Chapter 5. The international financial architecture under pressure
Norbert Gaillard and Michael Waibel
https://orcid.org/0000-0003-3584-5428
https://orcid.org/0000-0002-3777-8487
Abstract
The present international financial architecture (IFA) has been weakening since the early 2010s.
Several factors have hindered the reorganization of the current IFA, accelerated the bipolarization
of international financial relations, and reshaped the balance of power between sovereign debtors
and creditors as well as between creditors themselves. The post-Bretton Woods IFA has been
centered around the United States. The U.S. dollar has remained the world’s most important
reserve currency. The Federal Reserve and the U.S. Treasury have acted as the only reliable
international lenders of last resort since 2008. Further, the United States has a veto at the
International Monetary Fund. China has launched regional initiatives that threaten to fragment
the IFA. It has signed central banks swaps agreements to prevent cross-border spillovers and
internationalize the renminbi. The Asian Infrastructure Investment Bank is a key institution to
support the Belt and Road Initiative. The New Development Bank is another innovative and
independent institution. In fact, China is reshaping the IFA primarily through its sovereign lending
and debt restructuring practices. Chinese contracts are built on harder terms than Western
contracts, showing that China wants its creditors to obtain preferential treatment in the event of a
default.
*******
Section 1. Introduction1
The international financial architecture (IFA) can be defined as the governance rules and practices
established and implemented by formal and informal international financial organizations as well
as by some powerful national institutions and firms (e.g., central banks, financial institutions, and
credit rating agencies) to ensure an efficient, successful, and sustainable global monetary and
financial system. The current IFA has evolved significantly since the Bretton Woods Agreement
of 1944. The intensification of economic and financial relations between industrialized and
emerging countries, the collapse of economic planning, the growing public and private debts in all
regions of the world have made the IFA increasingly complex, which has led to heated debates.
For example, the key role played by the International Monetary Fund (IMF) since the 1980s has
stirred controversy (Flores Zendejas and Gaillard, 2022). Second, the efficiency of macroprudential
rules – established since the 2000s to preserve the stability of the banking system and fight systemic
risk – has been seriously questioned (see Montanaro’s chapter in this volume). Third and more
importantly, the increasing financialization of the U.S. economy (as well as other economies) has
1
been endangering the IFA since the late 2000s, which requires ambitious reforms to transform U.S.
capitalism (Gaillard and Michalek, 2022b).2
However, the economic and political rise of the People’s Republic of China (PRC) may also have
destabilizing effects on the IFA. Echoing the arguments advanced in China and emerging countries,
Chin and Thakur (2010, p. 119) point out that “the multilateral order cannot hold if the power and
influence embedded in international institutions is significantly misaligned with the real
distribution of power.”
This chapter puts this statement into perspective and argues that the present IFA has been
weakening since the early 2010s, partly because of the U.S.-China rivalry. Several factors have
hindered the reorganization of the IFA, accelerated the bipolarization of international financial
relations, and reshaped the balance of power between sovereign debtors and creditors as well as
between creditors themselves.
Section 2 shows that the post-Bretton Woods IFA is centered around the United States. The U.S.
dollar has remained by far the world’s reserve currency and the largest credit rating agencies (e.g.,
Moody’s and Standard & Poor’s) and financial institutions (e.g., JPMorgan Chase and Bank of
America) are headquartered in the United States. Next, the Federal Reserve and the U.S. Treasury
have become more powerful than ever, acting as the only reliable international lenders of last resort
(ILOLR) since the global financial crisis of 2008. Further, the United States has managed to keep
its veto at the IMF and has prevented any large-scale reform. Lastly, Washington can exclude
countries (e.g., Cuba, Iran, and Russia) from the international financial system by imposing
economic and financial sanctions.
Section 3 argues that the PRC has challenged the international institutions promoting the existing
liberal international order at the margins. China is now ranked third in terms of voting power at the
IMF and the World Bank and self-classifies as a developing country in the World Trade
Organization (WTO), but it is not a Paris Club member and does not participate in the Organisation
for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) Arrangement on Officially Supported
Export Credits. Instead, China launched initiatives that may be fragmenting the IFA, reflecting a
shift from a reformist to a revisionist stance (Nicolas, 2014). China signed central banks swaps
agreements with East Asian, European, and Latin American authorities to prevent cross-border
spillovers, preserve regional value chains, and internationalize the renminbi. Next, the BRICS
(Brazil, Russia, India, China, and South Africa) Contingent Reserve Arrangement could become
an alternative to the IMF in the medium-long term. Although the Asian Infrastructure Investment
Bank is a key institution to support the Belt and Road Initiative (BRI), it works with the World
Bank on various projects. The New Development Bank is a more innovative and independent
institution.
Section 4 investigates why and how China is reshaping the IFA through its sovereign lending and
debt restructuring practices. Chinese contracts are built on harder terms (e. g., collateral
arrangements, confidentiality, cancellation, acceleration, stabilization, and cross-default clauses)
than Western contracts. Chinese interests abroad are also considered interdependent and “solidary”
by the PRC, which involves diplomatic pressures on foreign debtors. In addition, the features of
Chinese debt restructuring practices are idiosyncratic: ‘No Paris Club’ clauses and the controversy
2
regarding the status of China Development Bank show that the PRC wants its creditors to obtain
preferential treatment in the event of a default.
Section 5 contends that the growing debt of developing countries, partly driven by the U.S.-China
rivalry, may be the underrated weakness of the IFA. At least two nonexclusive scenarios can be
envisaged in respect of the future path of debt in developing countries. The first is a possible “debt
trap” caused by debt overhang, as illustrated by Sri Lanka and possibly several African countries.
The second involves debtor and creditor moral hazard problems, which will inevitably weaken the
position of certain creditors. In either case, developing economies may pay a high price for being
at the fore of major geopolitical battles. Section 6 concludes.
Section 2. How the United States defends the status quo
Since the collapse of the Bretton Woods system in 1973, the IFA has been largely dominated and
centered around the United States. Concretely, Washington has managed to maintain the status of
the U.S. dollar as the foremost international currency, ensured the globalization of the world
economy, averted systemic risk, preserved its influence on key international financial institutions
(especially the IMF), and sanctioned “delinquent” countries financially.
