7 Technology
7 Technology
7 Technology
Technology
Technologies
y f ( x1 , , xn )
Production Functions
One input, one output
Output Level y = f(x) is the
production
y’ function
y’ = f(x’) is the maximal
output level obtainable
from x’ input units
x’ x
Input Level
Technology Sets
Technically
y’ efficient plans
The production
y” Technically set
inefficient
plans
x’ x
Input Level
Technologies with Multiple Inputs
What does a technology look like
when there is more than one input?
The two-input case: A production
plan is a vector (x1,x2, y)
Suppose the production function is
y f ( x 1 , x 2 ) 2x 1/ 3 1/ 3
1 x2 .
Technologies with Multiple Inputs
E.g., the maximal output level possible
from the input bundle
(x1, x2) = (8, 1) is
x2
(8,8)
(8,1)
x1
Technologies with Multiple Inputs
Technologies with Multiple Inputs
y
y
x1
Technologies with Multiple Inputs
The complete collection of isoquants
is the isoquant map
The isoquant map is a convenient
way to represent the production
function
1/3 1/3
E.g. y f(x 1, x 2 ) 2x 1 x 2
Technologies with Multiple Inputs
x2
y
x1
Fixed-Proportions Technologies
A fixed-proportions (or Leontieff)
production function is of the form
y min{ a 1 x 1 , a 2 x 2 , , a n x n }.
E.g. y min{ x 1 , 2x 2 }
E.g.
with
Fixed-Proportions Technologies
x2 y min{ x 1 , 2x 2 }
x1 = 2x2
7 min{x1,2x2 } = 14
4 min{x1,2x2 } = 8
2 min{x1,2x2 } = 4
4 8 14 x1
Perfect-Substitutes Technologies
A perfect-substitutes production
function is of the form
y a 1 x 1 a 2x 2 a n x n .
E.g.E.g. y x 1 3x 2
with
Perfect-Substitutes Technologies
y x 1 3x 2
x2
x1 + 3x2 = 9
x1 + 3x2 = 18
x1 + 3x2 = 24
8
6
Isoquants are linear
3
and parallel
9 18 24 x1
Marginal Products
y f ( x1 , , xn )
The marginal product of input i is the
rate-of-change of the output level as
the level of input i changes, holding
all other input levels fixed
That is,
y
MPi
xi
Marginal Products
E.g., if
1/ 3 2 / 3
y f ( x1 , x 2 ) x1 x 2
then the marginal product of input 1 is
Marginal Products
E.g., if
1/ 3 2 / 3
y f ( x1 , x 2 ) x1 x 2
then the marginal product of input 1 is
y 1 2/ 3 2/ 3
MP1 x1 x 2
x1 3
Marginal Products
E.g., if
1/ 3 2 / 3
y f ( x1 , x 2 ) x1 x 2
then the marginal product of input 1 is
y 1 2/ 3 2/ 3
MP1 x1 x 2
x1 3
and the marginal product of input 2 is
Marginal Products
E.g., if
1/ 3 2 / 3
y f ( x1 , x 2 ) x1 x 2
then the marginal product of input 1 is
y 1 2/ 3 2/ 3
MP1 x1 x 2
x1 3
and the marginal product of input 2 is
y 2 1/ 3 1/ 3
MP2 x1 x 2 .
x2 3
Marginal Products
Unless inputs are perfect substitutes, the
marginal product of one input depends
on the amount used of other inputs
Constant
y’ returns-to-scale
x’ 2x’ x
Input Level
Returns-to-Scale
If, for any input bundle (x1,…,xn),
f (kx 1 , kx 2 , , kx n ) kf ( x 1 , x 2 , , x n )
2f(x’) y = f(x)
f(2x’)
Decreasing
f(x’) returns-to-scale
x’ 2x’ x
Input Level
Returns-to-Scale
If, for any input bundle (x1,…,xn),
f (kx 1 , kx 2 , , kx n ) kf ( x 1 , x 2 , , x n )
2f(x’)
f(x’)
x’ 2x’ x
Input Level
Returns-to-Scale
y = f(x)
Increasing
returns-to-scale
Decreasing
returns-to-scale
x
Input Level
Examples of Returns-to-Scale
The Cobb-Douglas production function is
y x 1a 1 x a2 2 x n
an
.
