9.-Theory-of-tax-incidence-and-optimality
9.-Theory-of-tax-incidence-and-optimality
9.-Theory-of-tax-incidence-and-optimality
TOPIC 7
TAX INCIDENCE
& OPTIMALITY
MICHAEL SACHS
Adjunct Professor | Southern Centre for Inequality Studies
University of the Witwatersrand | Johannesburg
Outline
2
▪ This week
– Partial equilibrium
– Incidence
– Efficiency and deadweight loss
– Commodity taxes
▪ Next week
– General equilibrium
– Income taxes (on labour and capital)
– Equity and progressivity
Readings
3
▪ Institute for Fiscal Studies (2011) Tax By Design: The Mirrlees Review
– Chapter 2 The Economic Approach to Tax Design
▪ Stiglitz, J. E. and Rosengard, J. K. (2015) Economics of the Public Sector
– Chapter 18 Tax incidence
– Chapter 19 Taxation and economic efficiency
– Chapter 20 Optimal taxation
But also …
– Chapter 21 Taxation of capital
– Chapter 22: The personal income tax
▪ Hindriks, J. and Myles, G. D. (2013) Intermediate Public Economics
– Chapter 15 Commodity taxation
– Chapter 16 Income Taxation
▪ Also: Black, P. A., Calitz, E., Steenekamp, T. J. and Black, P. A. (2015) Public Economics
– Chapters 11, 12, 13 and 14
– Good coverage of incidence and efficiency, less on optimal taxation
4
Preliminary issues in
taxation
Tax systems Mirlees Review
5
Introduction to tax
incidence
Atkinson and Stiglitz
Retailer
Consumer
Tax incidence
9
▪ Tax incidence is the study of the effects of tax policies on prices and the distribution of
utilities
▪ Ideally, we would characterize the effect of a tax change on utility levels of all agents in the
economy
▪ In general tax incidence analysis is informative about signs and comparative statics but is
inconclusive about magnitudes
▪ Consider the following argument: Government should tax capital income because it is
concentrated at the high end of the income distribution
– If capital taxes result in less savings and/or capital flighyt then over time the capital
stock may decline, driving return to capital up and wages down
– Some argue that capital taxes are paid by workers and therefore increase income
inequality
Tax incidence in partial equilibrium
11
▪ Assumes
– Two good economy
• Only one relative price so partial and general equilibrium are same
• Might be realistic if:
the market being taxed is small
there are no close substitutes/complements (demands is independent)
• We can think of good one being the taxed good, and good two being all other
commodities.
– Tax revenue is “thrown into the ocean”
– Perfect competition among producers
▪ Commodity taxation - Government levies an excise tax on good x
– Excise or specific tax
– Ad-valorem tax: fraction of prices (e.g. VAT)
Price S1
S0
p0 + t
Tax
p0
Q0 Quantity
Specific tax in a competitive market
14
▪ The burden of the tax is shared between consumers and firms
▪ What happens if the tax was paid by the consumer (or the
retailer at the point of sale)?
Price S1
S0
E1
Price paid by consumer pc
E0
Pre tax price p0
Q1 Q0 Quantity
Specific tax in a competitive market
15
▪ What happens if the tax was paid by the consumer (or the retailer at the point of sale)
▪ The statutory burden is different, but the economic burden is exactly the same.
Price
(received by producer)
S0
Q1 Q0 Q0=Q1
Elastic S1
Inelastic
demand
supply
S0 p0=p1
p0=p1 D
D0
Q1 Q0 Q0=Q1
Tax incidence summary
17
▪ Economic incidence describes who actually bears the burden – whose real income or welfare
changes as a result of the tax
▪ It does not depend on who pays over the money (statutory incidence)
▪ In competitive markets, incidence depends on the elasticity of demand and supply
– If demand is perfectly elastic, consumers bear no burden
– If supply is perfectly elastic, producers bear no burden.
– If demand is perfectly inelastic, consumers bear the full burden
– If supply is perfectly inelastic, producers bear the full burden
Factor markets
18
Introduction to
taxation and efficiency
Welfare analysis of distortionary taxation
20
▪ For the same amount of revenue what is the
difference in welfare (utility) between a
Good 2
distortionary tax and a lump sum tax?
▪ Equivalently: for the same effect on individual
welfare, how much extra revenue (money)
would a lump sum tax have raised?
▪ The difference is the deadweight loss.
