in: R. Segal, K. von Stuckrad (eds.), Vocabulary for the Study of Religion Vol. 1-3 (VSR), Leiden, Boston: Brill
2015. http://referenceworks.brillonline.com/browse/vocabulary-for-the-study-of-religion
Economics of Religion
Academic work in economics of religion may be
divided into three systematic groups. A first group
considers the relation and interdependence of
religious and economic action, mentality, or habitus. The framework of this work is cultural theory
more than economic theory. A second group critically examines theories of economics, e.g. capitalism, market liberalism, or (popular) books or
trainings on leadership. They question these discourses for their normative or even ideological patterns. A third group borrows analytical tools from
economics in order to understand religion. Even
if these endeavors are not entirely separable, it is
mainly works in the third sense that have recently
founded a discipline of economics of religion.
The economics of religion (as distinct from
a religious economy) has existed in the narrow
sense as a discipline only since the 1980s, following American studies in rational choice sociology
by Rodney Stark, William S. Bainbridge and Roger
Finke, and studies in the neoclassical economics
of religion by Laurence Iannaccone. In Germany,
Burkhard Gladigow urged in a programmatic
article that scholars of religion should make a
study of the financial conditions and the economic embeddedness of religion (1995). The late
development of this new perspective in the study
of religion is explained by referring to the fixation
on religious meaning, textuality, and experience.
However, discourse traditions which also, or among
other things, see a relationship between religion
and economy are much older, and are more diversified today (Wuthnow 2005; Koch 2014). The economics of religion as a specialization within the
study of religion is part of a more comprehensive development in which cultural analyses are
extended to include the economic system. It also
plays a role in economic anthropology and new
economic sociology, economic ethics, the psychoanalytical critique of capitalism, and other disciplines. Today, even suicide bombers are analyzed
Koch A._Economics of Religion.indd 1
in terms of their economic calculation in a symbolic economy of gift, sacrifice, and annihilation
(e.g. Strenski 2003; Iannaccone and Berman 2006).
In some cases it has given rise to polemical arguments: Pierre Bourdieu, for instance, used the term
“economic imperialism” with reference to the way
rational choice (RC) economics has been extended
to the description of society—as in the classic studies by Becker 1976 of “household” (in sociological
terms: family), and “human capital.” At the same
time, Bourdieu’s sociology does something similar
when it refers to social analysis as a general theory
of the economy of practices under conditions of
struggle for reputation.
Ever since the beginning of cultural studies around 1900, and even more so since the cultural turn of the 1970s, scholars have worked on a
bridging theory to explain the relations between
market, organization, and community. From a historical and methodological point of view, this was
done using functional approaches and theories
of action and structure. In this sense, Bronislaw
Malinowski’s functionalist study of a Pacific trading ring is just as good an example of an integrative approach as New Institutionalism which puts
human capital, socialization, and education in a
special relationship to each other. With the aid of
such concordances, the economy finds its place
in cultural and social theories. For the creation of
value always goes beyond purely material scaling
and involves symbolic relations. Thus, for instance,
human capital as reputation depends on the social
milieu, which in some cases attaches more importance to titles and in other cases to muscle power.
Relations of recognition, as in G.W.F. Hegel’s
master-and-servant dialectic, are bound up in
economic value chains. For value is socially determined, in respect of both material usefulness and
affective, aesthetic and communal usefulness.
In what follows we will describe key positions,
then sketch specific approaches in the study of
9/22/2014 6:30:36 PM
2
economics of religion
religion, and conclude with some remarks on
main themes and the potential of the economics
of religion.
Historical Pioneers
In The Wealth of Nations (1776), Adam Smith
reflected upon religion and religious personnel
along with other occupations and market processes. He knew about motivation problems, profit
orientation, and the advantageous effects of competition in respect to religious actors. Karl Marx
emphasized the creation of value through performance; under the influence of the evolutionist model common in his day, and in reaction to
early globalization, he visualized the development
of a society with no social layering of economic
processes, ruled by a global working community.