2.1 The U.S. dollar as the foremost international currency
The privileged status of the U.S. dollar (USD) is a fascinating and complex phenomenon. The U.S.
currency is backed by the most powerful military in the world (thus reflecting the capacity to
protect American vital interests worldwide), the largest economy in terms of gross domestic
product (GDP), and a long-standing triple-A sovereign debt credit rating. As a result, it is not
surprising that the USD accounted for more than 64% of the world’s foreign exchange reserves, on
average, between 1973 and 20213 and played an outsized role in the invoicing of global exports
(Boz et al., 2020). It is also noteworthy that T-Bonds and T-Bills remain safe-haven assets during
high-risk aversion periods. For instance, the market yield on the U.S. 10-year bond declined, on
average, by more than 15% during the six domestic recessions observed since 1980.4
2.2 International finance and globalization
A second aspect of Washington’s dominance is its unique capacity to enlarge the “battlefield”
where it has a decisive competitive advantage: international finance. Several factors coalesced to
boost world financial globalization and support the U.S. hegemony on the IFA. On the eve of the
fall of communism, the “Washington Consensus” – a term coined by economist John Williamson
(1990) – served as a macroeconomic roadmap for many governments in advanced as well as
emerging countries. This Consensus spurred free trade, liberalization of inward foreign direct
investments (FDI), privatization, and deregulation. Between 1990 and 2020, annual world trade
volume and FDI stock jumped 4% and 10%, respectively. 5 The financialization of the world
3
economy, especially through the development of derivatives markets and the decisive influence of
the International Swaps and Derivatives Association, headquartered in New York City (Pistor,
2019), further strengthen this pattern.
In this context, the increasing accommodative monetary policy conducted by the Federal Reserve6
has encouraged leverage strategies in the United States and abroad. Between 1990 and 2020, the
total amount of international debt securities outstanding rose by a factor of 18, more than 42% of
this debt being denominated in USD.7
In the meantime, globalization contributed to blur the lines between capital-exporting and capitalimporting nations. It also entailed a high degree of interdependence and competition between
economies (Gaillard, 2020). Thus, it is not surprising that the tight co-movement in international
assets prices reinforced the global financial cycle among industrialized economies by
synchronizing risk appetite and exacerbating potential contagion and spillover effects (see Jordà et
al., 2018).
2.3 Fighting systemic risk
The latter point leads to the capacity of the United States to prevent major financial crises and fight
systemic risk. The first “policy tool” used by Washington involves credit rating agencies, such as
Moody’s and Standard & Poor’s (S&P), two U.S. firms. The basic job of rating agencies consists
in assessing credit risk. Their methodologies compel borrowers to remain solvent on their bond
debt because debt restructuring or missed payments can be considered a default and result in a
downgrade to the bottom of the rating scale. The incorporation of credit ratings in international
regulatory rules and investment funds’ prudential rules (very frequent until recently) transformed
credit rating agencies into gatekeepers of capital markets and drove up the cost of default. 8
Countries that failed to restore their credit position (such as Argentina and Venezuela) went through
severe economic and political crises.
The second tool was the development of macroprudential policies in the aftermath of the global
financial crisis (see Montanaro’s chapter in this volume). As early as 2009, the Financial Stability
Forum (FSF) published a report designed to address procyclicality in the financial system (FSF,
2009).9 This report was followed by a rich academic literature advocating the implementation of
macroprudential rules (e.g., additional capital requirements; additional liquidity requirements;
restrictions on assets, liabilities, or specific activities; and taxation) to fight systemic risk. These
rules were (and are still) considered indispensable in times of high interconnectedness between
too-big-to-fail (TBTF) banks and TBTF non-bank financial institutions.
The third tool was the extraordinary capacity of the United States to act as ILOLR. The first step
occurred during the Mexican sovereign debt crisis in the second half of 1982. After hesitation to
support Mexico and other Latin American economies in distress, President Ronald Reagan realized
that a “laissez faire” stance was likely to endanger the U.S. banking system. As a result, within a
few weeks, the White House approved a significant increase in IMF quotas, the Federal Reserve
relaxed its monetary policy, U.S. commercial banks – main creditors of less developed countries –
provided complementary financing to Mexico, and U.S. regulatory authorities agreed to classify
4
Mexican debt as performing loans on the books of U.S. banks (Gaillard and Michalek, 2022a).
These measures precluded the collapse of international financial markets, as had happened in the
early 1930s.
In the subsequent years, Washington intervened in a timely manner to avert systemic risk. During
the Asian crisis of 1997, the Clinton administration encouraged the IMF to rescue distressed
countries10 while the Federal Reserve arranged a bridge loan for Thailand and convinced U.S.
banks to restructure the short-term debt owed by South Korea. This last move reduced risk aversion
dramatically. During the global financial crisis and the Covid-19 pandemic, the Federal Reserve
acted as ILOLR.11 It conducted exceptional open market operations, both in terms of the amounts
offered and the maturity of the securities. It also expanded its lending facilities and broadened the
range of counterparties and eligible collateral. Next, it established dollar liquidity and foreign
currency swap lines with the central banks of major industrialized and emerging countries. Lastly,
it cut the funds rate to a range of 0% to 0.25%. The U.S. accommodative monetary policy
implemented between 2007 and 2021 eased access to capital markets and supported governments
that borrowed in USD.
2.4 U.S. influence on the IMF
The status quo in the IFA has also been underpinned by the capacity of the United States to maintain
its hegemony on Bretton Woods institutions. The most striking case is that of IMF governance. For
decades, the United States has managed to keep its veto at the IMF (i.e., more than 15% of vote
shares; see Hallaert, 2020; Shaffer and Waibel, 2015; Gu and Tong, 2022) while reforming the
institution when necessary. For example, a general allocation of Special Drawing Rights equivalent
to $650 billion was approved in August 2021 to boost global liquidity and fight the recessionary
effects of the pandemic. The Biden administration was concerned that developing countries might
turn to Chinese banks to meet their borrowing needs.12 This strategy has reinforced the status of
the IMF and complemented the ILOLR role played by the Federal Reserve.
Last but not least, a close examination of IMF loans with very soft conditionality13 reveals that
these are granted to U.S allies that implemented orthodox policies in recent decades (e.g., Colombia,
Mexico, Morocco, and Poland).14 Thus the United States continues to exert a major influence on
IMF policy.
2.5 U.S. financial and economic sanctions
An important yet overlooked dimension of the IFA involves U.S. economic sanctions against
“delinquent” foreign governments. As of August 5th, 2022, the Office of Foreign Assets Control
of the U.S. Department of the Treasury administered and enforced 38 sanctions programs. The
most recent and most spectacular program, established in February 2022, has targeted Russia after
its army invaded Ukraine. Numerous sanctions are directly related to the IFA.15
U.S. financial institutions were required to close many banks’ accounts of Russian nationals and
reject any future transactions while the U.S. Treasury froze their assets. Russian banks were also
5
removed from SWIFT, the Western financial messaging system. The Central Bank of the Russian
Federation was prevented from using its international reserves in many Western jurisdictions,
including the United States. Lastly, the Treasury blocked Moscow from paying USbondholders,
which led to the historic default of Russia in June 2022.
The sanctions against Russia have shown that Washington can exclude a country from the
international financial system and destroy its credit position. This “financial hyperpower” has been
increasingly questioned and constitutes a key incentive for emerging economies to de-dollarize the
global financial system (see Liu and Papa, 2022).