E*
E
U’
Good 1
Effects of taxation on behaviour
21
▪ Income effect
– All taxes take income away from individuals, it makes them worse off.
– Individuals make different decisions when their income changes.
– Because they are poorer they postpone their retirement, they cannot enjoy much leisure,
spouses take on work instead of looking after children…
▪ Substitution effect Efforts to avoid taxes by substituting non-taxed for taxed activities
– Not all activities are taxed, or taxed at the same rate.
– Taxation changes relative prices from their economic equilibrium.
– This diverts economic activity from taxed to untaxed areas, or from areas of higher taxes
to areas of lower tax.
– Leisure, household production, subsistence agriculture do not attract taxation. People
seek out untaxed areas – for instance more leisure may mean putting in less effort on the
job, retiring earlier, working shorter hours, or beginning work later in life.
– (Note the contrary impacts on work effort and retirement choice)
▪ Financial effects
– Real activity can be mediated through different forms of payments
– People may prefer payment in cash or in kind to avoid taxation.
– Remuneration may shift from income to capital
– Finance may be provided in the form of debt rate then equity.
Atkinson and Stiglitz p27
Income and substitution effects
22
Good 2
▪ A lump sum tax reduce the consumer’s income
▪ Equivalent to a proportional tax on all consumption goods
▪ Utility falls, but with no substitution effects
Government’s
revenue
U0
b
U1
Good 1
Income and substitution effects
23
▪ A lump sum tax reduce the consumer’s income
Good 2
▪ Utility falls, but with no substitution effects
rb
c
a
U0
b
U1
Good 1
Income and substitution effects
24
c
a
U0
b
U1
U2
Good 1
Income and substitution effects
25
▪ But at point c, utility is lowered even further.
Good 2
▪ U1 – U2 is DWL measured in utility terms: i.e. the fall in welfare that
exceeds the gain in revenue
U0
b
d
U1
U2
Good 1
Magnitudes of the income and substitution effect
26
▪ For the same amount of revenue what is the
Good 2 difference in welfare (utility) between a
distortionary tax and a lump sum tax?
U1 – U2
▪ Equivalently: for the same effect on individual
rc welfare, how much extra revenue (money)
would a lump sum tax have raised?
rd rd - rc
c
a
U0
b
d
U1
U2
Good 1
Magnitudes of the income and substitution effect
27
Good 2
c
a
d U0
U1
U2
Good 1
Magnitudes of the income and substitution effect
28
Good 2
c
a
U0
b
d
U1
U2
Good 1
Magnitudes of the income and substitution effect
29
a
U0
b
U1
Good 1
Deadweight loss (excess burden)
Price ▪ Constant cost supply
a – Infinitely elastic supply means that the
consumer bears the full burden of the tax
increase
– No producer surplus
Consumer
surplus Marginal
b social cost
p
Marginal social
benefit
(Compensated
demand curve)
X0 Quantity
Deadweight loss (excess burden)
Price
a The deadweight loss is the extent to which the
welfare loss exceeds the revenue raised
Consumer DWL = ½ t dX
surplus c
q
t = dP Tax revenue
(tX1) Marginal
DWL b social cost
p
Marginal
social benefit
dX
X1 X0 Quantity
Deadweight loss (excess burden)
Price 1 %∆𝑄 𝑑𝑄/𝑄
𝐷𝑊𝐿 = 𝑑𝑃 𝑑𝑋 𝜀 𝑑 = %∆𝑃 =
2 𝑑𝑃/𝑃
a
(NB: assume constant elasticity in log space)
𝑃 𝑑𝑋
𝜀𝑑 ≡
Consumer 𝑋 𝑑𝑃
surplus 𝑑𝑃 𝑑
q c => 𝑑𝑋 = 𝜀 𝑋
𝑃
𝑡 𝑑
t = dP Tax revenue or 𝑑𝑋 = 𝜀 𝑋
𝑃
(tX1)
DWL b
p
dX
1 𝑡 2 𝑑
=> 𝐷𝑊𝐿 = 𝜀 𝑋𝑃
2 𝑃
q c
t
b
p
X1 X0 Quantity
Proportional to tax rate
Price
d
t
q c
t
b
p
X1 X0 Quantity
Proportional to elasticity
Price
a
q c
t
b
p
X1 X0 Quantity
Proportional to elasticity
Price
a
c
q
t
b
p
X1 X0 Quantity
Question?