Equally important is his upgrading of material
things as the basis for ideas and the creation of
meaning. Early scholars in the field of cultural
studies had diverse aspects of the economics of
religion on their agenda. Max Weber closely examined the way religious ethics affect people’s way of
life and production methods all over the world. His
approach to questions of economics and religion
was to become extremely influential. He identified the Berufsmensch (man with a vocation), specialized production by different types of religious
actors, and, similar to Marx’s concept of alienation,
a depersonalizing bureaucracy. For Weber it was
especially a religious normativity which engaged
in a discursive formation with the early capitalist form of economy in Central Europe (Die protestantische Ethik und der Geist des Kapitalismus,
1904‒1905; Die Wirtschaftsethik der Weltreligionen,
1915‒1920). Georg Simmel showed the social consequences of money as a growing material and
symbolic medium of exchange, together with
its substitutes, such as the gift (Philosophie des
Geldes, 1899‒1907). Thorstein Veblen criticized the
way the American rich enjoyed a reputation based
on conspicuous consumption, thus referring to
correlations which Bourdieu later discussed in
Koch A._Economics of Religion.indd 2
connection with different sorts of cultural capital
(The Theory of the Leisure Class, 1898). These scholars were all involved in the early and increasingly
differentiated debates of their era on sociological, socio-political, and economic issues, and they
were interested in the value systems that determine economic behavior.
Marcel Mauss also belongs to this tradition.
Using the evidence of ethnographic and historical material, he showed that the social function of
gift exchange is to create social networks involving
mutual obligations (Le don, 1935). His work was a
reaction to the debilitating trench warfare of the
First World War, and he advised the West to adopt
the gift economy as a more peaceful social form.
In this context, Mauss also acknowledged the potlatch as a destruction of economic values, e.g. the
vicarious death in combat of the group leader.
This work showed that it is always important to
ask what the symbolic and social benefits of gift
exchange processes are, beside material benefits.
Subsequently the simple reciprocity of giving and
taking was criticized as being too bipolar. Later
scholars preferred to speak of the transfer and collective management of resources.
Continental philosophy in France freed itself
from logocentrism with a new philosophical irrationalism, thereby re-shaping the discursive allocation of economics, religion, and ethics. In this
discourse, economics classically appeared on the
side of the rational pole. In 1933 Georges Bataille
used the term “expenditure” (dépense) with reference to the overturning of the capitalist assumption of benefit in loss, sacrifice, and crisis. His basic
materialism was designed to leave behind all oppositions between the material and the spiritual. Gilles
Deleuze and Felix Guattari presented a psychoanalytical social analysis and critique of capitalism,
in which the individual is oppressed because of
being subjected to materialist desires (Capitalism
et Schizophrénie, 1972). As a counter-concept to
this split (“schizophrenia”), they proposed placing
desire in the irrational discursive pole.
Pierre Bourdieu’s religious field was shaped
largely by his reading of Weber, and his economic
9/22/2014 6:30:36 PM
Economics Of Religion
field by empirical studies of the French homebuyers’ market. He achieved great success with his
concepts of types of capital, habitus, and competition for recognition. He unambiguously touched
on the economics of religion with his negative
view of the religious field, taking the example of
the French Catholic Church, which, as he put it,
functions in the “economic universe” according
to the rules of the pre-capitalist “family economy”
(1998). The family economy is based on hierarchy,
patriarchy, honorary office, rights of primogeniture, and similar institutions. Thus, according to
Bourdieu, religious economies function by means
of various strategies aimed at rendering invisible the economic character of value-creation
or exchange processes. These strategies include
the idealization of jobs connected with the celebration of church services (cleaner, verger),
disguising the offering as self-sacrifice instead of
exchange, unbounding the job of the priest so that
he devotes his entire life to God, euphemization of
work performed in an honorary capacity and the
commitment to brotherliness, and finally, denial
of economic activity in general.
In economic anthropology following Malinowski,
two schools developed which saw economic activity as a social phenomenon. The formalist school
took up neoclassical premises which are universally applicable but which are realized differently on the local level; profit maximization, for
instance, can be understood in terms of recognition, integration or wealth (e.g. Raymond Firth,
Melville J. Herskovits). The so-called substantialist school, on the other hand, carried out a complete discursification of the object and argued that
the neoclassical premises could not be applied to
social systems without a market economy (e.g.
Karl Polanyi, George Dalton). These schools differ in their points of reference: in the first case it
is the individual and his (rational) choice, while
in the second it is the social and cultural context.
Against this background, religion is approached
either empirically in terms of its local embeddedness in the political economy (e.g. Donham 2002)
or formalized (e.g. Chesnut 2007).