Section 3. The ‘South-South’ dynamics driven by China
The PRC did not actively challenge the U.S.-led IFA until the global financial crisis. It used
complementary tactics to contest the U.S. hegemony and promote an alternative world economic
order, in line with some form of “financial nationalism” (Helleiner and Wang, 2019). Chinese
authorities refrained from joining several informal Western organizations to preserve their freedom
of action and champion South-South cooperation. They also launched last-resort policy tools to
support non-industrialized countries and built independent global payment infrastructures for
international transactions. In addition, China established new development banks to promote its
investments abroad and launched its own global financial infrastructures.
3.1 China as part of the ‘Global South’
Although it has been the second largest economic power in terms of GDP and a net capital exporter
for a few years, China has repeatedly rejected the constraints that a classification as “developed
country” would have entailed. For example, as the PRC does not participate in the Arrangement
on Officially Supported Export Credits,16 it is not compelled to impose restrictions on the financing
terms and conditions when providing official export credits. Next, China’s persistent claim of its
“developing member” status at the WTO aims to take advantage of the special and differential
treatment provisions granted by the institution (see Gmeiner’s chapter in this volume).17
Particularly controversial is the PRC’s decision to remain outside the Paris Club, despite its status
as a top official creditor.18 It seems that China has remained reluctant to submit to several key
principles of the club, such as information sharing, conditionality, and the comparable treatment of
public debts.
In fact, China’s policy reflects a mix of ideological and pragmatic positioning. China is eager to
preserve its image of “emerging country” to increase its geopolitical clout among the South. In the
meantime, it systemically tries to be a rule-maker to maximize its economic and financial gains.
This stance is consistent with the initiatives launched for a decade to break the perceived U.S.
stranglehold on the IFA.
3.2 New facilities to provide liquidity to emerging and developing countries
6
China has promoted two significant international facilities that partly compete with the institutions
and arrangements established by the present IFA: (i) bilateral and multilateral swap agreements
and (ii) the so-called BRICS Contingent Reserve Arrangement (CRA).
The Chiang Mai Initiative (CMI) was launched in 2000 by the Association of Southeast Asian
Nations (ASEAN), 19 plus China, Japan, and South Korea. This bilateral currency swap
arrangement (CSA) was designed to address potential short-term liquidity difficulties in the
aftermath of the Asian crisis. In 2010, the CMI Multilateralization (CMIM) succeeded the CMI:
with current resources of $240 billion, this multilateral CSA is more ambitious: it aims to prevent
balance-of-payments disturbances. Since the early 2010s, the People’s Bank of China (PBOC) has
also signed a growing number of bilateral swap lines with counterparts on five continents. In
December 2020, China was involved in 31 bilateral CSAs amounting to the equivalent of $567
billion (Perks et al., 2021).20 The development of these swap agreements has contributed to boost
cross-border trade and internationalize the renminbi (Song and Xia, 2020).
The BRICS CRA was established in 2014 in reaction to the persistent underrepresentation of the
BRICS (especially China) at the IMF. Contrary to the rules in force at the Washington-based
institution, none of the five parties has a veto power. The committed resources of the CRA, which
total $100 billion, 21 are split into two portions. The “de-linked portion”, equal to 30% of the
maximum access for each party, is available with limited conditionality. In contrast, the remaining
70% is contingent on an agreement with the IMF. This dichotomic scheme suggests that the BRICS
CRA remains embedded in the present IFA. However, in the medium-long term, this emergency
reserve fund could become a credible alternative to the IMF (see Würdemann, 2018).
The BRICS CRA and the currency swap agreements involving the PBOC have so far
complemented rather than competed with the US-led IFA. The ability of the PRC to create an
alternative IFA fundamentally depends on its willingness to act as ILOLR, as Washington has done
since the early 1980s.
3.3 The New Development Bank and the Asian Infrastructure Investment Bank
The New Development Bank (NDB) and the Asian Infrastructure Investment Bank (AIIB),
established in 2014, to counter the influence of the Asian Development Bank and the World Bank,
respectively, two institutions perceived be spearheaded by Japan and by Western countries.22 They
also support the BRI, launched in 2013 by Chinese leader Xi Jinping. It created a hub-and-spoke
network but one that is difficult to assess due to its fluidity and lack of transparency (Wang, 2019a;
Lorenzo, 2021; Dreher et al., 2022). The examination of the governance, the objectives, and the
lending policy of the NDB and the AIIB shows that these two entities have challenge the IFA on
the margins.23
In 2020, the AIIB was composed of 83 members. Most industrialized countries have joined the
bank, with Japan and the United States as exceptions. The PRC has a veto power, which mirrors
the U.S. position in the Bretton Woods institutions. The founding members of the NDB are the
BRICS: they have equal shareholding power and none of them has a veto.
7
During 2016–2020, 68% and 75% of the projects approved by the AIIB and the NDB, respectively,
were sovereign loans. Around 52% of the AIIB projects and 75% of the NDB projects involved
energy, water, transport infrastructures, and urban developments (AIIB, 2021a; NDB, 2021). The
two institutions insist that there is no policy conditionality attached to their loans, contrary to the
procedures applicable at the IMF, the World Bank, and multilateral development banks (Stephen
and Skidmore, 2019; NDB, 2019). However, there may still be conditionality attached to lending
along the Belt and Road in practice, and such lending may also create other types of dependency
of borrowing countries. Neither the AIIB nor the NDB activities have contributed thus far to dedollarize the world economy: in December 2020, 96% of total financial assets of the AIIB and 73%
of the loans granted by the NDB were denominated in the U.S. currency (AIIB, 2021b; NDB, 2021).
The lessons is that the AIIB is not designed to upset the IFA but is part of a broader strategy to
selectively reshape international economic institutions in China’s favor (Wang, 2020). The
numerous partnerships formed with the World Bank tend to support this view. The NDB may
embody an alternative model soon, provided the BRICS manage to increase their lending facilities
and use mostly local currencies (Wang, 2019b).
3.4 China’s bank card network and international payment system
A remarkable evolution observed since the 2010s has been China’s capacity to bypass U.S. global
financial infrastructures. Two successful ventures deserve examination: UnionPay and CrossBorder Interbank Payment System (CIPS).
Launched in 2002, UnionPay is a Chinese financial services corporation headquartered in Shanghai
and approved by the PBOC. It has become a major supplier of bank payment cards – ahead of Visa
and MasterCard – and reports a high acceptance rate, ranging from 70% in Europe and North
America to 90% in the Asia Pacific.24 CIPS was established in 2015 as an alternative to SWIFT.
Although CIPS conducts only $50 billion worth of volume daily, compared to $400 billion for
SWIFT, 25 the growth of its coverage has been impressive (+900% between October 2015 and
December 2020).26
UnionPay and CIPS promote broader international use of the renminbi. One may expect that this
trend will continue in the coming years. As China is the top economic partner of many U.S.sanctioned countries (e.g., Russia, Iran, Venezuela, North Korea, and Cuba), 27 those countries
could complete the de-dollarization of their trade and financial system in the next decade.
