines of credit; three-quarters of them appear to have
floating interest rates. If borrowing adds up to, say, 50% of a portfolio at a
lofty valuation then a rout in the market can leave debtors with nothing. In
2022, after the share price of Peloton collapsed, John Foley, founder of the
exercise-bike firm, ended up scrambling to restructure his loans, selling a
$55m house in the Hamptons just months after he had bought it. At BoA and
Morgan Stanley the value of loans secured in such a manner had crept down
by the end of 2023.
Yet politics, rather than high interest rates, represents the biggest threat to
the strategy. There are three arguments against Mr Biden’s proposal: that it is
unfair, that it is unconstitutional and that it would be an administrative
burden. The fairness argument rests on the idea that unrealised gains are, in
many ways, unreal. After all, the value of assets could change the day after a
tax is paid. This perhaps explains why a survey by academics at New York
University in 2021 found 75% of Americans oppose such taxation.
A clue as to whether the Supreme Court believes that wealth taxes are
constitutional will arrive in the coming days, when justices opine on Moore.
The plaintiffs were taxed under the Tax Cuts and Jobs Act, which was
passed in 2017 and imposed a mandatory repatriation tax on the earnings,
since 1986, of foreign corporations in which American shareholders own at
least 50% of the stock. The levy applies regardless of whether the earnings
were distributed to shareholders.
If the justices side with the plaintiffs, they may stop the push for an
unrealised-gains tax in its tracks. But they seem unlikely to do so. Sonia
Sotomayor, speaking for the court’s liberals, has noted that the concept of
“realisation” was “well established” when the relevant constitutional
amendment was ratified in 1913. As such, the early-20th century lawmakers
could have specified that unrealised assets were to be left alone had that
been what they intended. On top of this, at least two conservative justices
have suggested they will not weigh in on the constitutional point.
As for the idea that wealth taxes on private assets are unworkable, that is too
simplistic. Versions of them are already widely used in America,
undermining arguments that they are impossible to administer in the country.
Levies on property at the local or state level in effect act as taxes on
unrealised capital gains. Every single American state has property taxes,
which range from 0.3% to 2.3% of the property value each year. In more
than half of states, property values are reassessed annually. Mr Biden’s plan
also seeks to minimise headaches. It includes measures to smooth volatility
so that losses incurred in one year can be offset against gains in another.
Still, the bureaucratic effort to levy a new countrywide tax, on a small pool
of people, on every kind of asset they might hold, would be wince-inducing.
Valuing assets such as bonds and stocks is relatively straightforward. But
private assets, whether a Picasso or an investment in a startup, would be
another matter entirely. Adam Michel of the Cato Institute, a libertarian
think-tank, points out that it took 12 years for the IRS and Michael Jackson’s
estate to reach a court-mediated agreement on the value of the late pop star’s
assets. “Going through such a process every year for all taxpayers with
assets near some threshold is unworkable,” he argues. Several European
countries that have tried to levy wealth taxes and ultimately abandoned the
effort have described administrative costs as a reason why.
Thankfully for Mr Biden, there is a less radical alternative that would have
much the same effect as going after unrealised assets. Eliminating the
stepped-up basis, which Mr Biden also hopes to do, would remove lots of
the incentive to buy, borrow and die. It would also probably avoid a serious
legal challenge and be easier to administer. Such a move would raise a
quarter of the sum the president expects his grander plan to fetch. Taxing
capital gains at death would raise another hefty chunk. And closing a few
additional loopholes would just about cover the rest. ■
For more expert analysis of the biggest stories in economics, finance and
markets, sign up to Money Talks, our weekly subscriber-only newsletter.
This article was downloaded by zlibrary from https://www.economist.com/finance-and-economics/2024/06/20/americas-rich-never-
sell-their-assets-how-should-they-be-taxed
Finance & economics | Buttonwood
How can you tell it is time to get out of the market? In 1929 Joseph
Kennedy, an American businessman and politician, supposedly realised the
party was over upon hearing a shoeshine boy dispensing stock tips. In 2000
the exit doors beckoned after 17 “dotcom” firms paid millions of dollars
each for brief advertising slots during the Super Bowl, an American-football
extravaganza.
And so to a sell signal fit for 2024: Keith Gill is back on social media. Mr
Gill was an architect of the meme-stock frenzy of 2021, exhorting retail
traders to buy shares in GameStop, a struggling chain of video-game shops.
After a three-year absence he is posting once again, now apparently in
possession of a stake in the firm worth a few hundred million dollars.
GameStop’s share price has resumed a gut-churning roller-coaster ride and is
up by more than 40% since Mr Gill’s return; the ailing company has made
use of the excitement to issue some $3bn-worth of new shares. If you are
looking for signs of speculative excess in markets, this is Exhibit A.
America’s benchmark S&P 500 share index is hitting new highs every other
week, fuelled by enthusiasm about artificial intelligence (AI). On June 18th
this made Nvidia, a chip designer, the world’s most valuable firm. The
cyclically adjusted price-earnings ratio, popularised by Robert Shiller of
Yale University, is at nearly 36. It has been higher only before the crashes of
the early 2000s and 2022—and even then, not by much. That a correction
will arrive at some point seems a racing certainty, but in the meantime there
is a still more worrying prospect. As far as it has come, the rally may yet
have further to go.
After all, pricey shares can always get pricier if investors keep bidding them
up. To see why they may now be especially prone to a melt-up, consider the
concept of “duration”. This is typically applied to bonds, and is similar to
their maturity. It is the average time until a bond’s future payouts, including
both coupons and repayment, weighted by the size of each payout.
Unusually in financial maths, which tends to be messy, duration has a rather
elegant meaning: it is the sensitivity of an asset’s price to changes in interest
rates. A long-duration asset—a 50-year bond, say—is hammered by rising
interest rates, and appreciates a lot if they fall. Cash, the value of which is
invariant under such changes, has a duration of zero.
What about shares? Intuitively, those that derive much of their value from
earnings in the distant future must be closer in duration to the long-maturity
bond than to cash. So must stocks with a high price-to-earnings ratio, since it
will take many years of profits to repay their initial cost. In other words,
America’s stockmarket—expensive overall, and led by tech behemoths
promising an innovation-fuelled bonanza—has a very long duration.
Interest rates, meanwhile, are now poised to fall. True, at the last meeting of
the Federal Reserve’s rate-setting committee, which finished on June 12th,
the median member expected only one cut before the end of 2024, down
from three. But more significant was the fact that share prices rose on the
news, suggesting investors had anticipated hawkishness rather than (as so
often in recent years) underestimating it. Rates traders also expect the Fed’s
short-term rate to finish the year in line with its officials’ projections.
Markets have tended to be more doveish than the Fed, leaving scope for
surprises that send bond yields up and long-duration assets down. Now,
provided the Fed’s next move really is down, the shoe is on the other foot.
There is an obvious counter to all this: that the recent buoyancy of share
prices, in spite of rising bond yields, shows duration analysis to be drivel
when applied to the stockmarket. A theoretician might reply that share prices
have soared in spite of the downward pressure from interest rates, with
expected future earnings being marked up by more than enough to
compensate.