37
▪ The ability to shift a tax burden depends on the elasticities of supply and
demand.
▪ The size of the excess burden (or efficiency cost of taxation) is determined by
price elasticities, the size of the tax base and the tax rate.
▪ The more inelastic demand the greater the revenue collection and the smaller
the excess burden.
▪ As the tax rate increases, the excess burden (distortion and welfare impact)
increases by a multiple of the tax rate
▪ Low tax rates on a wide base will lead to lower excess burdens and more tax
revenue than high tax rates on a narrow base.
Introduction to optimal
taxation
What is optimal taxation?
▪ Combine (positive) analysis about efficiency and incidence to reach (normative) conclusions
about the optimal design of the whole tax system
▪ The set of taxes that results in the highest level of welfare while raising the revenue
required by government
– Consumers left free to choose their most preferred consumption plans at the resulting
prices
– Government sets taxes on uses of income in order to accomplish two objectives: Raise a
total amount of revenue (R), Minimize the utility loss for agents in the economy
▪ At least one good is not taxed (e.g. leisure) (so relative prices must change)
▪ Standard assumption : Production prices are fixed (infinitely elastic supply curve)
▪ For now, we assume that income tax is not an option (which is the case in many
developing countries)
constraint
𝑝𝑥 = ℓ U’(ℓ)<0
l
1 labour use,
input
Production
43
▪ One firm (demanding
labour supplying output)
x
▪ The price of output (p) is consumption,
set in competitive output
equilibrium (!) at the profit
maximizing level – i.e
parametric
▪ Production function:
constant returns to scale
▪ So the firm is indifferent to
points on the production Production
frontier frontier
▪ Inside the frontier there is
production inefficiency Feasible
production p
set
l
1 labour use,
input
No taxes
44
▪ Everybody happy
ent
l
1 labour use,
input
A tax on output of the firm
45
▪ Government needs to
raise revenue R
x
▪ The first R units of labour consumption,
input are commandeered output
by government
l
1 labour use,
input
R
Lump sum tax
46
A lump sum tax
would change the
consumers income, x
without affecting the consumption,
output
relative price of
labour and 𝑝𝑥 = ℓ − 𝑅
consumption
But this is ruled out
by assumption
elst
l
1 labour use,
input
R
A tax on consumption
47
▪ This is achieved by driving a wedge between the cost of production
(p) and the purchase price of output (q)
▪ Labour is not taxed, but this is a normalisation not a real restriction x
▪ A second best world: different agents face different levels of consumption,
taxation output
(𝑝 + 𝑡)𝑥 = ℓ
q
t
p
l
1 labour use,
input
R
Two good economy - production
48
l
1 labour use,
input
R
Two good economy - production
49
q
p
l
1 labour use,
input
R
Two good economy - production
50
l
1 labour use,
input
R
Optimal commodity taxation
51
▪ What is the optimal rate of
taxation on consumption? (q-
p)
x
▪ The optimal commodity tax is consumption,
determined at the highest output
point on the offer curve in the
production set.
▪ The optimal tax rate is t*, which
ensures that:
– The consumer chooses
point e
U0
– By construction this point Offer curve
raises R = t* x*, where x* is
consumption at point e
elst
▪ The optimal rate e, is second best
because elst raises the same e
revenue with a higher level of
utility q
t*
p
l
1 labour use,
input
R
Diamond-Mirlees production efficiency lemma
52
▪ Optimal taxation: The set of taxes that results in the highest level of welfare while raising
the revenue required by government
▪ Modelling approach
– Firms maximize output on the production efficiency frontier
– Constant returns to scale fixes producer prices, and ensures that any demand is met
with supply
– The problem is then divided into two problems
• The consumers problem: Consumer left free to choose most preferred consumption
plans, maximizes utility to derive the offer curve in the context of inevitable price
distortions
• The government's problem: achieve the revenue constraint while maximizing the
consumers welfare by choosing the maximum point on the offer curve.
– The solution is the determined at the highest point of the offer curve in the production
set
– An optimal allocation is chosen (e), and the tax rate is inferred from this point
▪ Commodity taxes are second best, relative to lump sum taxes (the level of welfare is always
lower
Questions unasked
54
▪ In this example we had only one consumer, so equity was not at issue
▪ We also had only one commodity: What is the solution if we have more than one
commodity?