3.5 The limits of challenging the U.S.-led IFA
For a few years, Chinese authorities have had to endure the status quo on specific issues, either
because it has been in their own interest to do so or because they refrained from challenging U.S.
leadership.
Consider the PRC’s strategy regarding its holdings of U.S. Treasury securities. Between December
2017 and May 2022, the percentage of China in all foreign holdings in federal debt declined from
19.1% ($1,185 billion) to 13.2% ($981 billion).28 Although China will continue to diversify its
8
foreign exchange reserves, there are few comparable alternative risk-free investments (He et al.,
2016; Bernanke et al., 2020). Moreover, since the United States is China’s largest customer, a
massive selloff of T-Bonds and T-Bills could destabilize the two economies and lead Washington
to retaliate by implementing new protectionist measures. In addition, such a move could signal a
hardening geopolitical stance and increase the risk of a direct conflict between the two superpowers.
For the moment, it seems that China is neither able nor eager to change the international reserve
system.
Turn now to what has been the most spectacular setback suffered by China in the international
financial field: namely, its failure to develop a credible international credit rating system. In the
aftermath of the subprime crisis of 2007–2008, Chinese policy makers were critical of Moody’s
and S&P. Dagong – a rating firm headquartered in Beijing – made a breakthrough in the sovereign
rating area (Bush, 2021). Dagong’s credit opinions diverged from those of its U.S. competitors in
the sense that emerging economies obtained much higher ratings whereas developed economies
were rated lower (Gaillard, 2011). In fact, Dagong ratings, like those of other Chinese credit rating
agencies, are too politicized and lack objectivity, which has prevented them from obtaining a
regulatory license in the United States. Chinese authorities were so concerned by Chinese domestic
credit rating agencies that they allowed S&P to rate domestic Chinese bonds in 2019. 29 This
decision – unprecedented for a foreign firm – evidenced the low credibility of Chinese credit rating
firms on their own domestic market.
Section 4. Sovereign lending and debt restructuring practices: The Chinese way
Documentation of China’s capital exports is opaque. China does not report on official lending and
does not provide comprehensive standardized data on overseas debt stocks and flows. Credit rating
agencies do not monitor sovereign borrowing from official lenders. Commercial providers such as
Bloomberg and Dealogic do not track China’s official overseas loans. The PBOC does not publish
its sovereign bond purchases or the composition of its portfolio. China is not subject to standard
disclosure requirements of the Paris Club, the OECD Creditor Reporting System, and the OECD
Export Credit Group. China reports to the BIS, but the coverage is incomplete. As a result, the data
and information used here come from a small set of research works. Although they may not match
perfectly, they provide a good overview of the activities of Chinese creditors.
4.1 The features of Chinese lending practices
China’s economic growth and enormous trade surpluses since the late 1990s have led to the
accumulation of massive foreign exchange reserves available for use as a foreign policy tool (Horn
et al., 2021; Dreher et al., 2022). Such global imbalances are not a new feature of the global
economy but have raised tensions in the increasingly conflictual China-U.S. relationship (Frieden,
2009; Eichengreen, 2015; Shaffer and Waibel, 2016). Today, China is the world’s largest creditor,
far outstripping the combined Paris Club members. Over the last decade, non-Paris club members
9
such as the PRC have become more important. In 2016, non-Paris Club debt accounted for 13% of
low-income countries’ public debt (Essl et al., 2019, p. 6). Besides, of $45 billion in scheduled
sovereign debt interest payments due in 2020, $6.2 billion was owed to Paris Club members and
$11.4 billion to China.30
Chinese debt contracts are built on harder terms, including confidentiality clauses, collateral
arrangements, cancellation, acceleration, and stabilization clauses. Chinese creditors have signed
over 2000 loan agreements with developing countries since the early 2000s. Although these loan
agreements are subject to far-reaching confidentiality clauses, Gelpern et al. (2021) obtained a
sample of 100 contracts, based on which they found indications that Chinese entities use
standardized contracts varying by lender. China’s state-owned entities blend commercial and
official lending terms and introduce novel ones to maximize commercial leverage over the
sovereign borrower and secure repayment priority over other creditors. Around 30% of the
contracts include a special bank account that effectively serves as security for debt repayment, an
approach uncommon in sovereign lending since the early twentieth century.31 The consequence
may be that a substantial share of debtor countries’ revenues is under the secret effective control
of a single creditor, resulting in countries having a servicing capacity less than, and a risk of debt
distress greater than, those assessed by conventional measures based on publicly available sources
(Gelpern et al., 2021, pp. 4–6). Loan agreements used by China Eximbank and China Development
Bank (CDB) all include versions of a cross-default clause, standard in commercial debt but
uncommon in the context of bilateral or multilateral official lending. Certain loan agreements also
allow cross-default to be triggered by actions adverse to the interests of “a PRC entity” (Gelpern
et al., 2021, p. 7).
Although Chinese domestic debates have often criticized IMF and World Bank conditionality in
lending, Chinese lending shows forms of conditionality itself (Mattlin and Nojonen, 2015;
Chesterman, 2016). Chinese-style conditionality comes in four varieties: First is political
conditionality, including “basic diplomatic and political preconditions prior to receiving any
funding”, in respect of the diplomatic isolation of Taiwan. The second is embedded conditionality,
including “project-related demands regarding, for example, the use of Chinese-sourced contractors,
sub-contractors, technology, equipment suppliers, management and training, as well as a Chinese
workforce,” whereby “making aid conditional on the purchase of donor country products and
technologies is one of the main economic aims of foreign aid.” The third is cross-conditionality,
making conditions established by other creditors de facto conditions for loan disbursements by a
new creditor.32 The fourth is emergent conditionality, describing the structural effects a history of
funding and investment might create in the future, for example with Chinese-built infrastructure
creating technological, financial, managerial, and educational dependencies of a host country on
China (Mattlin and Nojonen, 2015).
Lastly, it is noteworthy that Chinese interests abroad are considered interdependent and ‘solidary’
by the PRC. China has low involvement, for its size as a lender, in “vertical funds” combining
private and public investment from multiple countries for sector-specific global development goals
in areas including agriculture, climate, education, health, and regional and national reconstruction
(Morris et al., 2021, pp. 28–31). Stand-alone and “100% made in China” projects are prioritized.
10
4.2 The features of Chinese debt restructuring practices
China is not member of the Paris Club: this poses major challenges for at least some restructurings,
given the size of China’s loans. Concretely, close to three quarters of the debt contracts reviewed
by Gelpern et al. (2021) contain so-called “No Paris Club” clauses, expressly compelling the
borrower to exclude Chinese debts from restructuring in the Paris Club of official bilateral creditors
and from comparable debt treatment. These clauses predate and are in tension with the PRC’s
commitments under the G20 Common Framework for Debt Treatments beyond the World Bank’s
Debt Service Suspension Initiative (DSSI) announced in November 2020, in particular the
commitment of G20 governments to coordinate debt relief terms for eligible countries (Gelpern et
al., 2021, pp. 6–7).