It would probably be closer to the truth to say that just now, for whatever
reason, investors seem willing to buy whichever narrative paints the rosiest
picture. At the end of 2023 this was that bond yields were falling and
monetary policy would soon follow. This year, as such hopes have faded, it
has concerned AI and the resilience of America’s economy. Do not be
surprised if duration is soon back in the spotlight once a good-news story
can be spun around it. Mr Gill’s first appearance did indeed herald a crash,
but only after plenty more euphoria. The shoeshine boys, your columnist
hears, are not yet all-in.■
For more expert analysis of the biggest stories in economics, finance and
markets, sign up to Money Talks, our weekly subscriber-only newsletter.
This article was downloaded by zlibrary from https://www.economist.com/finance-and-economics/2024/06/19/think-nvidia-looks-dear-
american-shares-could-get-pricier-still
Finance & economics | Free exchange
Things are big in America. That is true of houses, cars and food portions.
Perhaps most shocking of all is the size of tips. In much of the rest of the
world, gratuities are a small gesture for good service. In American
restaurants they are de rigueur. And they are becoming more generous and
more common. For workers who already get them, tips are growing; for
those who do not get them, tips may be coming their way. But this cannot go
on for ever. Look closer at the tipflation gripping America and a surprising
conclusion emerges: the country may be approaching peak tip.
As with so much these days, Donald Trump has a hand in this. At a recent
rally in Las Vegas, he casually inserted a radical proposal about halfway
through his speech. “For those hotel workers and people that get tips, you’re
going to be very happy. Because when I get to office we are going to not
charge taxes on tips,” he said. It was, he argued, only right to stop the
government from going after the earnings of people who provide good
service.
The legal landscape is also in flux. Whereas Mr Trump’s pledge raises the
prospect of yet more tipping, state officials are pushing in the opposite
direction. Many restaurants in America pay what is known as a tipped
minimum wage, which can be as low as $2.13. The rest—to get to the state
minimum wage—is meant to be derived from tips. In practice many servers
earn well above that. Restaurant owners like this system because it gives
them flexibility to hire more workers and to keep menu prices down,
knowing that customers will directly cover wage costs through tipping. But
little by little cities and states are applying their true minimum wages to all
workers, whether tipped or not. That is currently the case in a handful of
states such as Minnesota and Oregon. Chicago and Washington, DC, have
recently started down this path; Connecticut, Massachusetts and Ohio may
be next.
A little gratuitous
Higher minimum wages raise labour costs for restaurants. Some
establishments have responded by cutting staff or shutting during slow
hours, while others have added mandatory service charges or raised prices.
From a broader economic perspective, the impact need not be quite so
dramatic: the main effect for customers will be to see some of the cost of
their meal migrating from the tip line on their receipts to the upfront food
price. This does not mean that gratuities will go away—they are too deeply
entrenched in American life. But the eye-watering amounts may start to
recede. The country is at a tipping-point. ■
For more expert analysis of the biggest stories in economics, finance and
markets, sign up to Money Talks, our weekly subscriber-only newsletter.
This article was downloaded by zlibrary from https://www.economist.com/finance-and-economics/2024/06/20/is-america-approaching-
peak-tip
Science & technology
The dominant model of the universe is creaking
The secret to taking better penalties
A flower’s female sex organs can speed up fertilisation
How physics can improve image-generating AI
Science & technology | Dark secrets
mysterious entity that accounts for 68% of everything in the universe and
which pushes space apart in a repulsive version of gravity. Though they do
not know what it is, scientists have hitherto assumed that the density of dark
energy has been the same since the start of the universe, 13.7bn years ago.
But DESI’s initial results suggest that this assumption may have been wrong.
Perhaps, say DESI’s scientists, the density has been changing over time. “It’s so
bizarre,” says Dragan Huterer from the University of Michigan, who was
involved with the work. If the findings prove true, it would catapult
cosmology into a crisis.
The study of dark energy is surprisingly new. Direct evidence for its
existence was not detected until 1998, when scientists discovered that
extremely bright exploding stars called supernovas were moving away from
Earth much more quickly than they ought to. Their conclusion: not only was
the universe expanding, but that expansion was accelerating. “People did not
expect that,” says Adam Riess of Johns Hopkins University, who shared a
Nobel prize in physics for the discovery in 2011.
Because it is hard to study directly, the true nature of dark energy remains
poorly understood. The leading hypothesis is that it is energy intrinsic to the
vacuum of empty space. Per quantum theory, a vacuum is not really empty,
it fizzes with countless pairs of particles and antiparticles that emerge from
nothing, only to annihilate each other. These interactions produce a “vacuum
energy” that, over the scales of the cosmos, could push space apart. This
idea is not without its problems—when physicists try to calculate what this
vacuum energy density would amount to, they get a value between 60 and
120 orders of magnitude larger than what observational evidence currently
supports—a fiasco known as the vacuum catastrophe. “The general
consensus is that resolving the [catastrophe] will require fundamental new
insight,” says Dr Huterer.
Vacuum catastrophe aside, dark energy now forms one of two central pillars
of the standard model of cosmology, the best scientific description of the
universe’s evolution. The other pillar is dark matter, an invisible form of
matter that makes up 27% of the universe. Regular matter, which constitutes
stars and galaxies, accounts for a measly 5%. The standard model says that,
after the Big Bang set the universe’s expansion in motion, the gravitational
attraction between atoms first led to the formation of stars and galaxies,
while also acting as a brake on the universe’s overall growth. As the amount
of empty space increased, however, so did the amount of dark energy and,
eventually, it took over as the primary influence on the evolution of the
cosmos, driving the accelerated expansion that Dr Riess observed a quarter
of a century ago.
This expansion of the universe is expected to go on for ever, with galaxies
eventually drifting out of each other’s sight, a fate known as the Big Freeze.
But if, as DESI suggests, the density of dark energy can change, other scenarios
come into play: ever-denser dark energy could one day cause atoms and
even the fabric of spacetime itself to burst apart, a scenario known as the Big
Rip. Conversely, a dark energy of decreasing density could cause matter and
gravity to take over the universe once again, recollapsing the cosmos into an
inverse Big Bang, known as the Big Crunch. (Earthlings need not worry
overmuch—the Sun will swallow up the innermost planets of the solar
system long before either fate occurs.)
time. According to Dr Huterer, what happened is even stranger than that: the
density increased until around 4bn years ago and then it began decreasing
(see chart). Nobody can explain why.
If the DESI team’s results are right, it would mean a complete re-evaluation of
what dark energy could be. “The moment [dark] energy changes in time, it is
no longer vacuum energy,” says Bhuvnesh Jain, a cosmologist at the
University of Pennsylvania. Alternative proposals already exist, centring on
a dark-energy field called quintessence, which pervades all space and can
change with time. However, Dr Jain says, the DESI results as they stand now
indicate something more complex than the simplest quintessence models.