▪ Should all goods have the same rate or should taxes be related to the
characteristics of the good
Inverse elasticity rule Model set up
55
▪ Using only commodity taxes, maximize social welfare subject to raising required
revenue
▪ Labour (input) produces commodities (output)
▪ Labour (x0) is the numeraire , it is the only good not taxed (t0 = 0)
▪ Two commodities (xi where i = 1, 2)
▪ Independent demands (i.e. no cross-price effects) – this is a very strong simplifying
assumption, which is relaxed in the more general model
▪ Commodities are produced competitively at constant returns to scale:
– pi = MC = ci where ci units of labour needed to produce commodity i
– Equilibrium prices are independent of the level of demand
– In equilibrium supply will meet any level of demand.
▪ Producer price: pi = ci
▪ Consumer price: qi = pi + ti
▪ Governments revenue requirement: R = t1x1 + t2x2
Inverse elasticity rule Consumers problem
56
𝑚𝑎𝑥 𝑈 𝑥0 , 𝑥1 , 𝑥2 𝑠. 𝑡. 𝑞1 𝑥1 + 𝑞2 𝑥2 = 𝑥0
ℒ = 𝑈 𝑥0 , 𝑥1 , 𝑥2 + 𝛼 𝑥0 − 𝑞1 𝑥1 − 𝑞2 𝑥2
𝜕ℒ
= 𝑈 ′ 𝑥1 − 𝛼𝑞1 = 0 𝑈 ′ 𝑥1 = 𝛼𝑞1
𝜕𝑥1
𝜕ℒ
= 𝑈 ′ 𝑥2 − 𝛼𝑞2 = 0 𝑈 ′ 𝑥2 = 𝛼𝑞2
𝜕𝑥1
max ℒ = 𝑈 𝑥0 , 𝑥1 , 𝑥2 + 𝜆 𝑞1 𝑥1 + 𝑞2 𝑥2 − 𝑅 − 𝑝1 𝑥1 − 𝑝2 𝑥2
𝑥1 ,𝑥2
▪ NB
– the labour supply is endogenously determined through the consumer’s maximization, so
we can substitute x0 for 𝑥0 = 𝑞1 𝑥1 + 𝑞2 𝑥2
– The consumer’s choices of xi feed directly to the governments revenue constraint (this is
the source of deadweight loss)
– Inverse demand function 𝑞𝑖 = 𝑞𝑖 𝑥𝑖
(since demand is independent; otherwise its too complicated)
𝜕ℒ 𝜕𝑞1 𝜕𝑞1
= 𝑈 ′ 𝑥1 + 𝑈 ′ 𝑥0 𝑞1 + 𝑥1 + 𝜆 𝑞1 + 𝑥1 − 𝑝1 = 0
𝜕𝑥1 𝜕𝑥1 𝜕𝑥1
Inverse elasticity rule Government’s problem 2
58
𝜕ℒ 𝜕𝑞1 𝜕𝑞1
= 𝑈 ′ 𝑥1 + 𝑈 ′ 𝑥0 𝑞1 + 𝑥1 + 𝜆 𝑞1 + 𝑥1 − 𝑝1 = 0
𝜕𝑥1 𝜕𝑥1 𝜕𝑥1
▪ And further rearrange and simplify to conclude and state the inverse elasticity rule
𝑡1 𝜆−𝛼 1
=−
𝑝1 +𝑡1 𝜆 𝜀1𝑑
Inverse elasticity rule
59
▪ The proportional rate of tax on good i should be inversely related to its price
elasticity of demand
𝜆−𝛼
▪ The constant of proportionality is the same for all goods
𝜆
▪ The goods with inelastic demand have lower deadweight loss, and must
therefore attract a higher rate of taxation.
▪ The assumption of independent demand is relaxed to give a more general
version
▪ Very efficient, but is it equitable?