Turn to CDB, the world’s largest national development bank and China’s largest institution for
overseas investment. In 2019, CDB had total assets of $2.4 trillion. It typically lends at rates above
those of the World Bank, although sometimes below in cases of political interest. Depending on
context, CDB can act as both an official and a commercial creditor. CDB has the status of a
development finance institution to support China’s national initiatives and prioritize political
objectives over profits. Unlike China Eximbank, CDB does not offer officially subsidized loans.
Moreover, the Chinese government insists that CDB is not an official bilateral lender but instead a
commercial bank under the DSSI. In development circles, CDB is seen as lacking international
experience and credit risk management expertise, with less international staff than the PBOC
(Rudyak and Chen, 2021, pp. 5–6).
Contrary to China Eximbank, CDB loan restructurings do not require a government-to-government
agreement. Decisions are made within the bank and remain rather decentralized, partly because
CDB has several regional branches. Debt renegotiations involving CDB most frequently lead to
rescheduling. This outcome is less favorable than that observed for China Eximbank’s and China
International Development Cooperation Agency’s restructured loans, which are likely to include
not only maturity extension but also haircuts. In a few cases, the latter agency may concede writeoffs (Rudyak and Chen, 2021, pp. 13–17).
According to Beers et al.’s (2022) database, at least 25 sovereign borrowers were in default on
China’s bilateral official loans in 2021. 33 Angola, the Republic of the Congo, Pakistan, and
Venezuela accounted for 87% of total defaulted debt to Chinese official creditors.34 In general, the
capacity of a distressed country to obtain a significant debt restructuring from China is contingent
on several factors: the availability of alternative financing sources, a leadership change in the
borrowing country, and tight bilateral relations between the borrower and China (Kratz et al., 2019).
Horn et al. (2021) consider that the geopolitical objectives of the Chinese government influence
Chinese official lending. They also estimate that about 50% of China’s lending may be “hidden.”
Despite significant Chinese lending to crisis countries such as Iran, Venezuela and Zimbabwe over
the past 15 years, China has not reported bank claims towards these countries to the BIS. Whereas
other official creditors often lend to developing countries on concessionary terms with long
maturities and at below-market rates, China often lends at market terms (with risk premia), with
11
shorter maturities, and with collateral clauses that secure repayment through commodity export
proceedings (e.g., oil and wheat), giving China a seniority among other creditors. In these regards,
China’s lending shows parallels with British, French, and German foreign lending in the 19th
century, likewise market-based, partially collateralized by commodity income, and closely tied to
political and commercial interests.
Section 5. The underrated weakness of the IFA: The growing debt of developing
countries
At least two (nonexclusive) scenarios can be envisaged in respect of the future path of debt in
developing countries. The first is a possible “debt trap” caused by debt overhang. The second
involves the risk of debtor and creditor moral hazard. The short- and medium-term scenario is
contingent on the future of the DSSI and the Common Framework.
5.1 Debt overhang
Aggressive lending practices by China have already drawn attention in cases of financially
distressed states, such as Zambia and Sri Lanka, which have borrowed significantly from Chinese
lenders, thus suggesting that the PRC is engaging in “debt trap diplomacy”. This term was coined
in 2017 by Brahma Chellaney, a professor of strategic studies at the New Delhi-based Center for
Policy Research. He mentioned the China-Sri Lanka “debt for equity” deal for the port of
Hambantota to popularize the notion that China engages in predatory lending. 35 The term has
attained great popularity, generating nearly two million search hits on Google by 2018 as well as
criticism that it has become a “meme” (Brautigam, 2020).
In the case of Sri Lanka, although Chinese investment as part of the Belt and Road Initiative
postdates Sri Lanka’s reliance on debt to fund internal conflicts with Tamil groups, Chinese BRI
investment has allowed China to build, then obtain majority shareholdings in and a 99-year lease
over, the port of Hambantota. In the case of Zambia, U.S. National Security Advisor John Bolton
alleged in 2018 that China was making “strategic use of debt to hold states in Africa captive to
Beijing’s wishes and demands”, including purported plans to take over Zambia’s national power
company and airport. In response to Bolton’s comments, Zambia lodged an official protest with
Washington, emphasizing in a press conference that Zambia did not use state assets or state
enterprises as collateral for its loans with China (Brautigam, 2022, p. 1357).
The theory of ‘debt trap diplomacy’ has also been expressed as a theory of ‘institutional eclipse’,
with China acting as an ILOLR, providing a bilateral alternative outside of the current IFA. In this
view, China offers debtor states emergency lending on more favorable terms – or in any event with
reduced or more attractive conditionality – than the IMF in exchange for economic and diplomatic
advantages: “Lending to countries across the developing world has assisted China’s efforts to
export construction services, import natural resources, and secure important votes in international
fora, such as Cambodia’s decision to block the Association of Southeast Asian Nations (ASEAN)
12
from issuing a joint statement rejecting China’s territorial claims in the South China Sea”
(Sundquist, 2022).
Other authors express skepticism over the scope of any political or diplomatic ambitions behind
Chinese lending. Brautigam argues that evidence remains “weak for the ‘debt trap diplomacy’
hypothesis, which asserts that China deliberately indebts countries for the purpose of acquiring
leverage and strategic assets.” She finds that, in the case of Zambia, China has exerted at most
limited political pressure (and generated domestic political resistance) in spite of a large volume of
lending. She also identifies potentially positive elements in the Chinese development philosophy,
for example the critique by Li Ruogu, the former president of Eximbank, that the IMF Debt
Sustainability Analysis framework fails to consider what debt is used for. China’s BRI debt
sustainability framework, announced in 2019, differs in its willingness to lend notwithstanding a
high risk of debt distress in case of growth-oriented projects. Brautigam suggests that Chinese
lenders may be “supporting Zambia’s strategic vision, lending for projects with high growth
potential” (Brautigam, 2022, pp. 1350–1351).
Regardless of whether borrowing from Chinese lenders entails an intentional loss of sovereignty
in favour of China, it is uncontroversial that Chinese lenders routinely impose stricter and more
expensive terms than peer official lenders, potentially leading to increased poverty in debtor states.
Chinese banks structure their loans to give them discretion to trigger cancellation or default
remedies, increasing economic pressure on debtors and the incentives to repay.
Another negative assessment draws on theories of debt dilution, according to which Chinese
lending strategies intentionally exacerbate cooperation problems between creditors. In the absence
of a sovereign insolvency mechanism, lenders seek de facto seniority, for example by agreeing
contractual terms that are difficult to restructure in a crisis. The stricter terms of newer loans will
facilitate fresh lending but dilute the seniority of existing debt, resulting in a “bad” debt structure
that is extremely hard to restructure. Gelpern et al. (2021) note that this interpretation gels with the
Chinese loan agreements reviewed, including the “No Paris Club” and special account (cash
collateral) clauses, which are contractual terms effecting greater seniority and repayment
advantages. As stated above, Chinese creditors provide debt relief predominantly through debt
reprofiling, rather than face value debt reductions generally accepted by the Paris Club and private
creditors, even in case of exogenous shocks such as the COVID-19 pandemic. Lengthy
renegotiations resulting at best in maturity extensions without interest or principal reductions can
contribute to worsening debt overhang that is unresolved, hampers growth and sustains poverty for
years or even decades.