It would also mean that the standard model of cosmology, in its current
form, is toast. It is no wonder, then, that DESI’s results are causing
consternation. But these are not the only vexing cracks in the model. For
example, some astronomers have observed that matter in the nearby universe
clumps together less than the standard model says it ought to and that the
early universe does not seem to have been as uniform a place as the standard
model’s predictions say it should have been.
What’s more, over the past decade different teams have measured differing
values for the Hubble constant, the rate at which the universe is currently
expanding (named after Edwin Hubble, an American astronomer, who
worked out that galaxies were moving away from Earth at a velocity
proportional to their distance from it). This would imply that cosmologists
do not really understand the universe’s historical expansion—or, by
extension, how dark energy has behaved in that time. Recent observations
from the James Webb Space Telescope, however, collected by Wendy
Freedman of the University of Chicago and her team, seem to suggest these
values can be reconciled, implying nothing unexpected in dark energy’s
behaviour. The results have yet to be published in a scientific journal,
though, so not all sides in the debate are convinced.
All these problems have led some cosmologists to advocate for radical
solutions—adopting more flexible notions of dark energy, for example, or
working on an alternative to the standard model of cosmology. Some even
go so far as to suggest that Albert Einstein’s general theory of relativity, on
which the model is based, may have reached its limits. “We know that
sooner or later, it will fail. It happened to Newton, it will happen to
Einstein,” says Andreu Font-Ribera, a cosmologist at the Institute of High
Energy Physics in Barcelona and another member of the DESI team. That
would not mean that Einstein was wrong but only—small consolation
though it may be—incompletely right. Just as Isaac Newton’s law of
universal gravitation was shown to be an approximation of general relativity
under the right conditions (ie, across the relatively small distances and low
gravitational fields on and around Earth), general relativity may also turn out
to be the limiting case of some deeper, as-yet-undiscovered theory.
For now, all talk of replacing the standard model of cosmology, let alone
general relativity, is motivated by hints and guesswork. But as the next
generation of telescopes and observatories begins to generate data, a new,
more complete picture of dark energy’s role in the universe may emerge.
The Vera Rubin Observatory in Chile, for example, will also chart the
universe’s expansion over time and map the universe’s evolution over the
past several billion years. That will start watching the heavens next year. The
European Space Agency’s Euclid, a space telescope, is already in orbit and
building its own map of galaxies. It is likewise aiming to track dark energy
through measurements of the universe’s expansion. “You feel like the clues
are almost there,” says Dr Riess. “I keep waiting for a really smart person to
put these puzzle pieces together.” ■
“I cannot say we would get the same effect with Cristiano Ronaldo, because
I haven’t tested him. But I can say over all the players we tested it works,
and it really works,” says Jean-Pierre Bresciani, a neuroscientist who leads
the research.
The technology focuses on the type of penalty favoured by three out of four
professional penalty-takers, in which the kicker waits for the goalkeeper to
move before propelling the ball into the empty part of the goal. (Those
players who simply blast it as hard as they can should seek help elsewhere.)
The idea is to speed up the kicker’s reaction time in cases when the
goalkeeper fails to move in the expected direction, increasing their chances
of switching tactic mid-stride.
Working with players from the under-18 teams of FC Luzern and FC Basel, two
Swiss clubs, the scientists got penalty-takers to wear a headset that projected
the avatar of a goalkeeper into the centre of a real goal. Each player was then
asked to kick a real ball into one or other side of the goal, but to switch if the
simulated goalie moved in that direction. The headsets were also connected
to an algorithm capable of adapting the speed of the goalkeeper’s
movements.
Dr Bresciani says that such tests offer several advantages over other penalty-
taking drills. First, the avatars are programmed to move in consistent ways
each time, which makes the results more reliable and useful for analysis than
those using a real goalkeeper. And second, no human goalkeeper needs to
get their shirt muddy.
With this year’s European championship taking place just across the border
in Germany, Dr Bresciani says he is eager to help any team that asks. All
they need to pack is a headset and laptop. But with the knockout rounds
beginning on June 29th, time is running out. ■
ANY biologically aware parent who has started talking about the birds and
the bees will have realised halfway through that what they are really
discussing is flowers. Bees carry pollen grains from one plant to another,
enabling fertilisation; birds digest and excrete the resulting seeds, allowing
new blooms to grow.
The role that flowers themselves play in their own reproduction, however,
remains imperfectly understood. In a new paper published recently in EMBO
Reports, Mizuta Yoko at Nagoya University and her colleagues unveiled the
secrets of this process with unprecedented detail. Among the revelations that
arose from her 13-year-long investigation was the degree of control that a
flower’s female sex organs have over the fertilisation process. Not only do
they have the power to attract male reproductive cells, but they can also
repel them once fertilisation has begun.
The vocabulary of reproduction is, fortunately for parents, the same across
the animal and plant kingdoms. A male reproductive cell is a sperm, a
female reproductive cell is an egg. When the two meet under the right
conditions, an embryo forms. Such conditions, always tricky to engineer, are
even more complex for flowering plants as their sperm cells cannot move.
To overcome this limitation, their sperm cells are packaged in microscopic
grains of pollen. When the wind blows, say, or a bee visits, these pollen
grains can then come into contact with another flower’s pistil, the rod-like
structure typically located in its centre that contains the ovules, each of
which in turn contains an egg cell.
To penetrate the surface of the pistil and reach a flower’s eggs, a grain of
pollen must create a pollen tube. The tube grows out of the pollen much like
a seedling emerges from a seed. But if several pollen tubes converge on one
ovule—a phenomenon known as polytubey—the offspring may contain too
many copies of the paternal DNA and not form viable seeds. Yet polytubey
rarely happens, despite the large numbers of pollen tubes and ovules
involved. (A typical fertilisation event of Arabidopsis thaliana, botanists’
favoured guinea pig, involves an average of 60 ovules and pollen tubes, each
of which somehow finds a one-to-one match.)
It has been worth the wait. In previous studies, researchers had shown that
ovules send chemical signals which attract pollen tubes. These attractive
signals were thought to disappear once an ovule is fertilised. The first thing
the research by Dr Mizuta and her team confirms is that they do indeed
vanish. It also adds valuable information about where and when fertilisation
occurs. For example, they observed that pollen tubes fertilise a pistil’s
ovules more or less at random, rather than in an orderly fashion—from the
top of the pistil to the bottom—as some had hypothesised.
The videos also revealed a new aspect of the mechanism that blocks
polytubey. When Dr Mizuta and her team looked through their videos, they
observed some pollen tubes seemingly trying to enter an ovule before
suddenly turning away. That led the team to conclude that the ovule is
capable of repelling unwanted pollen tubes once fertilisation has begun.
They suspect that this repulsion arises when proteins in the ovule come into
contact with receptors on the pollen tube (or, perhaps, vice versa), somehow
inducing it to change direction.
Many will be watching the team’s work closely. As important crops like rice,
wheat and corn all reproduce in a similar way to A. thaliana, says Mark
Johnson, a cellular biologist at Brown University who was not involved in
the research, a better understanding of the mechanisms involved could help
farmers boost future yields. Dr Mizuta and her colleagues hope to keep
expanding that understanding. ■
Diffusion models mimic the maths of the physical process of diffusion, the
flow of particles from areas of high to low concentration as they are
randomly jostled about in space. The MIT team’s more advanced algorithms
make use, instead, of the equations of electromagnetism—and may one day
even use the mathematics that govern the forces at play in the atomic
nucleus. This work suggests that computer scientists have barely scratched
the surface of how generative algorithms can work. A new school of AI art is
emerging.
