city futures
city futures
confronting the crisis of urban development
edgar pieterse
z e d b o ok s
London & New York
UCT Pr ess
Cape Town
City Futures: Confronting the Crisis of Urban Development
was irst published in 2008 by:
in southern Africa, UCT Press, an imprint of Juta and Company Limited,
Po box 14373, Lansdowne, 7779, south Africa
www.uctpress.co.za
in the rest of the world, zed books Ltd,
7 Cynthia street, London n1 9jf, uk
and room 400, 175 Fifth Avenue, New York ny 10010, usa
www.zedbooks.co.uk
Copyright © edgar Pieterse 2008
The right of edgar Pieterse to be identiied as the author of this work
has been asserted by him in accordance with the Copyright, designs
and Patents Act, 1988
Typeset in Monotype Garamond by illuminati, Grosmont
www.illuminatibooks.co.uk
Cover designed by Andrew Corbett
Printed and bound in the eU by Gutenberg Press Ltd, Malta
distributed in the UsA exclusively by Palgrave Macmillan,
175 Fifth Avenue, New York ny 10010, usa
All rights reserved. No part of this publication may be reproduced, stored
in a retrieval system or transmitted in any form or by any means, electronic,
mechanical, photocopying or otherwise, without the prior permission of zed
books Ltd
A catalogue record for this book is available from the british Library
Library of Congress Cataloging in Publication data available
isbn 978 1 91989 509 3 (UCT Press)
isbn 978 1 84277 540 0 Hb (zed books)
isbn 978 1 84277 541 7 Pb (zed books)
Contents
Figures and tables
vi
Acknowledgements
vii
1
Introduction: deciphering city futures
1
2
Urbanization trends and implications
16
3
Mainstream agenda I: shelter for all
39
4
Mainstream agenda II: good governance
62
5
Reconceptualizing the political in cities
84
6
Informal everyday urbanism
108
7
Counterpoint: alternative urban development
130
8
Making a start towards alternative city futures
161
Notes
177
References
189
Index
200
Figures and tables
Table 1.1
Table 2.1
Table 2.2
Table 2.3
Figure 2.1
Table 2.4
Figure 2.2
Table 2.5
box 3.1
Figure 4.1
Figure 5.1
box 6.1
Figure 7.1
Figure 7.2
box 8.1
Figure 8.1
dimensions of governance
13
The declining time needed for 1 billion additional
urban dwellers
19
Urban population by region, 1950–2010
19
Geodemographic segmentation of Cape Town
28
scale of informal economic activity in developing
countries
30
regional distribution of the world’s urban slum dwellers 31
slum population projections, 1990–2020
32
Cost of water in Accra, Ghana
34
Tenure systems and their characteristics
46
Municipal priorities and trade-offs
82
domains of political engagement in the relational city
89
Urban think tank: Caracas case
119
Institutional dimensions of sustainable
urban development
133
overlapping dimensions of urban planning
152
Typology of poverty reduction domains
165
developmental linkages at the micro scale
171
Acknowledgements
This book is written primarily for progressive urban development
practitioners within (local) governments, development institutions,
NGos and social movements who are in different ways continuously
reining ideas with the aim of advancing a more effective response to
the daunting crises unfolding in cities and towns across the world. In
light of this, the book cannot be read as an academic guide to the
debates, although it does try to bring relevant theoretical perspectives
into conversation with pragmatic considerations in order to clarify
where we stand and where we need to explore to ind more effective
responses to the multidimensional knots of injustice in our cities.
The book has been written in a relatively short space of time,
but it draws on the experience of twenty years in which I have
wrestled with the challenges of urban development and governance
in a range of capacities: as activist, trainer, teacher, researcher, public
policy manager, consultant and, most recently, scholar. I have been
inspired and animated throughout by the tenacity and commitment
of the urban activists whose determination is such that they refuse
to be defeated by the seemingly insurmountable challenges that come
together in cities. I invariably pick up from them something new, often
something almost indeinable, that gives me fresh insights into whatever my praxis or obsession may be at a given time. It is impossible to
viii
city futures
recall all of the generous spirits that I have crossed paths with, and
continue to engage with, but I want simply to acknowledge colleagues,
comrades and friends whom I have accumulated over the years.