Scale up all input levels proportionately
by k. The output level becomes
a1 a2 an
(kx 1 ) (kx 2 ) (kx n )
Examples of Returns-to-Scale
The Cobb-Douglas production function is
y x 1a 1 x a2 2 x n
an
.
Scale up all input levels proportionately
by k. The output level becomes
a1 a2 an
(kx1 ) (kx 2 ) (kxn )
a1 a 2 an a1 a 2 an
k k k x x x
Examples of Returns-to-Scale
The Cobb-Douglas production function is
y x 1a 1 x a2 2 x n
an
.
Scale up all input levels proportionately
by k. The output level becomes
(kx1 ) a1 (kx 2 ) a 2 (kxn ) an
k a1k a 2 k an x a1 x a 2 x an
k a1 a 2 an x1a1 x a
2
2 x an
n
Examples of Returns-to-Scale
The Cobb-Douglas production function is
y x 1a 1 x a2 2 x n
an
.
Scale up all input levels proportionately
by k. The output level becomes
a1 a2 an
(kx1 ) (kx 2 ) (kxn )
a1 a 2 an a1 a 2 an
k k k x x x
a1 a 2 an a1 a 2 an
k x1 x 2 xn
a1 an
k y.
Examples of Returns-to-Scale
The Cobb-Douglas production function is
y x 1a 1 x a2 2 x n
an
.
At
what rate can a firm substitute
one input for another without
changing its output level?
Technical Rate of Substitution
x2
x'2
y
x'1 x1
Technical Rate of Substitution
The slope of the isoquant is the
x2 rate at which input 2 must be
substituted by input 1 so as not
to change the output level.
x'2 It is the
Technical Rate of Substitution
y
x'1 x1
Technical Rate of Substitution
How is the TRS computed?
Same as always
Use total differentiation on y f ( x 1 , x 2 ).
We want to introduce a small change
(dx1, dx2) in the input bundle such that
the output does not change
y y
0 dx1 dx 2 .
x1 x2
Technical Rate of Substitution
y y
0 dx1 dx 2
x1 x2
rearranges to
y y
dx 1 dx 2
x1 x2
so
dx 2 y/ x 1
dx 1 y/ x 2
Technical Rate of Substitution
dx 2 y/ x 1 MP1
dx 1 y/ x 2 MP2
dx 2 y / x1 ax1a 1xb2 ax 2
.
dx1 y / x2 a b1 bx1
bx1 x 2
Technical Rate of Substitution; A
Cobb-Douglas Example
x2 1/ 3 2 / 3 1 2
y x1 x 2 ; a and b
3 3
ax 2 (1 / 3)x 2 x2
TRS
bx1 ( 2 / 3 ) x1 2x 1
8 x2 8
TRS 1
2x 1 24
4 x1
Technical Rate of Substitution; A
Cobb-Douglas Example
x2 1/ 3 2 / 3 1 2
y x1 x 2 ; a and b
3 3
ax 2 (1 / 3)x 2 x2
TRS
bx1 ( 2 / 3 ) x1 2x 1
x2 6 1
TRS
2x 1 2 12 4
6
12 x1
Well-Behaved Technologies
Awell-behaved technology is
monotonic, and
convex
Well-Behaved Technologies -
Monotonicity
Monotonicity:More of any input
always generates more output
y y
monotonic
not
monotonic
x x
Well-Behaved Technologies -
Convexity
Convexity: If the input bundles x’
and x” both provide y units of output
then the mixture tx’ + (1-t)x”
provides at least y units of output,
for any 0 < t < 1
Well-Behaved Technologies -
Convexity
x2
x'2
x"2
y
x'1 x"1 x1
Well-Behaved Technologies -
Convexity
x2
x'2
tx'1 ( 1 t ) x"1 , tx'2 ( 1 t ) x"2
x"2
y
x'1 x"1 x1
Well-Behaved Technologies -
Convexity
x2
x'2
tx'1 ( 1 t ) x"1 , tx'2 ( 1 t ) x"2
x"2 y
y
x'1 x"1 x1
Well-Behaved Technologies -
Convexity
x2 Convexity in technology
implies that the TRS
x'2 decreases (in absolute value)
as x1 increases
Combining inputs
x"2 increases output
x'1 x"1 x1