The fact that mimicking such simple physical processes has had such
profound computational benefits caught the attention of Max Tegmark and
Tommi Jaakkola, two physicists at MIT, and their graduate students, Yilun Xu
and Ziming Liu, in 2022. Together, they set out to explore whether models
trained on more complex processes might do an even better job of image
generation. They started by toying with the physics of electrically charged
particles. Unlike in standard diffusion, the journeys of charged particles are
not truly random. Repelled and attracted by their neighbours, they are
governed instead by the electric field in which they exist.
It’s electrifying
This behaviour can be emulated in the way that noise is added to a digital
image. Recall that images can be represented as points in a multidimensional
space defined by the colours of each pixel. If these points are treated like
particles with identical electric charge, they ought to repel one another,
moving in opposite directions until the system reaches electrostatic
equilibrium. Or, in other words, each image will change in response to every
other image until all have been sufficiently distorted.
It turns out that a machine-learning model trained to reverse this process can
have considerable advantages. This is because the distorting noise is not
merely random, as in diffusion models, but carries additional information
about the training data. That makes for a more efficient algorithm. Mr Xu,
Mr Liu and their colleagues then published a preprint outlining this new
class of models. They called them “Poisson flow generative models” (PFGMs),
named for Poisson’s equation, which describes the electric field created by
static electrical charges. Judged by industry standards, PFGMs generate images
of equal or better quality than state-of-the-art diffusion models, while being
less error-prone and requiring between ten and 20 times fewer computational
steps.
The researchers were not done yet. They also turned their attention to
Coulomb’s law, the equation that governs the strength of the electric field
which exists between two charges (and from which Poisson’s equation can
be derived). The researchers found that changing the number of dimensions
in which Coulomb’s law operates has implications for a PFGM’S behaviour.
Fewer dimensions result in models that require more data to train but that
need fewer parameters, make fewer errors and produce more consistent
images. More dimensions result in models that require less data to train but
are bulkier, more error-prone and less consistent.
In a subsequent preprint, the team called this broader family of electrostatic
models PFGM++. They also made a surprising discovery. When the number of
dimensions in the equations is taken to infinity, the distortion algorithm
behaves like a standard diffusion model. This means that PFGM++ folds all the
current physics-inspired generative models into one family.
Still more complex distortion mechanisms beckon. The next target for
Messrs Xu and Liu is the weak interaction, which, alongside
electromagnetism, gravity and the strong interaction, is a fundamental force
of nature. (Imperceptible at human scales, it is responsible for certain types
of radioactive decay.) Conveniently, its equations are almost identical to
those used in the PFGM++ family of models.
The weak force, however, has special properties that the electromagnetic
force does not. For one thing, it does not need to conserve the number of
particles. Pairs of particles can mutually annihilate, and new ones can pop
into being. If this physics is translated into an algorithm, it may unlock new
behaviour: compressing data with record efficiency, for example, or offering
applications in cell biology where objects multiply or die out. How well it
can draw a penguin, though, remains to be seen. ■
Champagne now merits its own victory tour. The value of sales of
champagne hit €6.4bn ($6.9bn) in 2023; 2021-23 were the best years on
record, even after accounting for inflation (see chart). Over the past five
years the “Champagne 50” index, which tracks the value of the top brands
traded on Liv-ex, a wine-buying platform, has surged by 47%, more than
any other regional index worldwide, including Bordeaux (up by 1.3%),
Burgundy (25%) and Italy (29%). In the past half-decade the Wine Advocate
has published more articles and reviews devoted to champagne than it did in
the preceding 41 years since its founding, says William Kelley, the editor-in-
chief. (Bottles can bear the “champagne” name only if they hail from that
region of north-eastern France near Épernay.)
The fact that wine aficionados have only lately lapped up champagne may
be a surprise. Champagne has long been a luxury brand in its own right, a
global symbol of celebration and splurging. LVMH, a French luxury-goods
juggernaut, has collected champagne companies like a tippler acquiring
bottles: it owns seven, including Dom Pérignon, Krug, Moët & Chandon and
Veuve Clicquot. Together, they account for an estimated 46% of global
champagne sales by value and 23% by volume, according to Edouard Aubin
of Morgan Stanley. (The disparity arises because LVMH sells a lot of “prestige
cuvées”, an elegant-sounding term for expensive bottles.)
Big champagne houses can afford Balthazar-size advertising budgets. For
much of modern history champagne has been “pushed as a bubbly drink for
bubbly people”, writes Robert Walters in “Bursting Bubbles” a book about
champagne. It has been drunk by rappers and those wrapping up their
evenings at night clubs. This “double-edged marketing…has both led to
champagne’s incredible popularity and diminished its reputation” among
connoisseurs, according to Mr Walters. Oenophiles did not take it very
seriously. “Champagne was considered a fine thing, but not necessarily a
fine wine,” explains Justin Gibbs of Liv-ex.
Two things changed. One was covid, which gave wine-lovers more time at
home to research and try new bottles. It may seem odd that a festive drink
flourished at such a bleak time. But well-off people who were not going out
to dine in restaurants sought pleasures at home, sometimes bidding in online
auctions for new bottles. They also had more time to study the terroir of
champagne and producers’ different methods of blending and adding dosage
(a mixture including cane sugar that sweetens it before bottling). In other
words, drinkers started to “understand there is a wine behind the bubble”,
says Arthur Larmandier of Larmandier-Bernier, a champagne house. At first
Mr Larmandier thought it would take five years for champagne to bounce
back from covid; instead, demand surged, and it “took six months”.
The second factor is more appreciation for the smaller houses that produce
limited quantities of high-quality bubbly. Prices for these “grower”
champagnes have rocketed on the secondary market: the Wine Market
Journal’s grower-champagne index has more than doubled in value since
2019. Oenophiles now invoke these winemakers’ last names with the
fondness that football players refer to their teammates: Selosse, Prévost,
Collin, Bouchard, Egly-Ouriet. (Selosse, at around $650 a bottle, is the
Lionel Messi of grower champagne.)
Growers have brought artisanal winemaking techniques to champagne,
relying more on ripe, carefully tended grapes than on dosage; this leads to a
lower sugar profile and greater complexity. Appreciation of grower
champagne connects with a broader trend in culture, including gastronomy,
whereby people are seeking out local, authentic producers and tastes, says
Mr Kelley of the Wine Advocate. More reviews of champagne by Mr Kelley
and fellow critics piqued the interest of collectors and investors, who found
even the highest-quality champagne undervalued, relative to top wines from
Burgundy and Bordeaux.