signiicant friends and co-conspirators whose ideas and engagements have found their way into many parts of this book are: Askoek
Adhikari, Ash Amin, eve Annecker, Jo beall, Joel bolnick, Andrew
boraine, stephen boshoff, owen Crankshaw, Ntone edjabe, Adi
eindhoven, Alicia Fuentes-Calle, Nthato Gobodo, Graeme Gotz,
Gita Govern, Firoz khan, Christa kuljian, barbara Lipietz, Alan
Mabin, Neo Muyanga, Mokena Makeka, dominique Malaquais, Nisa
Mammon, Frank Meintjies, Tanner Methvin, zayd Minty, Luyanda
Mpahlwa, Njabulo Ndebele, sophie oldield, ebrahim rasool,
kopano ratele, Alan roberts, Jennifer robinson, david schmidt,
bryan slingers, AbdouMaliq simone, Pep subirós, barbara southworth and Vanessa Watson. The sustainable Cities M.A. class of 2007
at the University of stellenbosch was a creative inspiration because
many of the ideas in the book were tried on them for size; their
engagement, alongside that of Mark swilling, contributed greatly to
clarifying my thoughts. katherine Mckenzie offered her valuable time
to proofread the full manuscript under very dificult circumstances
with generosity and professionalism. I am deeply appreciative. I have
also to single out my close friend and intellectual partner in crime, sue
Parnell, who has been a constant source of comradeship, support and
encouragement. zed books, initially with robert Molteno and later
with ellen Mckinlay and her team, have been incredible in terms of
their patience, their professionalism and their commitment.
Family is the constant in our lives that makes it possible to express
ourselves. I want to thank all my siblings and their families for their
enduring support, and especially my Mom, who is simply always there
as the unconditional and proud constant. ebrahim rasool, rosieda
shabodien, Tahrir and Tanwir, thanks for your loving support; and,
most importantly, Mirjam van donk and rafael zukile Pieterse,
thanks for the home and fun where I’m allowed to be me.
Finally, writing ebbs and lows to a soundtrack, and the one
carrying this book aloat includes brilliant music by: Tony Allen, MV
bill, the branford Marsalis Quartet, Celso Fonseca, Common, dave
Matthews, Marisa Monte, Cassandra Wilson, roots Manuva, Tom
Waits, Lekou Wanza, richard bona and Toto, Lizz Wright, U-Cef.
For Rafael & Mirjam
1
Introduction:
deciphering city futures
With cities, it is as with dreams: everything imaginable can be
dreamed, but even the most unexpected dream is a rebus that conceals a desire, or, its reverse, a fear. Cities, like dreams, are made up
of desires and fears, even if the thread of their discourse is secret,
their rules are absurd, their perspectives deceitful, and everything
conceals something else.1
Nothing about cities in the twenty-irst century is insigniicant; the
stakes are always high in pinning down what cities are, in thinking
about what to do with cities and in acting on/in/through the city,
especially if one wants to bring to life more liberating and just
futures. For this reason it is extremely dificult to ind a conceptual
path that cuts through the vicissitudes of the city without losing
one’s way in blind alleys and dead ends. before I delve into what
will come in the following chapters it is opportune to render explicit
the coordinates that anchor the conceptual lens I use in inding my
way through the maze of competing perspectives and experiences
of the contemporary city.
In very broad terms the literature on the contemporary city in the
global south 2 can be divided between those who take an apocalyptic
view and those who display an irrepressible optimism about the
possibility of solving the myriad problems that beset such cities. For
instance, Planet of Slums by the proliic urbanist Mike davis provides
2
city futures
a relentless catalogue of the utterly devastating conditions that characterize the daily lives of the majority of the world’s urban dwellers.
At the end of this book one is left emotionally devastated but also
virtually incapacitated because on every conceivable front of potential
change, one encounters the superior cunning of an oppressive system
that will simply reinvent the conditions of exploitation. The davis
book foresees an interminable state of exploitation as it awaits the
‘future of human solidarity [which] depends upon the militant refusal
of the new urban poor to accept their terminal marginality within
global capitalism’.3 At this end of the spectrum, scholars and policy
activists insist that without addressing the framing conditions of the
global economy it is not possible to solve urban poverty.