Koch A._Economics of Religion.indd 3
3
Rational Choice Sociology and
Economics of Religion (“Market Model”)
The market model based on the neoclassical rational choice theory has led to the development of a
highly-interconnected strand of discourse since
the 1970s. Unlike secularization theories, it predicts
that the density of religious options is dependent
on factors such as state regulation of the religious
market, the degree of religious pluralism (supplyside explanations: supply creates demand), and
wealth. To this day, many studies are based on
these axioms (McCleary 2010) or revisions of them
(Stolz 2006).
Peter L. Berger wrote in remarkably stringent
economic terms about the market of American
Protestant denominationalism, its competition,
its cartelizations, and the forming of specific
bureaucratic interdenominational dialogue actors
(1963). A classic study in the field is the application of the microeconomic analysis of household
production by Azzi and Ehrenberg, in which they
found that the accumulation of religious human
capital is a benefit (1975). But it is mainly due to
the sociologists Stark, Bainbridge, and Finke, and
the economist Iannaccone, that the neoclassical
economics of the Reagan era have been applied
to religion. The premises of utility maximization,
stable preferences, and market equilibrium are the
model for explaining human behavior. It has often
been misunderstood as anthropology, instead of
being appreciated as a useful prediction model.
Iannaccone, Stark and Finke discuss themes that
are typical of the 1980s and 1990s: the retreat into
privacy, spirituality, and informal forms of religious belonging. The theory of religion presented
by Stark and Bainbridge in 1987 contains a social
exchange variant of the RC paradigm. Actors expect
a compensation proportional to their contribution
in an interaction. Compensation in the afterlife is
the specific offer made by religious firms.
Iannaccone also notes some correlations worthy of discussion (1994). In his view the uncertainty associated with faith goods is treated in a
manner similar to risks in the world of financial
9/22/2014 6:30:36 PM
4
economics of religion
investments and insurance: diversification or
long-term specialization. Two types of religion are
derived from these two approaches to risk management, based on private or collective production. In
the private production of religious goods, the portfolio is diversified by considering the offers made
by different suppliers. Private production concentrates on fee-for-service transactions. If a product
does not measure up to expectations, there are
other products available from independent suppliers. Iannaccone sees this type mainly in esoteric
religions and in “Asian religions.” Typical examples
of collective production are the Christian churches
as profit-maximizing firms which create institutions for information purposes (theology), set up
authorities, create forms of interaction like witnessing, and generally yield social capital. In order
to solve the problem of free riders, exclusivity is
required, and the costly demands of membership
of a religious group are increased by stigma and
sacrifice. Stigma, or social labeling based on lifestyle, increases the cost of participating in social
activities outside the group, and sacrifice means
high contributions, a special moral code or commitment. The two latter strategies function most
effectively in small religious groups. This leads to
the conclusion that a market equilibrium exists in
cost-intensive sects and low-cost churches.
Critique of Rational Choice Economics
of Religion and New Institutionalism
Two forms of critique of rational choice can be
distinguished: (1) the way it is applied to culture
and religion, and (2) the development of neoclassical theories leading to bounded rationality in
economics.
(1) Scholars of cultural studies object that rational
choice religious economics uses conventional economics to explain practices that have long ago
been dealt with in the more comprehensive context of a cultural theory (Chidester 2008: 84). Thus,
Koch A._Economics of Religion.indd 4
the new economic sociology examines the social
embeddedness of institutions and markets (Mark
Granovetter, Richard Swedberg). Among others,
Christian triumphalism (Alles 2009) and the historical propositions in Stark (Bruce 2002) are criticized. Also, conclusions on the basis of data from a
worldwide survey of religion are somewhat more
ambivalent than the market model would indicate
(Inglehart and Norris 2004; McCleary and Barro
2006).
(2) Results from empirical economics (behavioral economics, game theory) have entered into
the concepts of bounded or quasi rationality: this
means questioning whether economic behavior
is rational, as a result of decision theory, which
also describes in intercultural terms (Henrich
et al. 2004) the broad variety of behaviors such
as altruism, fairness, and reciprocity instead of
maximizing (Kolm and Ythier 2006; Tan 2006).