This is not champagne’s first transformation. In the 17th century, when Dom
Pérignon, a monk, was making it in his abbey, bubbles were seen as a flaw:
champagne then was a still wine. (Though Pérignon is credited with being
the “inventor” of champagne, that is just marketing; his famous remark
“Come quickly, I am drinking the stars!” first appeared in a 19th-century
advert.) It was only in the 18th century that the Champagne region embraced
bubbles, as both a source of differentiation and a justification for higher
prices.
Flights of fancy
What does the future hold? France used to buy most champagne, but that
changed in 2012. Now America and Japan are important growth markets,
says Stéphane Dalyac, chief executive of Laurent-Perrier, a prominent
house. Unlike many firms peddling well-known luxury brands, bubbly-
makers are not optimistic in the near term about China, where buyers over
40 tend not to gravitate to the cold fizziness of champagne, Mr Dalyac says.
But the sun is shining on champagne in many ways. Climate change is
helping the region’s wine by ripening grapes naturally, therefore requiring
less dosage, says Peter Gibson of the Wine Market Journal,. Many think the
effect of grower champagne will endure, elevating the whole region’s quality
for years to come.
For more on the latest books, films, TV shows, albums and controversies, sign
up to Plot Twist, our weekly subscriber-only newsletter
This article was downloaded by zlibrary from https://www.economist.com/culture/2024/06/20/wine-collectors-are-at-last-taking-
champagne-seriously
Culture | Who are you calling a Neanderthal?
THERE IS NO doubt that the past can shape the future in profound ways: consider
climate change, for instance. It is also true that imagined pasts can influence
real-world events. Vladimir Putin invokes history to justify his invasion of
Ukraine, picturing it as a child that was snatched from Mother Russia and
should be returned. Ukrainians see things differently. This clash of visions
underpins the bloodiest war in Europe since 1945.
Imagined histories can shape the present in subtler ways, too. Take pre-
history, the 3m or so years of human evolution before the invention of
writing (thought to be in the fourth millennium BC). A new book by Stefanos
Geroulanos, a professor of European intellectual history at New York
University, offers a sweeping exploration of Western ideas about early
humankind. He shows that theories about the ancient past have exerted a
strong and sometimes pernicious influence on the modern world. “Pre-
history is about the present day,” Mr Geroulanos writes. “It always has
been.”
There are plenty of villains in this story, many of them respected sages in
their own time. In 1925 Raymond Dart, an anthropologist working in South
Africa, wrote about his discovery of a child Australopithecus africanus. The
species would come to be understood as the direct ancestors of Homo, the
genus of modern humans, and the region known as “The Cradle of
Humankind”. But Mr Geroulanos suggests that racial prejudice coloured
Dart’s attitudes. In the 1950s he offered almost ghoulish descriptions of
imagined prehistoric savagery; Dart’s argument “certainly hinted that the
brutality of Africans’ origins influenced Africans in the present day”, Mr
Geroulanos observes. The theories thus appealed to supporters of apartheid.
Historians today are more meticulous, though the author gently chides Yuval
Noah Harari, a popular writer, for asserting on thin grounds that civilisation
started with cooking. Recent scientific advances—such as the Nobel-
prizewinning work done by Svante Paabo, a Swedish geneticist, on
sequencing the Neanderthal genome—have unlocked new areas of inquiry.
But Mr Geroulanos insists that “However much we may ‘know’” about
Neanderthal man and his predecessors, “he continues to say more about us.”
■
For more on the latest books, films, TV shows, albums and controversies, sign
up to Plot Twist, our weekly subscriber-only newsletter
This article was downloaded by zlibrary from https://www.economist.com/culture/2024/06/20/theories-of-pre-history-are-a-mirror-
on-their-times
Culture | Back Story
The collective, Fossil Free Books (FFB), has set its sights on Baillie Gifford, a
Scottish asset manager, which until recently sponsored ten literary festivals
in Britain. The firm, charge the activists, invests in fossil-fuel producers and
companies tied to Israeli security. (“Solidarity with Palestine and climate
justice are inextricably linked,” FFB questionably maintains.) Their convoluted
strategy involved pressuring the festivals and urging authors to withdraw
from them, in the hope of pushing Baillie Gifford to divest from these
holdings. “Disruption” and “escalation” were promised.
This statement is accurate. The episode shows exactly the sort of power such
campaigns have—and the kind they don’t. The butterfly effect does not
apply: boycotting a book festival in Wales will not prevent extreme weather
events, nor drive back Israeli tanks to their barracks. These antics cannot
force Baillie Gifford to dispose of any holdings, since it can do that only on
its customers’ say-so. Rather than damaging its brand, the fuss has shown
that it prioritises clients’ interests. None has withdrawn their money.
The activists do, however, have the power to hurt Britain’s book festivals,
which must cobble together funding at a time of shrinking state subsidy.
Some may have to put up prices for punters; others may fold. Perhaps that is
a sacrifice worth making to achieve what FFB calls “a literary industry free
from fossil fuels, genocide and colonial violence”. This smells like activism
aimed less at global warming than the warm glow of moral smugness, more
concerned with seeming good and feeling good than doing it.
In a second misconception, the likes of FFB fail to face the moral realities of a
globalised world. By any sane measure, Baillie Gifford is no villain. Only
1% of the £225bn ($287bn) it manages is invested in fossil-fuel producers; it
invests far more in green technologies. As for its alleged stake in “Israeli
apartheid, occupation and genocide”, it mostly consists of shares in tech
giants like Amazon and Nvidia.
The idea that any investment outfit, or indeed any person, could sever every
remote and indirect link to fossil fuels or Israel, an important tech hub, is an
adolescent fantasy. British authors ought to know that: their books are sold
on Amazon and in Waterstones, a bookshop chain owned by Elliott, a hedge
fund that trades oil. In a spider’s web of global connections, moral lines and
prohibitions are bound to be drawn imperfectly. That is one reason to
hesitate before imposing yours on others.
The third delusion is that pristine art and filthy Mammon can ever be
separate realms. Like everyone else, writers and artists must make ends
meet; they have always made compromises to do so, whether in blithe
ignorance, embittered hypocrisy or emasculating gratitude. In bygone eras
they relied on patrons, from Roman emperors to the feudal overlords and
corrupt prelates of the Renaissance. “I should be Employ’d in Greater
things,” William Blake groaned in 1802 as he churned out hack work for a
benefactor.
In the modern age of mass literacy and commercial entertainment, the moral
hazard has been dispersed rather than eliminated. Now the compromises are
over how much creative folk charge, which fads they pander to, which
middlemen they employ and so on. Even today, some artistic endeavours
tend to require munificent patrons. These include full-scale opera, museum
construction—and book festivals.
Artists who repudiate support from the likes of Baillie Gifford are naive
about power and childish about morality. More than that, if it’s purity they
covet, they are in the wrong business.■
For more on the latest books, films, TV shows, albums and controversies, sign
up to Plot Twist, our weekly subscriber-only newsletter
This article was downloaded by zlibrary from https://www.economist.com/culture/2024/06/14/what-a-row-over-sponsorship-reveals-
about-art-and-mammon
Culture | No city of angels
“Chinatown” was released several decades after the genre’s heyday in the
1940s-50s. The film, and the “neo noirs” that followed it, tried to strike a
balance between paying homage to the classics and turning the genre on its
head. In 1982 “Blade Runner” transported viewers to the futuristic Los
Angeles of 2019. Rick Deckard (Harrison Ford) searches for bioengineered
humans who are not supposed to be on Earth, let alone in the City of Angels.