5.2 Debtor and creditor moral hazard
The rivalry between the United States and China may encourage debtor moral hazard akin to what
was observed in the second half of the 1970s, with debtors shopping for loans and exacerbating
competition between lenders. For example, the Export–Import Bank of the United States (U.S.
Eximbank) and China Eximbank may compete to provide lending for projects and states of
questionable creditworthiness to pursue geopolitical aims. Darbellay and Gaillard (2022, pp. 69–
13
71) give the example of U.S. Eximbank’s approval of a $5 billion loan to Mozambique in 2019,
the largest direct loan in its history, despite S&P rating Mozambique in “selective default” when
the loan was approved. U.S. Eximbank emphasized its interest in the integrated liquefied natural
gas project being carried out by U.S. companies, rather than by Chinese and Russian companies in
the event of financing from those countries.
Creditor moral hazard has materialized among Western systemic banks since the 1980s (see Flores
Zendejas and Gaillard, 2022) but it can arise within the institutional framework of Chinese lending
as well. Erie (2021, p. 107) notes that, because state-owned enterprises “rely on the Party State for
insurance and on the PRC government as an arbitrator in their disputes with the host government,
they tend to take excessive risks.” This problem arises with institutions in other countries, such as
the U.S. Eximbank, but it “is more pronounced in state capitalism given the muted role of
independent decision-making. Moral hazard has long been a problem in the Chinese domestic
economy: governmental guarantees to enterprises against insolvency de-incentivize firms from
internalizing risk.”
There is a growing risk of massive sovereign defaults and disorganized debt restructurings, as in
the 1930s and 1940s (Wynne, 1951). An assessment of this risk is made difficult by the
confidentiality clauses and secrecy of Chinese lenders, which in parallel appear to be contributing
to tensions between the World Bank and the present IFA, on the one hand, and Chinese lenders, on
the other. Chinese entities have already effectively diluted and antagonized the World Bank.
A recent World Bank publication urging “transaction-level debt transparency” mentions China
only in passing, namely in the context of criticizing Chinese lending in Zambia, but it is difficult
to read the publication other than as addressed to China, the global leader for confidential project
finance in official lending. The World Bank authors emphasize that debt transparency is a critical
basis for debt sustainability and creditworthiness assessments. Significantly, they also mention,
without providing specifics, that their paper was “prompted by disclosure-related challenges and
friction points that became evident during recent periods of widespread debt distress in developing
countries.” In particular, the authors mention instances of “(i) the non-sharing of transaction-related
information with IFIs that perform debt sustainability assessments and generate global debt
information for stakeholders; (ii) revelations of ‘surprise’ and ‘hidden’ debt; (iii) undisclosed
granting of collateral and quasi-collateral that, if disclosed, may impact creditor assessments of
borrower liquidity or creditworthiness; and (iv) inter-creditor mistrust and tensions during debt
restructurings” (Maslen and Aslan 2022, pp. 9 and 13). This expresses succinctly four key
categories of pressure exerted by Chinese lending on the current IFA today.
Section 6. Conclusion
The IFA has gone through a series of substantial changes since 1944. They include the shift to a
floating exchange rates regime in the 1970s, the pervasive role played by the IMF, the Federal
Reserve, and the U.S. Treasury since the 1980s, and the establishment of international
microprudential and macroprudential rules since the advent of financial globalization in the 1990s.
14
All these changes were spurred by U.S. authorities, who have aimed to fight systemic risk and
protect the rights of international creditors.
The emergence of China as a major commercial, economic, and financial power has exacerbated
its rivalry with the United States and may be undermining the current IFA. The activities of the
AIIB and the NDB – two China-based international institutions – do not seem to question
fundamentally the present IFA. In contrast, Chinese sovereign lending and debt restructuring
practices not only do they create coordination problems between creditors but they also burden
developing countries with debt. These two issues should be tackled right now to prevent economic
and geopolitical crises.
References
Asian Infrastructure Investment Bank (2021a) 2020 AIIB Annual Report. Beijing: AIIB.
Asian Infrastructure Investment Bank (2021b) Auditor’s Reports and Financial Statements for the
Year Ended Dec. 31, 2020. Beijing: AIIB.
Bank for International Settlements (1998), 68th Annual Report. Basel: Bank for International
Settlements.
Beers, D., Jones, E., McDaniels, K. and Quiviger, Z. (2022) “BoC–BoE Sovereign Default
Database: What’s New in 2022?,” Bank of England.
Bernanke, B. S., Bertaut, C., Pounder DeMarco, L. and Kamin, S. B. (2011) “International Capital
Flows and the Returns to Safe Assets in the United States, 2003–2007,” International Finance
Discussion Paper No. 1014, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.
Block, C. (2022) “Design and Cost of U.S. Responses to the 2007–2009 Financial Crisis and the
2020 Covid-19 Pandemic,” in Flores Zendejas, J., Gaillard, N. and Michalek, R. (Eds) Moral
Hazard – A Financial, Legal, and Economic Perspective. Abingdon: Routledge.
Boz, E., Casas, C., Georgiadis, G., Gopinath, G., Le Mezo, H., Mehl, A., and Nguyen, T. (2020)
“Patterns in Invoicing Currency in Global Trade,” IMF Working Paper WP/20/126.
Brautigam, D. (2020) “A Critical Look at Chinese ‘Debt-Trap Diplomacy’: The Rise of a Meme,”
Area Development and Policy, Vol. 5, No. 1, pp. 1–14.
Brautigam, D. (2022) “China and Zambia: Creating a Sovereign Debt Crisis,” International Affairs,
Vol. 98, No. 4, pp. 1347–1365.
15
Bush, C. (2021) “The Rise and Fall of Dagong Global Credit Rating Agency: A Geopolitical
Challenge for the Rating Industry,” Journal of Financial Regulation, Vol. 7, No. 2, pp. 319–324.
Chesterman, S. (2016) “Asia’s Ambivalence about International Law and Institutions: Past, Present
and Futures,” European Journal of International Law, Vol. 27, No. 4, pp. 945–978.
Chin, G. and Thakur, R. (2010) “Will China Change the Rules of Global Order?,” The Washington
Quarterly, Vol. 33, No. 4, pp. 119–138.
Darbellay, A. and Gaillard, N. (2022) “Moral Hazard in the Export Credit Industry,” in Flores
Zendejas, J., Gaillard, N. and Michalek, R. (Eds) Moral Hazard – A Financial, Legal, and
Economic Perspective. Abingdon: Routledge.