Equally weighty is the neo-institutionalist criticism starting from so-called transaction costs,
meaning information search costs, costs of monitoring and control, bargaining and decision costs,
or opportunity costs (e.g. of free riders). For this
transaction-costs approach, and the governance
approach (chiefly developed by the economists
Ronald H. Coase in the 1930s and later by Oliver
Williamson), firms are crucial coordination mechanisms in addition to the market; an insight that
is yet to be taken into account by scholars interested in the economics of religion with their
focus on the market. The early model premises
(e.g. market transparency for actors, viewed
as calculating without deceiving, institutions as
exogenous) are too idealized to offer sufficiently
accurate predictions in small institutional structures. A small number of recent studies in the
economics of religion have taken these criticisms
into account in the new-institutional tradition
(Brinitzer 2003). The exchange rates for goods and
types of capital in the religious field and in interaction with other embedments, where there are
no organizational coordinations, also have to be
reconsidered.
9/22/2014 6:30:37 PM
Economics Of Religion
Themes and Potential of the Economics
of Religion
In recent years the discussion has tended to center
around more specific concepts borrowed from economics and economic sociology: cultural religious
production, distribution, signaling, path dependency, marketing, ritualistic formal structures
of organizations, mental models, free riders, risk
behavior, and types of goods. So far, little attention
has been paid to the discursive construction of
markets, for instance, the signaling of narratives.
A socio-culturally sensitive perspective would
also take other things into account. For example,
when considering the commercialization of religious objects, the value of the goods as specifically
religious must first be constructed. This happens, for instance, when they are authenticated
on the graves of religious figures (Zaidman and
Lowengart 2001), or when their aesthetics match
the habitus. Still, from the point of view of RC, the
growth of certain groups, whether Pentecostal
groups in Latin America, or Afro-Brazilian and
New Age groups, is explained by some scholars by
means of attractive products (supply side explanation) such as faith healing and money charms
offered by religious firms that see themselves as
“personal problem-solving agencies” (Chesnut
2007). The decisive thing is that they all have to
make these products attractive to the poor and to
women, as these are the biggest consumer groups.
Besides market-related factors, Chesnut also takes
into account the fact that successful strategies link
cultural conceptions of pneumacentrism as penetration by the Holy Spirit with the gender understanding of femininity of the buyer. For identity is
created through consumption, as demonstrated
recently by the demand for halal food products of
an educated Muslim middle class in the West as
well as in the Near East. Neoliberal consumer culture can be seen as an important framing of these
changes (Martikainen and Gauthier 2013).
The potential of the economics of religion is
twofold. First, religious and economic action is
Koch A._Economics of Religion.indd 5
5
explained in the context of cultural patterns of
action and institutions. Economic models are
extremely valuable, empirically effective, and
differentiated action theories, which can also
be applied to the study of practices and conceptions in the area that is constructed as religion
in a society. New economic institutionalism and
behavioral economics, and to a lesser extent the
older rational choice theory, take into account the
embeddedness of both religion and economics in
cultural dynamics (on the convergence of religion
and capitalism, see Roberts 1995). These studies
are influenced by economic anthropology and
economic sociology. Among all studies in this field,
those must be emphasized which describe religion
and economics as an interface between identityformation, means of coping with life, political
power strategies, and strategies of social recognition. And it is important that neither the cultural
character of actions—in other words institutions
as endogenous factors—nor the stringent, and in
some cases arithmetical, application of any particular economic theory should be neglected.
Second, economic theories and models and
their ideologies are subjected to critical examination by scholars of religion. In the sense of a
most-attractive and most widely-encompassing
value system, today’s financial-market capitalism has been called the “first truly world religion”
(Foltz 2007). The overvaluation of money as a
medium of exchange, for instance, or of trust as
the basis of the market, the regulative effect of
anonymous market forces, new green religion in
karma capitalism which is claimed to be sustainable, the utopias of communism, the silent takeover of spirituality through brands (Carrette and
King 2005), identity-formation or social exclusion
through consumerism, the management consultant as savior, business ethics: all these economic
models, economic evaluations and actors belong
to the field of study of the economics of religion.
Just as economic history is written as a part of cultural history, it is time to also write it as a part of
the global history of religion.
9/22/2014 6:30:37 PM
6
economics of religion
Bibliography
Alles, G., “Religious Economies and Rational Choice: On
Rodney Stark and Roger Finke’s ‘Acts of Faith’ (2000),”
in M. Stausberg (ed.), Contemporary Theories of
Religion, London, 2009.
Azzi, C., and R.G. Ehrenberg, “Household Allocation of
Time and Church Attendance,” Journal of Political
Economy 83(1): 27–56, 1975.
Berger, P.L., “A Market Model for the Analysis of
Ecumenicity,” Social Research 30(1): 77–93, 1963.