Crime flicks can be made about any city. But Los Angeles cornered the
market back when Chandler was writing screenplays. Many great crime
novelists have lived there, including Chandler and, later, James Ellroy. But
their novels need not be adapted faithfully. “Double Indemnity”, after all,
was based on a murder in Queens.
Why does Los Angeles continue to play a leading role in film noir? Its status
as America’s long-reigning film capital is part of it. The city also lends itself
to film noir because it is such a study in contrasts. The relentless sunshine
and skinny palm trees jar with the genre’s violence and corruption. LA is
where people come to make it, and only a few succeed.
What happens to those who are disappointed? Wannabe starlets become call
girls. Men who cannot pay their mortgage become muscle for mobsters.
Danny DeVito, who plays a smarmy tabloid journalist in the neo-noir “LA
Confidential” (1997), based on a novel by Mr Ellroy, gives an oleaginous
monologue that encapsulates the duality of LA noir. “You’d think this place
was the garden of Eden,” he says, “but there’s trouble in paradise.”
A newer spate of LA noirs fetishise the genre even while challenging its
conventions. In the television series “Lucifer”, the lord of Hell solves
murders alongside a city detective. There are sometimes musical numbers to
offset all the killing. In “Sugar”, which premiered on Apple TV in April, John
Sugar, a private investigator, is a cinephile. He wears a suit and drives an old
Corvette in the mould of Marlowe or Gittes. A girl goes missing, and as
Sugar investigates, he finds each member of her family to be corrupt in their
own way. Sugar, too, loses sight of himself the more he obsesses over the
case. The series even begins in black and white and features old film clips
throughout.
Gittes is not so lucky. His efforts, like many a private investigator in film
noir, prove futile. “Forget it, Jake,” his partner says when the woman he
wants to protect is killed. “It’s Chinatown.” ■
For more on the latest books, films, TV shows, albums and controversies, sign
up to Plot Twist, our weekly subscriber-only newsletter
This article was downloaded by zlibrary from https://www.economist.com/culture/2024/06/20/los-angeles-is-the-capital-of-film-
noir
Culture | When screens clean the green
ON JUNE 2ND Bill Guan, the chief financial officer of the Epoch Times, a right-
wing newspaper, was arrested. Prosecutors in New York charged him with
laundering $67m, allegedly buying pre-paid debit cards using
cryptocurrency. (Mr Guan has pleaded not guilty.) Chainalysis, a
blockchain-analysis firm, estimates that $22.2bn in illicit funds were
laundered globally using cryptocurrencies in 2023. Despite Western
sanctions, Iran, North Korea and Hamas, a terrorist group, all launder funds
with crypto.
As Geoff White, a journalist, makes clear in a gripping new book, money-
laundering can seem bloodless and abstruse, but it is going to become only
more relevant and widespread. That is because technology is making this
kind of crime easier—and much harder to detect.
Cleaning dirty money involves three steps. The first is “placement”, getting
it into the financial system so it does not sit unproductively under a mattress.
During the heyday of Pablo Escobar, a notorious Colombian drug kingpin, in
the 1980s, couriers travelled with briefcases stuffed with cash to Anguilla, a
Caribbean island with appealing banking-secrecy laws, and deposited it in
local banks. Now people can get intermediaries to change stolen funds into
bitcoin—or do it themselves—without the need for an aeroplane ticket.
“Rinsed” will no doubt please crypto-sceptics, but that misses the larger
picture, which is about governments grappling with crypto’s attractiveness to
criminals. The tech sector’s relentless drive to innovate has an upside: just
think of all you can do with that little supercomputer in your pocket. But, as
Mr White reminds us in this book, it has plenty of downsides, too. ■
For more on the latest books, films, TV shows, albums and controversies, sign
up to Plot Twist, our weekly subscriber-only newsletter
This article was downloaded by zlibrary from https://www.economist.com/culture/2024/06/20/technology-has-changed-money-
laundering
Culture | Everything to play for
Playing with Reality. By Kelly Clancy. Riverhead Books; 368 pages; $30.
Allen Lane; £25
IN 1824 PRINCE WILHELM OF PRUSSIA asked for a demonstration of an elaborate game he had
heard about from his military tutor. The Kriegsspiel, or war game, had been
devised a few decades earlier as a more militarily realistic form of chess.
Instead of regular squares, the board was a detailed map of a real battlefield.
Wooden blocks represented different military formations; each turn of the
game simulated two minutes of battlefield combat. Damage was worked out
by rolling special dice and using odds-based scoring tables based on casualty
statistics from historical battles. The game took two weeks to play, during
which all cats had to be banished from the vicinity, so they did not climb on
the board and mess up the pieces.
The prince was enchanted, and every Prussian officer was ordered to learn to
play the game. It allowed new tactics to be tried out, even in peacetime. The
rules were constantly updated with new weapons and statistics. When
Wilhelm became king, Prussia’s unexpectedly swift victory in 1871 in the
Franco-Prussian war was attributed to these gamed simulations.
By the time of the first world war, Kriegsspiel was being used to predict
when German battalions were likely to run out of ammunition, allowing
timely replenishment—what would now be called supply-chain forecasting.
In the interwar period, German planners used it to develop Blitzkrieg tactics
and simulate the invasion of Czechoslovakia. When Hitler invaded Russia,
both sides relied on the game to predict how the campaign might unfold.
Such war games, in turn, prompted John von Neumann’s initial steps in the
development of what is now known as game theory, a branch of
mathematics that could, its proponents hoped, be the physics of human
nature. By the 1950s the theory had been fleshed out, with now-familiar
ideas such as the Nash equilibrium and the prisoner’s dilemma, which
consider how adversaries adjust their strategies in response to each other’s
actions. Game theory directly underpinned the idea of “mutually assured
destruction” during the nuclear build-up and stand-off of the cold war. It has
since been applied in fields ranging from trade to evolution.
In the 21st century, the influence of game-like mechanisms has assumed a
new, digital form. Social-media platforms are akin to games in which users
compete for clicks and attention; apps have gamified dating, fitness and
language-learning; and woe betide anyone whose rating on eBay, Uber or
Airbnb, based on scores from other users, falls too low. Games have also
been central to the development of artificial intelligence. Modern systems
rely on the computational horsepower of graphics chips originally designed
to run video games; and games have driven progress in the field, from chess,
to Go, to the ImageNet image-recognition contest.
For more on the latest books, films, TV shows, albums and controversies, sign
up to Plot Twist, our weekly subscriber-only newsletter
This article was downloaded by zlibrary from https://www.economist.com/culture/2024/06/20/how-games-and-game-theory-have-
changed-the-world
The Economist reads
How to stare at the Sun, through art
The Economist reads | The Economist looks at
Visual artists, from the prehistoric to the contemporary, provide a safer way
for Sun-worshippers and the Sun-curious to deepen their appreciation. As
solar power becomes an ever more important energy source around the
world, here are seven artworks that also harness the Sun’s energy and deepen
its resonance.