Ramsey tax rule Stiglitz and Rosengard version
60
𝑡𝑖 1 1
=𝑘 𝑑+ 𝑠
𝑞𝑖 𝜀𝑢 𝜀
Chetty (2012)
Lump sum taxes and distortions
64
▪ From an efficiency point of view we should fund expenditure with lump sum taxes
▪ Poll tax (efficient but highly regressive)
▪ If we are concerned with equity or redistribution we need individual specific lump sum tax
related to intrinsic ability
▪ E.g. A height tax:
– In a world where height was was a perfect predictor of income, we could impose a lump
sum tax on height
– Height is observable
– It is endowed and cannot be changed (leaving aside childhood nutrition etc)
▪ But in the real world
– We cannot directly observe individual’s ability
– Revealing ability is not incentive compatible
– Therefore we must tax economic outcomes such as income or consumption
– When we tax outcomes we change incentives to attain those outcomes (e.g. reducing the
income associated with labour may reduce the supply of labour)
▪ This leads to distortions
▪ And distortions lead to a trade off between equity and efficiency
Optimal taxation and Mirrleesian approach
65
▪ Consideration of the optimal system must be flexible enough to consider a variety of forms
▪ Optimal tax system: maximizes social welfare (equity and efficiency) subject to raising
governments revenue requirement
Taxation and labour supply model
66
𝑧
𝑧 = 𝑤ℓ ℓ=
𝑤
𝑧
𝑈 = 𝑈 𝑥, 𝐿 – ℓ = 𝑈(𝑥, ℓ) 𝑈 = 𝑈 𝑥,
𝑤
s.t. 𝑝𝑥 = 1 − 𝑡 𝑤ℓ s.t. 𝑝𝑥 = 1 − 𝑡 𝑧
𝑝𝑥 = 1 − 𝑡 𝑧
Consumption
Consumption
1 − 𝑡 𝑤𝐿
𝑝
𝒙∗ 𝒙∗
a Consumption a
b
Consumption
c
c
b
b
a
a
▪ What if the number of working hours cannot be varied continuously to arrive at preferred
income
▪ In practice, the hours of work are fixed: there is a minimum working day, regulated by firms
and firm-union agreements
▪ Workers must “choose” whether on not to work or not (useful to think of non-working
spouse)
▪ A worker who was indifferent between working and not working is now committed to not
working
Consumption
Consumption
▪ Note that:
– On 45-degree line 𝑇(𝑧)Ƹ
𝑐 ′ 𝑧 = 1 𝑠𝑜 𝑇 ′ 𝑧 = 0
𝑥ො 𝑐 𝑧 = 𝑧 − 𝑇(𝑧)
– At point a c
𝑐 ′ 𝑧 > 1 𝑠𝑜 𝑇 ′ 𝑧 < 0 b
– At point b
𝑐 ′ 𝑧 < 1 𝑠𝑜 𝑇 ′ 𝑧 > 0
▪ A negative (marginal) tax rate implies a a
marginal subsidy
▪ The after tax wage for additional work will
be greater than the before tax wage (e.g.
EITC) 45○
z
𝑧Ƹ
Optimal income taxation High and low skill consumers
72
𝑧
▪ All consumers have the same utility function: 𝑈 = 𝑈 𝑥,
𝑠
z
𝑧Ƹ
Optimal income taxation Maximum marginal tax rate
73
z
Optimal income taxation Lower limit?
74
𝑥 = 𝑐(𝑧)
▪ We showed that (optimally)
the marginal tax rate should be
less than 1
▪ But is there an optimal lower
𝑐 𝑧 = 𝑧 − 𝑇(𝑧)
limit for T’(z)?
▪ To answer we must say 𝑥ො
something about the b c
welfare function and equity
45○
z
𝑧Ƹ
Utilitarian egalitarianism
75
Δ𝑈 𝐻
Δ𝑈 𝐿
Y
R1000 R1000
Optimal income taxation Can marginal tax rate be negative?
76
h1
𝑥ℎ1
UL
𝑥𝑙1 l1
45○
z
𝑧𝑙1 𝑧ℎ1
Optimal income taxation Negative marginal tax rate?
77
𝑥𝑙1 l1
45○
z
𝑧𝑙1 𝑧ℎ1
Optimal income taxation Negative marginal tax rate?
78
▪ What marginal tax rate should we impose on the highest skill people?
▪ Lets post ABC as a candidate for optimality
▪ At point B the gradient of the function is less than 1, due to a positive marginal tax rate
▪ The high income consumer pays over tH to the government
C
tH
45○
z
Optimal income taxation Top end
80
▪ Along alternative tax schedule ABD, the line BD is parallel to the 45 degree line (i.e. with
zero marginal tax rate)
▪ The consumer moves to point b
▪ The government still gets tH
▪ There is a pareto improvement (nobody is worse off as a result of the welfare improvement)
▪ The optimal marginal tax rate for the highest skill person is zero
x
tH D
b C
45○
z
Optimal tax in theory and practice
81