The register of urban implosion inds it dificult not merely to see
victims – victims of corrupt governments (politicians and bureaucrats); victims of unscrupulous private irms that cherry-pick proitable services whilst leaving the poor to fend for themselves; victims
of patronizing NGos that neutralize militant resistance through
their ameliorative ‘good’ works; victims of deeply entrenched cultural
afiliations that get mobilized to exploit and abuse those considered
inferior in terms of race, ethnicity and caste whilst allowing the real
proiteers to get away with the loot; victims of (extreme) weather
conditions due to bad locations in the city, which in turn link back
to being powerless. In the fulcrum of compounded victimhood, it
is almost impossible to imagine possibilities of resistance, liberation
and empowerment. In contradistinction, scholars like Malcolm Jack
treat the urban poor like a ‘blank igure’ with little awareness or
reference to the conditions that must be endured while mainstream
institutions get their act together and pursue a rational policy agenda
that will, incrementally, ix the conditions of urban poverty bit by bit.4
This is maybe an unreasonable depiction of conventional apolitical
policy-prescriptive studies, but it seems to me that unrelexive policy
prescription in the wake of the impasse in development studies – or,
more accurately, when development studies lost its innocence – is
deeply problematic, for it reinforces a conidence among the powerful
that has profound disempowering effects.5
There is a third seam of analysis that attempts to work through the
experiences and ‘everyday practices’ of the urban majority who draw
introduction
3
the short end of the stick in contemporary cities. These commentators draw attention to the pervasive system of informalization – that
is, partially outside of formal economies, conventional governance
systems and enumerated areas – that lows from the unjust structures
of opportunity in cities. However, instead of reading only marginalization and exclusion from the urban, these writers also point to the
ways in which marginalization can be read differently as a zone of
possibility and autonomy in various interstices of the city, even if
in circumscribed ways.6 I do not want to get into the merits of this
approach, but simply want to draw attention to the fact that unless
the complex, dynamic, highly improvising and generative actions
of the urban poor are acknowledged and explored, it is foolish to
come to conclusions about what is going on in a city, or what may
or may not work, either from an insurrectionary perspective or from
a ‘policy-ix’ approach.
The importance of the informal register in reading the city is that
it compels one to take a more provisional approach before one pronounces on either what is going on, or what must be done to improve
the quality of life and freedom in the city. For, as AbdouMaliq
simone reminds us:
Cities are densities of stories, passions, hurts, revenge, aspiration, avoidance, delection, and complicity. As such, residents must be able to
conceive of a space suficiently bounded so as to consolidate disparate
energies and make things of scale happen. but at the same time, they
must conceive of a fractured space suficiently large enough through
which dangerous feelings can dissipate or be steered away. Urban
residents are thus concerned about what kinds of games, instruments,
languages, sight lines, constructions, and objects can be put in play in
order to anticipate new alignments of social initiatives and resources,
and thus capacity.7
Thus, today (if ever) it is simply inconceivable to approach or
move through the city and its futures with irrevocable certainty
about what is going on or what is needed to make the place better.
Conceptual analysis and policy prescription must move with great
care and relexivity.8 does this mean that one cannot perceive and
engage with what are surely blatant deployments of dominating power
over those with little material or political resources? of course not;
4
city futures
it remains perfectly possible and essential to uncover the multiple
and complex circuitries of power in the city, but unfortunately this is
unlikely to render a simple story line of domineering power where it
is clear-cut who the perpetrators and victims are. This takes me on
to another set of coordinates that shape the approach of the book.
Power and complexity
It is crucial to appreciate the constitutive nature of power and complexity in the city. Any analysis of urban conditions and future
prospects must come to terms with the dimensions of complexity
and the ways in which it is sutured by various dynamics of power.
This opens the door, conceptually, to two central ideas of the book:
radical incrementalism and recursive political empowerment. but irst a few
comments of clariication on the intertwined ideas of complexity
and power, and particularly the tension wire that runs between these
dynamics and that animates much in the contemporary city.
Following the work of anthropologist emery roe, one can link
complexity to the reality of contingency which gives rise to incessant
uncertainties and surprises in most development contexts. of course
such uncertainties coexist with structural factors that reproduce
uneven spatial development patterns, but such factors do not explain
or predetermine the fate of development ambitions and interventions.