Through chinks that seem natural but have been perfectly aligned to the
geometries of the winter solstice, the Sun creeps in. An intruder and a
timekeeper. The ruler of lives. Steadily, the beam widens until the whole
interior is lit. At Newgrange it marks the start of the new year and the ever-
strengthening Sun. Light fertilises the womb-dark of the chamber. At the
caves of Lascaux, in south-western France, it declares the summer solstice
and the season’s fullness. Where it enters, the Sun turns the earth floors to
hammered fire. There is light enough to paint, at Lascaux, men, hunters and
wild oxen. Or, at Newgrange, to carve mesmerising looped spirals and a
leafing fern, the plant of rejuvenation. Plants, beasts and men live, and will
live again, in the Sun.
Sun Tunnels. By Nancy Holt; 1973-1976; Little Pigeon Rd, Great Basin
Desert, Utah
Five thousand years later, such alignment has become industrial. The Land
Art movement of the 1960s and 1970s saw some artists use bulldozers,
concrete and steel to mount human interventions in the relationships
between land, water and sky, at once massive and, in context, hauntingly
inconsequential. Nancy Holt brought “the sky down to earth” by passing
solstice sunlight down tubes that might have been sewers, one set for winter,
one for summer. Brutal concrete evoked an infrastructure on a global scale,
but in an arrangement that would have been understandable to men and
women measuring the comings and goings of the seasons through the sky
throughout human history—and even before it began.
Impression/Sunrise. By Claude Monet; 1872; Musée Marmottan Monet,
Paris; on display at the Musée d’Orsay in Paris until July 24th 2024; at the
National Gallery in Washington, DC from September 8th 2024 to January
19th 2025
Dawn barely breaks outside the window of his hotel on the Grand Quay in
Le Havre, and a bearded man is already at his easel. He paints the Sun as no
one has done before: it is a rough red ball, which has already dropped its
careless colours on the sea. This Sun must burn its way through the fog of
the industrial age. Vague chimneys and cranes jostle to obscure it. The sky is
smoke, and the water thick as oil. The Sun’s rays are withdrawn: as yet, it
illuminates only wisps of cloud. Yet it hangs centrally, or just off-centre, as
the plain commander of the scene. Monet calls his painting an impression;
from this casual description, a whole artistic genre will spring. He insists
that it is not finished yet. And his painter-Sun has not started, let alone
finished, the uncreated day.
Beachy Head Lighthouse (Belle Tout). By Eric Ravilious; 1939; private
collection
The Sun is barely visible in this painting. Yet it still governs everything. Eric
Ravilious, a modern man, boasted that he looked “into the eye of the sun as
long as it could be borne” when he worked in the open air. It became one of
his beloved yellow things, commonplace as a pat of butter, a beached skiff
or a baker’s cart. He loved especially to catch it coming in through glass,
entering silent bedrooms and kitchens like a too-familiar friend. Yet the Sun
of his woodcuts was an object of worship. It was powerfully geometrical,
streaming out parallel rays and with an orb of concentric circles, like a
dartboard. Its light fell on the Sussex Downs as regular lattices of lines; it
netted the sea. Here at Belle Tout it does the same: Ravilious snares it
through the severe panes of the lantern, organising light to light, dangerously
and divinely bright.
Happy accident in 1939, then: the thick emulsion burns through, and the
Sun, which should be bright, is dark instead, a vanished point. The effect is
called solarisation. Elsewhere in California at the time Robert Oppeneimer is
exploring the physics of the black hole; soon he will be working on the sun-
bright bombs. As Adams develops the picture, the black sun’s light comes
silver off the stream, flares white in the lens, casts the bare tree into shadow
as if burnt.
541,795 Suns from Sunsets from Flickr (Partial) 01/23/06, 2006 (Detail,
2000 - 4 x 6” machine c-prints). By Penelope Umbrico (courtesy of the
artist)
Every phone becomes a camera; every camera turns to the softened, sinking
sun. Penelope Umbrico looks at Flickr, a then-newish photo-sharing app,
and finds that “sunset” is the most common tag. In January 2006 she
downloads 541,795 images; by 2019 she has 43,186,046. She selects, she
centres, she crops, she prints. From time to time a subset will be installed
somewhere, all the same, all different, a work of art unknown, for the most
part, to the phone-wielders who made it possible. The endlessly repeated
Sun slips from the focus; the creators’ shared, anonymised delight in the Sun
becomes the subject in and of itself, an array of a thousand pinholes through
which the light comes in.
It was, in fact, only half a Sun, an electric lower hemisphere reflected into
wholeness by a mirrored ceiling that contrived to make the Tate’s cavernous
turbine hall yet bigger. Where ancient sunlight stored in oil was once
released and turned back into power a new source of sort-of sunlight sat low
and unchanging. David Nye, a historian, introduced the idea of the
“technological sublime”; recapturing nature in a quondam power station in
2013 Mr Eliasson made it his own. It felt as if it should be ominous: an
ersatz Sun without a sky. But the gallery-goers loved it. They sat in front of
it as if at the beach. They lay on their backs and looked at their rufous
reflections above, making sun angels as they would snow angels. It was their
sun, they said, theirs to enjoy.
Also try:
This week we published an essay and a leader on the way in which sunlight,
as captured by photovoltaic cells, is changing the world. Earlier this year we
wrote about the continuing relevance of Impressionism, the movement that
took its name from Monet’s image of sunrise at Le Havre 150 years ago. In
2019 we wrote in appreciation of some of Mr Eliasson’s other works, and in
2020 a retrospective piece on Land Art discussed the work of Nancy Holt,
her husband Robert Smithson, and others. Our obituaries editor has a lot
more to say about Ravilious, the Sun, Sussex, souls and more in her book
“Six Facets of Light”. Our essays editor talks of artwork made by
photosynthesis in his book “Eating the Sun”. ■
This article was downloaded by zlibrary from https://www.economist.com/the-economist-reads/2024/06/19/how-to-stare-at-the-sun-
through-art
Economic & financial indicators
Economic data, commodities and markets
Economic & financial indicators | Indicators
Slowly, limping and swaying with a sort of palsy, a young woman was led
across the grass. Her name was Jarmila. She was 27, but had the body of a
wasted child. Rain was pouring down; two women sheltered her with an
umbrella. She had come to see Birubala Rabha because her sister-in-law beat
her, and called her a witch. But all she really wanted was a room of her own
in her brother’s house. Inside the hall where Birubala was she went to sit
alone, a child-woman with a reedy voice and huge pleading eyes. But
Birubala made a compromise between her and her brother. At the end
Jarmila crumpled to the ground, crying, to seek her brother’s blessing. He
had agreed that he would give her a room and never call her a witch again.
As he left, he touched the feet of Birubala and, with a namaste, thanked her.