Bourdieu, P., “The Economy of Symbolic Goods,” in
Practical Reason: On the Theory of Action, Cambridge
MA, 1998 [1994].
Brinitzer, R., Religion: Eine institutionenökonomische
Analyse, Würzburg, 2003.
Bruce, S., “The Poverty of Economism or the Social
Limits on Maximizing,” in T.G. Jelen (ed.), Sacred
Markets, Sacred Canopies: Essays on Religious Markets
and Religious Pluralism, 167–186, Lanham, 2002.
Carrette, J., and R. King, $elling Spirituality: The Silent
Takeover of Religion, London, 2005.
Carrier, J.G. (ed.), A Handbook of Economic Anthropology, Cheltenham, 2005.
Chesnut, A., Competitive Spirits: Latin America’s New
Religious Economy, Oxford, 2007.
Chidester, D., “Economy,” in D. Morgan (ed.), Key Words
in Religion, Media and Culture, 83–95, New York, 2008.
Donham, D.L., “On Being Modern in a Capitalist World,”
in B. Knauff (ed.), Critically Modern: Alternatives,
Alterities, Anthropologies, 241–257, Bloomington, 2002.
Foltz, R.‚ “ ‘The Religion of the Market’: Reflections of a
Decade of Discussions,” Worldviews 11: 135–154, 2007.
Gladigow, B., “Religionsökonomie, eine Subdisziplin
der Religionswissenschaft,” in H.G. Kippenberg and
B. Luchesi (eds.), Lokale Religionsgeschichte, 253–
258, Marburg, 1995.
Henrich, J., R. Boyd, S. Bowles, C. Camerer, E. Fehr, and
H. Gintis (eds.), Foundations of Human Sociality:
Economic Experiments and Ethnographic Evidence
from Fifteen Small-Scale Societies, Oxford, 2004.
Iannaccone, L.R., “Rational Choice: Framework for the
Social Scientific Study of Religion,” in L.A. Young
(ed.), Rational Choice Theory and Religion, 24–25,
New York, 1994.
Iannaccone, L.R., and E. Berman, “Religious Extremism:
The Good, the Bad, and the Deadly,” Public Choice
128(1): 109–129, 2006.
Inglehart, R., and P. Norris, Sacred and Secular: Religion
and Politics Worldwide, New York, 2004.
Koch, A., Partly Annotated Bibliography of Economics of
Religion, Open access University of Munich, http://
epub.ub.uni-muenchen.de/12437/, last update:
Feb 2014.
Kolm, S., and J.M. Ythier (eds.), Handbook of the
Economies of Giving, Altruism and Reciprocity I,
Amsterdam, 2006.
Martikainen, T., and F. Gauthier (eds.), Religion in the
Neoliberal Age: Political Economy and Modes of
Governance, Farnham, 2013.
McCleary, R.M. (ed.), The Oxford Handbook of the
Economics of Religion, Oxford, 2010.
McCleary, R.M., and R.J. Barro, “Religion and Economy,”
Journal of Economic Perspectives 20(2): 49–72, 2006.
Richter, R., and E. Furubotn, Institutions and Economic
Theory: The Contribution of the New Institutional
Economics, Ann Arbor, 2005.
Roberts, R.H. (ed.), Religion and the Transformations of
Capitalism: Comparative Approaches, New York, 1995.
Stark, R., and W.S. Bainbridge, A Theory of Religion, New
York, 1987.
Strenski, I., “Sacrifice, Gift and the Social Logic of
Muslim‚ Human Bombers,” Terrorism and Political
Violence 15: 1–34, 2003.
Stolz, J., “Salvation Goods and Religious Markets:
Integrating Rational Choice and Weberian Perspectives,” Social Compass 53(1): 13–32, 2006.
Swedberg, R., Principles of Economic Sociology, Princeton,
2007.
Tan, J.H.W., “Religion and Social Preferences: An
Experimental Study,” Economics Letters 90: 60–67,
2006.
Wuthnow, R., “New Directions in the Study of Religion
and Economic Life,” in N.J. Smelser and R. Swedberg
(eds.), The Handbook of Economic Sociology, 603–
626, Princeton, 22005.
Zaidman, N., and O. Lowengart, “The Marketing of
Sacred Goods: Interaction of Consumers and
Retailers,” Journal of International Consumer
Marketing 13(4): 5–27, 2001.
Anne Koch
Koch A._Economics of Religion.indd 6
9/22/2014 6:30:37 PM