According to roe, development issues are fundamentally ‘highly
uncertain and complex [because] many, if not most, parties to these
issues, including the experts, are in the grip of many unknowns,
frequent surprise, and little agreement, where few involved know what
really is in their best long-run interests, and where almost everyone is
playing it by ear – and this includes the so-called power brokers.’9 In
more recent times complexity theory as a philosophical stream has also
been deployed to capture the interactions of various physical, social,
economic, political, ecological and cultural systems in urban spaces,
producing an ininite number of unpredictable dynamics. Thus, for
urbanist david byrne, the city must be approached and explored as
a fundamentally emergent and therefore open-ended reality:
Cities are plainly dissipative complex systems with emergent properties and evolutionary history. The identiication of cities as dissipative
systems matters a great deal because it describes the relationship between
introduction
5
urban places, the ‘unnatural’ location of contemporary life within a
‘built’ environment and the natural systems of this planet. Cities are
indeed complex systems but complex systems embedded within both
the complex system of global economic and cultural relations, and the
complex systems which compose the natural world.10
What this mouthful suggests is that there are always so many variables
at play in how cities function, unfold and incessantly become something different; it is important to assume a constitutive complexity,
heightened by the rapidity of change in a globalized world, as central
to the rebus character of cities.
on the other hand it is also fair to say that even if we are to
appreciate the signiicance of complexity, uncertainty, surprise and
therefore open-ended futures, or at least malleable futures, we cannot
deny that power is at the heart of city development, because governance boils down to questions of control over decision-making about
how resources are used in a sea of competing and different interests.
Fortunately our thinking about power has evolved beyond mere
notions of ‘who beneits?’, ‘who is getting exploited?’, ‘how badly
are they exploited?’, to understanding the dynamic, capillary and
decentred nature of circuits of power, which are always unstable and
vulnerable to resistance and transformation.11 In response to roe, and
taking on board the insights about complexity, anthropologist donald
Moore offers a useful multifaceted approach to power:
Instead of simply mapping typologies of power [as roe does], alternative perspectives could emphasize the practices through which power
operates, the symbolic and material effects power produces, and its
performance. In feminist cultural critic Judith butler’s terms: ‘Performativity describes this relation of being implicated in that which one
opposes, this turning of power against itself to reproduce alternative
modalities of power, to establish a kind of political contestation that is
not a “pure” opposition, a “transcendence” of contemporary relations
of power, but a dificult labor of forging a future from resources
inevitably impure.’12
The reason I ind these two lenses – complexity and power – useful
is because they allow one to respond to the existing mainstream
literature and more critical conceptual approaches to cities and begin
to build something akin to a bridge between them. The complexity
6
city futures
lens allows us to address the technical, technocratic and managerialist
discourses and imperatives characteristic of the various literatures in
the domain of urban management. Thus, Chapters 3 and 4 start with
a critical engagement with mainstream policy discourses that seek
to address the challenges of intensifying urbanization with respect
to the managerial and technical complexity of the issues at stake. At
the same time, this book stresses that technical solutions are often
oblivious to power dynamics and by default are in fact profoundly
political in their effects – a danger that is ever present as progressivesounding urban policies continue to produce or perpetuate unjust
and inequitable urban outcomes.
Radical incrementalism
The existential core of urbanism is the desire for radical change to
bring all the good implied in the original utopian association of
‘the city’.13 This radical impulse stands in contrast to the necessary
prudence and constraints of incremental change, which is the only way
of intervening in conditions of profound complexity and entrenched
power dynamics embedded in capitalist modernities.
We know that the current scale of human suffering and violence
that low from the profoundly unequal distribution of resources and
opportunity is fundamentally inhumane and intolerable. Yet we also
know that we cannot wish into existence an overnight revolution
that will make everything all right in the world. At the same time
it seems futile simply to work away at creating the right conditions
for insurrectionary revolutions that will eventually bring to life a
large-scale ‘militant refusal’ by the world’s urban multitudes, as intimated by Mike davis. This leaves one with bringing change into the
world through more discrete avenues: surreptitious, sometimes overt,
and multiple small revolutions that at unanticipated and unexpected
moments galvanize into deeper ruptures that accelerate tectonic shifts
of the underlying logics of domination and what is considered possible. radical incrementalism is a disposition and sensibility that
believes in deliberate actions of social transformation but through a
multiplicity of processes and imaginations, none of which assumes
or asserts a primary signiicance over other struggles. This position
may not resolve the existential struggle of urbanism, but it provides
introduction
7
a means to confront the struggle and perpetually work one’s way
through it, stumbling across what works and what does not. stuart
Hall captured this sensibility with great acuity: ‘are we not all, in
different ways, and through different conceptual spaces … desperately trying to understand what making an ethical political choice
and taking a political position in a necessarily open and contingent
political ield is like, what sort of “politics” it adds up to?’14 This
book takes this sensibility of ethical searching into the domain of
urban change and renewal. Holding this sensibility in mind, I explore
what I mean by recursive political empowerment.