Those feet were hard with constant travelling on unmade hill roads between
the villages of Assam. Birubala was no more than a peasant herself, a tribal
woman, simple and uneducated beyond class five; a farmer’s daughter,
married at 15, who had grown crops and reared poultry to bring in little bits
of money, as most did in this remote north-eastern corner. Her house, like
theirs, had a tin roof and woven bamboo walls, with little furniture except
her mosquito-netted bed and a tin trunk for papers. Her dialect was so
particular to her home village, Thakurbila, that other Assamese struggled to
understand it. But one hateful word had motivated her life and driven her
travels: daini, a witch.
Between 1991 and 2010, more than 1,700 women in rural India were killed
for being witches. They were declared so by tribal bej or medicine men, and
also by their own communities. When crops failed or people fell ill for no
apparent reason, the blame was almost always placed on women, usually the
single, widowed or old. They were said to use the evil eye, or spells and
amulets, to wither stems or stop hearts. If they were not lynched, they were
tortured by being burned, tonsured, stripped, beaten and expelled from their
villages. The police were loth to penalise a tradition that ran deep. Besides,
many believed in it themselves.
It was all nonsense, nothing but superstition, as she told everyone who
would listen. The bej were quacks and frauds. The real reason for this
treatment was probably to let relatives grab the victim’s property, express
some bitter resentment, or end an argument. Sometimes, sheer ignorance
was the cause. Over the years she gathered a small team, 19-20 victims and
sympathisers, to put pressure on the police and state government to stop it.
From 2011 her Mission Birubala purposely set out to rescue women; by her
reckoning she saved around 90 lives, 35 of them personally. In 2018 came
her best victory: the implementation of a law in Assam, said to be the
strictest in India, which would send a person to prison for up to seven years
for calling someone a witch.
She had been called one herself. In 1985, when he was 15, her eldest son
Dharmeswar began to become mad. In despair, and because she had not yet
abandoned the old beliefs, she and her husband went to the local quack, who
told them, for a handful of betel nuts and leaves, that their son was in thrall
to an evil spirit. That spirit was now pregnant; in three days the child would
be born and their son would die. She was stricken, but of course he did not
die; he lived for years, though his madness did not go away. Then, in 1996,
her husband died of throat cancer. At that point even her close relatives
declared her a witch and shunned her.
Though she often blamed men and the patriarchy for witch-hunting, she
knew it was not so simple. Women were just as ready to call another woman
a witch. They could often be their own worst enemy. But as for the men,
those she knew best had not been troublesome. Her father had died when she
was six and her mother, a midwife, was often away, leaving her in charge.
Her elder brother Rana, who was scared of being left in the house alone,
came to depend on her. She was not scared. Her husband, though much older
than she was, never criticised her campaigning, even cooking his own meals
when she was out. Her brother-in-law helped set up her first village group, in
1985, to call for better roads and to stop the men drinking. Eventually she
made fine allies of the police superintendents of Goalpara and Kokrajhar, as
well as the politicians who drove the witch law through.
The state was proud of its law, and of her. Her work was recognised, too, by
the Indian government, and she was nominated for the Nobel peace prize.
That was all very well. But witch-hunting still went on in India’s most
backward parts, and her team was so small. What she needed were more
resources, especially to build an ashram for persecuted women.
In her house, where light filtered through the bamboo walls, she searched in
her tin trunk. It was full of her awards, framed or loose, in carrier bags. She
arranged some along the floor for the visiting government reporter, but they
were not what she was looking for. She wanted to show him the tiny ID
photos of nine women. They had been tonsured and exiled, and she had
rescued them. Saving lives was the important thing. ■
This article was downloaded by zlibrary from https://www.economist.com/obituary/2024/06/20/birubala-rabha-fought-to-end-the-
stigmatisation-of-women
Table of Contents
The world this week
Politics
Business
KAL’s cartoon
This week’s covers
Leaders
The exponential growth of solar power will change the world
AI will transform the character of warfare
Emmanuel Macron’s project of reform is at risk
How to tax billionaires—and how not to
Javier Milei’s next move could make his presidency—or break it
India should liberate its cities and create more states
Letters
Letters to the editor
By Invitation
Ray Kurzweil on how AI will transform the physical world
Vladimir Putin’s war against Ukraine is part of his revolution against
the West
Briefing
How AI is changing warfare
Essay
Solar power is going to be huge
United States
Republicans are favoured to win the Senate. What would they do?
Are America’s leading presidential candidates up to it?
America is educating a nation of investors
Lauren Boebert’s primary is a window into everyday Trumpism
New research exposes the role of women in America’s slave trade
Legal immigration to America has rebounded
Donald Trump has finally got it right about the January 6th
insurrectionists
The Americas
Javier Milei has turned Argentina into a libertarian laboratory
Asia
Vladimir Putin’s dangerous bromance with Kim Jong Un
Thailand legalises same-sex marriage
The army-backed establishment in Thailand goes after its enemies
Why India should create dozens of new states
China
China and Russia have chilling plans for the Arctic
China wants to export education, too
China doesn’t want people flaunting their wealth
China’s revealing struggle with childhood myopia
Middle East & Africa
Is a Palestinian state a fantasy?
Israel’s northern border is ablaze
Private firms are driving a revolution in solar power in Africa
A remarkable new era begins in South Africa
Europe
Emmanuel Macron faces heavy losses after a short campaign
A hard-right 28-year-old could soon be France’s prime minister
Hard-right parties are entering government across Europe
Russia’s latest crime in Mariupol: stealing property
Why southern Europeans will soon be the longest-lived people in the
world
Europe today is a case of lots of presidents yet nobody leading
Britain
Britain’s Conservatives rule the Thames Estuary. Not for long
What taxes might Labour raise?
Child poverty will be a test of Labour’s fiscal prudence
Climate change casts a shadow over Britain’s biggest food export
Jeremy Corbyn wants more nice things, fewer nasty ones
The silence of the bedpans
Britain’s Conservatives are losing as they governed. Meekly
International
Brainy Indians are piling into Western universities
Business
China’s giant solar industry is in turmoil
Floating solar has a bright future
India’s electronics industry is surging
The cautionary tale of Huy Fong’s hot sauce
European airlines are on a shopping spree
Nvidia is now the world’s most valuable company
Are manufacturing jobs really that good?
Palmer Luckey and Anduril want to shake up armsmaking
Finance & economics
Why house prices are surging once again
How bad could things get in France?
Europe faces an unusual problem: ultra-cheap energy
Indian state capitalism looks to be in trouble
America’s rich never sell their assets. How should they be taxed?
Think Nvidia looks dear? American shares could get pricier still
Is America approaching peak tip?
Science & technology
The dominant model of the universe is creaking
The secret to taking better penalties
A flower’s female sex organs can speed up fertilisation
How physics can improve image-generating AI
Culture
Wine collectors are at last taking champagne seriously
Theories of pre-history are a mirror on their times
What a row over sponsorship reveals about art and Mammon
Los Angeles is the capital of film noir
Technology has changed money-laundering
How games and game theory have changed the world
The Economist reads
How to stare at the Sun, through art
Economic & financial indicators
Economic data, commodities and markets
Obituary
Birubala Rabha fought to end the stigmatisation of women