Dreher, A., Fuchs, A., Parks, B., Strange, A. and Tierney, M. J. (2022) Banking on Beijing: The
Aims and Impacts of China’s Overseas Development Program. Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press.
Eichengreen, B. (2015) Hall of Mirrors: The Great Depression, the Great Recession, and the Uses
and Misuses of History. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Erie, M. S. (2021) “Chinese Law and Development,” Harvard International Law Journal, Vol. 62,
No. 1, pp. 51–116.
Essl, S., Celik, S. K., Kirby, P., and Proite, A. (2019) “Debt in Low-Income Countries – Evolution,
Implications, and Remedies,” World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 8794.
Financial Stability Forum (2009) Report of the Financial Stability Forum on Addressing
Procyclicality in the Financial System. Basel: Financial Stability Forum.
Flores Zendejas, J. and Gaillard, N. (2022) “The International Lender of Last Resort between Scylla
and Charybdis,” in Flores Zendejas, J., Gaillard, N. and Michalek, R. (Eds) Moral Hazard – A
Financial, Legal, and Economic Perspective. Abingdon: Routledge.
Frieden, J. A. (2009) “Global Imbalances, National Rebalancing, and the Political Economy of
Recovery,” Council on Foreign Relations, Center for Geoeconomic Studies.
Gaillard, N. (2011) A Century of Sovereign Ratings. New York: Springer.
Gaillard, N. (2016) “Coping with Reliance on Credit Ratings,” Banking & Financial Services
Policy Report, Vol. 35, No. 7, pp. 12–21.
16
Gaillard, N. (2020) Country Risk: The Bane of Foreign Investors. Cham: Springer.
Gaillard, N. and Michalek, R. (2022a) “The Institutionalization of Bailouts, 1970–1984,” in Flores
Zendejas, J., Gaillard, N. and Michalek, R. (Eds) Moral Hazard – A Financial, Legal, and
Economic Perspective. Abingdon: Routledge.
Gaillard, N. and Michalek, R. (2022b) “Remarks and Policy Recommendations to Fight Moral
Hazard,” in Flores Zendejas, J., Gaillard, N. and Michalek, R. (Eds) Moral Hazard – A Financial,
Legal, and Economic Perspective. Abingdon: Routledge.
Gaillard, N. and Waibel, M. (2018) “The Icarus Syndrome: How Credit Rating Agencies Lost Their
Quasi Immunity,” SMU Law Review, Vol. 71, No. 4, pp. 1077–1116.
Gelpern, A., Horn, S., Morris, S., Parks, B. and Trebesch, C. (2021) How China Lends – A Rare
Look into 100 Debt Contracts with Foreign Governments. Williamsburg, Kiel, and Washington,
DC: AidData at William & Mary, Kiel Institute for the World Economy, Center for Global
Development, and Peterson Institute for International Economics.
Gu, B. and Liu, T. (2022) “Shareholding Formulas in International Financial Institutions: Learning
from the Asian Infrastructure Investment Bank,” Journal of International Economic Law, Vol. 25,
No. 4, pp. 643–658.
Hallaert, J-J. (2020) “The Tragedy of International Organizations in a World Order in Turmoil,”
ECIPE Policy Brief No. 5/2020, European Centre for International Political Economy.
He, Z., Krishnamurthy, A. and Milbradt, K. (2016) “What Makes US Government Bonds Safe
Assets?,” American Economic Review, Vol. 106, No. 5, pp. 519–523.
Helleiner, E. and Wang, H. (2019) “The Richness of Financial Nationalism: The Case of China,”
Pacific Affairs, Vol. 92, No. 2, pp. 211–234.
Horn, S., Reinhart, C. M. and Trebesch, C. (2021) “China’s Overseas Lending,” Journal of
International Economics, Vol. 133, 103539.
Jordà, Ò., Schularick, M., Taylor, A. and Ward, F. (2018) “Global Financial Cycles and Risk
Premiums,” NBER Working Paper No. 24677.
Kalmoe, N. P. and Mason, L. (2022) Radical American Partisanship – Mapping Violent Hostility,
Its Causes, and the Consequences for Democracy. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
17
Kratz, A., Feng, A. and Wright, L. (2019) “New Data on the “Debt Trap” Question,” Rhodium
Group, Note, available at https://rhg.com/research/new-data-on-the-debt-trap-question.
Liu, Z. and Papa, M. (2022) Can BRICS De-dollarize the Global Financial System? Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
Lorenzo, J. A. P. (2021) “A Path Toward Sustainable Development Along the Belt and Road,”
Journal of International Economic Law, Vol. 24, No. 3, pp. 591–608.
Maslen, S. and Aslan, C. (2022) “Enhancing Debt Transparency by Strengthening Public Debt
Transaction Disclosure Practices,” Equitable Growth, Finance & Institutions Insight, World Bank.
Mattlin, M. and Nojonen, M. (2015) “Conditionality and Path Dependence in Chinese Lending,”
Journal of Contemporary China, Vol. 24, No. 94, pp. 701–720.
Morris, S., Rockafellow, R. and Rose, S. (2021) “Mapping China’s Multilateralism: A Data Survey
of China’s Participation in Multilateral Development Institutions and Funds,” Center for Global
Development Policy Paper No. 241.
New Development Bank (2019) New Development Bank Policy on Sovereign Loans & Loans with
Sovereign Guarantee. Shanghai: NDB.
New Development Bank (2021) Annual Report 2020. Shanghai: NDB.
Nicolas, F. (2014) “La Chine et les institutions économiques multilatérales, entre révisionnisme et
‘statu quo’,” Politique étrangère, Vol. 79, No. 3, pp. 49–61.
Perks, M., Rao, Y., Shin, J. and Tokuoka, K. (2021) “Evolution of Bilateral Swap Lines,” IMF
Working Paper No. 2021/210.
Pistor, K. (2019) The Code of Capital: How the Law Creates Wealth and Inequality. Princeton:
Princeton University Press.
Rudyak, M. and Chen, Y. (2021) “China’s Lending Landscape and Approach to Debt Relief,”
Overseas Development Institute, Emerging Analysis.
Shaffer, G. and Gao, H. (2021) “How China Took on the United States and Europe at the WTO,”
in Shaffer, G. (Ed) Emerging Powers and the World Trading System: The Past and Future of
International Economic Law. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
18
Shaffer, G. and Waibel, M. (2015) “The (Mis)Alignment of the Trade and Monetary Legal Orders,”
in Halliday, T. C. and Shaffer, G. (Eds) Transnational Legal Orders. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
Shaffer, G. and Waibel, M. (2016) “The Rise and Fall of Trade and Monetary Legal Orders: From
the Interwar Period to Today’s Global Imbalances,” in Mallard, G. and Sgard, J. (Eds) Contractual
Knowledge – One Hundred Years of Legal Experimentation in Global Markets. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
Song, K. and Xia, L. (2020) “Bilateral Swap Agreement and Renminbi Settlement in Cross-Border
Trade,” Economic and Political Studies, Vol. 8, No. 3, pp. 355–373.
Stephen, M. D. and Skidmore, D. (2019) “The AIIB in the Liberal International Order,” The
Chinese Journal of International Politics. Vol. 12, No. 1, pp. 61–91.
Sundquist, J. (2022) “Institutional Eclipse: How Chinese Loans Substitute for IMF Assistance,”
mimeo, available at https://jamessundquist.github.io/website/docs/Sundquist_JMP.pdf.
Wang, H. (2019a) “China’s Approach to the Belt and Road Initiative: Scope, Character and
Sustainability,” Journal of International Economic Law, Vol. 22, No. 1, pp. 29–55.
Wang, H. (2019b) “The New Development Bank and the Asian Infrastructure Investment Bank:
China’s Ambiguous Approach to Global Financial Governance,” Development and Change, Vol.
50, No. 1, pp. 221–244.
Wang, H. (2020) “Selective Reshaping: China’s Paradigm Shift in International Economic
Governance,” Journal of International Economic Law, Vol. 23, No. 3, pp. 583–606.
Williamson, J. (1990) “What Washington Means by Policy Reform,” in Williamson, J. (Ed) Latin
American Adjustment: How Much Has Happened? Washington, DC: Institute for International
Economics.
Würdemann, A. I. (2018) “The BRICS Contingent Reserve Arrangement: A Subversive Power
Against the IMF’s Conditionality?,” Journal of World Investment & Trade, Vol. 19, No. 3, pp.
570–593.
Wynne, W. (1951) State Insolvency and Foreign Bondholders – Volume II. New Haven: Yale
University Press.
19
1
Thanks to Benjamin Letzler for research assistance.
The U.S.-led IFA is also indirectly threatened by the mounting radical partisanship in U.S. politics (see Kalmoe and
Mason, 2022).
3
Authors’ computations based on IMF data. In 2021, the percentage reached 59%.
4
Authors’ computations based on Federal Reserve data, see https://fred.stlouisfed.org/series/DGS10.
5
Authors’ computations based on the United Nations Conference on Trade and Development (UNCTAD) and World
Trade Organization (WTO) data.
6
US real interest rates (i.e., the Federal Funds effective rate minus the Consumer Price Index growth rate) fell from
1.9% in the 1990s to 0.1% in the 2000s, and ˗1.1% in the 2010s. Authors’ computations based on Federal Reserve
data.
7
Authors’ computations based on Bank for International Settlements (BIS) data.
8
European and U.S. lawmakers withdrew the references to credit ratings in their financial regulations in the early
2010s (Gaillard and Waibel, 2018). Yet the use of alternative credit measurements has proved difficult (Gaillard,
2016). Investors continue to extensively scrutinize credit ratings.
9
The FSF was a forum including international financial institutions (IFIs) and finance ministries and central bankers
of the Group of Seven. It was succeeded by the Financial Stability Board (FSB) in 2009. When the FSF report was
released, the United States was the country posting the highest number of financial institutions in the world’s 30
largest banks by total assets, see www.gfmag.com.
10
The IMF lent a total of $35 billion to Indonesia, South Korea, and Thailand in 1997 (BIS, 1998, p. 134).
11
See Block (2022) for an overview of how U.S. authorities coped with the two crises.
12
The title of the 2021 IMF Annual Report (“Build Forward Better”) echoes the “Build Back Better” agenda
promoted at the time by President Biden.
13
These specific loans include Flexible Credit Lines (FCLs) and Precautionary and Liquidity Lines (PLLs).
14
See the IMF Annual Reports published since 2012.
15
See https://home.treasury.gov/policy-issues/financial-sanctions/sanctions-programs-and-country-information.
16
This arrangement, set up by the OECD in 1978 to control export subsidies, brings together high-income
economies.
17
In the meantime, Chinese authorities invest massively in building trade law capacity to defend their policy (Shaffer
and Gao, 2021).
18
In 2017, emerging and developing countries owed $380 billion to China compared to $246 billion owed to the 22
Paris Club members (Horn et al., 2021).
19
The ASEAN is composed of ten countries: Indonesia, Malaysia, Philippines, Singapore, Thailand, Brunei
Darussalam, Viet Nam, Laos, Myanmar, and Cambodia.
20
More than 51% of these bilateral swap lines (in volume) were signed with Hong Kong, South Korea, Singapore,
the Eurozone, and the United Kingdom.
21
The top contributing member is Beijing ($41 billion), ahead of New Delhi, Brasilia, and Moscow ($18 billion
each), and Pretoria ($5 billion).
22
The Asian Development Bank and the World Bank are commonly perceived as Japan-led and U.S.-led institutions.
23
Skidmore’s chapter in this volume analyzes how the AIIB and the NDB compete with multilateral development
banks and challenge the global development finance regime.
ent Bank and the World Bank are commonly perceived as Japan-led and U.S.-led institutions.
24
See https://www.unionpayintl.com/en/mediaCenter/newsCenter/companyNews/7374.shtml.
25
See https://asiatimes.com/2022/02/china-can-break-swift-sanctions-but-at-a-high-cost.
26
See https://www.cips.com.cn/cipsen/7050/index.html.
27
Authors’ classification based on https://home.treasury.gov/policy-issues/financial-sanctions/sanctions-programsand-country-information and https://oec.world.
28
Authors’ calculations based on U.S. Treasury data, see https://ticdata.treasury.gov.
29
PRNewswire, “S&P Global Ratings receives first-of-its-kind approval to enter China domestic bond market,” 28
January 2019.
30
https://www.imf.org/Publications/fandd/issues/2020/09/debt-relief-for-the-poorest-kevin-watkins.
31
An exception was the U.S. emergency loan to Mexico in 1995, requiring oil revenues to flow through an account
at the Federal Reserve Bank of New York.
2
20
32
For example, Chinese creditors suspended billions in funding for Indonesian power projects pending resolution of
a small dispute between the Indonesian government and a Chinese lender over a $232 million loan for the purchase
of 15 civilian aircraft from a Chinese manufacturer.
33
Nearly two-thirds of these defaulting countries are African (Angola, Burundi, Cameroon, Cape Verde, Central
African Republic, Chad, the Republic of the Congo, the Democratic Republic of the Congo, Djibouti, Ethiopia,
Gabon, Kenya, Mauritania, Mozambique, Sierra Leone, and Zambia). Others are in Latin America, Asia, and
Oceania (Dominica, Maldives, Pakistan, Papua New Guinea, Samoa, Tajikistan, Tonga, Venezuela, and Yemen).
34
Authors’ calculation based on Beers et al.’s (2022) database.
35
B. Chellaney, “China’s Debt-Trap Diplomacy,” Project Syndicate, 23 January 2017, available at
https://www.project-syndicate.org/commentary/china-one-belt-one-road-loans-debt-by-brahma-chellaney-2017-01.
21