Recursive political empowerment
Transformative change in cities cannot be bestowed by a (benign)
state; nor can it take root simply as a consequence of good policy
plus political will (whatever this overused and underspeciied notion
may mean). Transformative urban change that leads to the enhancement of ‘capabilities’ of the poor and abandoned requires agency
by these very same constituencies, agency ideally inserted into a
multidirectional meshwork of institutions and discourses that frame
the functioning and reproduction of urban systems. However, the
mobilization of these constituencies is not at all a straightforward
matter, because ‘the poor’ and ‘the abandoned’ are never cohesive, or
coherent, or homogenous in any way. Complex and shifting identities and group-based associations, embedded in dynamic cultural
processes, render the urban majorities inherently fragmented and
contested. Furthermore, neighbourhoods and associational circuits
where the urban poor are concentrated are typically stratiied by
deep power differentials between those who control and channel
resources in and out of these areas and those rendered dependent
on such gatekeeping.
engaging with these multilayered realities requires a degree of
awareness and a (personal) decision to participate in structures and
processes that can lead to an improvement in one’s lot. signiicantly,
people’s sense of possibility is closely tied to culturally shaped assessments of opportunities and threats associated with participation.
such calculations, in turn, are intertwined with a sense of being
and self in relation to place and particular communities.15 Thus, a
8
city futures
viable notion of empowerment of the poor requires an appreciation that empowerment is fundamentally an individual process that
deepens with time if individual efforts are consciously embedded in
more collective forms of solidarity and mutual empowerment. The
practice of shack/slum dwellers International (sdI), explored in
Chapters 3 and 6, illustrates this effectively. sdI explicitly seeks to
build autonomy from the state and informal power brokers, whilst
socializing their members into an alternative normative framework,
which in turn becomes the basis of mobilization and legitimacy in
their work.
Framing propositions
on the basis of these conceptual coordinates, the book is premissed
on a number of propositions. First, in dealing with the myriad problems associated with urban development, the central problematic that
must be addressed is urban inequality. This focus allows one to keep
in view the ways in which the framing conditions of the increasingly integrated global economic system places severe limits on the
radicalism of urban interventions and experiments. The economic
vested interests that tie together urban elites across societal and
national cleavages make it almost impossible to propose, let alone
pursue with any modicum of success, alternative economic systems
and initiatives.16 Yet, unless one is able to address and systematically reverse urban inequalities, the prospects of creating more just,
inclusive and vibrant cities are bleak. Therefore, on the back of the
more overtly ‘moral’ turn in global development forums and circuits
(e.g. the Millennium development summit of 2000, which spawned
the MdGs for 2015), there is an opportunity to use the (diversionary)
focus on urban poverty to make linkages to the more fundamental
conditions driving inequality that fall along various faultlines: class,
race, ethnicity, caste, location, religion, ability, gender, sexual preference, age, and so on. This can become a key strategic plank in
progressive coalitions and networks mobilizing to remake cities in
the global south.
second, particular ‘network infrastructures’ are privileged at the
moment to create favourable conditions for economic productivity
and competitiveness. These are infrastructures that facilitate the rapid
introduction
9
movements of goods and services as cities are pushed to reinvent
themselves as magnets for investment in a globalizing world. In the
logic of pursuing these particular infrastructures, the location and
infrastructure needs of the poor take a back seat to what the city
may need to become competitive, and, more recently, ‘creative’. As
stephen Graham and simon Marvin demonstrate in their authoritative overview, network infrastructure pressures tend to further skew
public resource allocations and reinforce the marginalization of the
urban poor at different scales. The point about this trend is that in
the discourses surrounding the need for increased investment in ‘connectivity infrastructures’, spaces open up to demonstrate how most
urban infrastructures are indeed indispensable but also fundamentally
public goods because of their functions in satisfying the full gamut of
human rights. In other words, spaces of counter-discursive strategies
become possible as the right to sustainable livelihood infrastructures
becomes the basis for more critical political campaigns that assert
the general ‘right to the city’ over the sectional interests of urban
elites to live in enclaves and proit indiscriminately off, essentially,
public investments.
Third, the phenomenology and practices of ‘the everyday’ or ‘the
ordinary’ must be the touchstone of radical imaginings and interventions. everyday realities are most compellingly captured in artistic,
literary and anthropological accounts because these registers are most
attuned to the intimate textures of socialities forged in the midst of
very dificult and painful circumstances, as meticulously captured
by Mike davis in Planet of Slums. social interactions and identity
constructive dynamics are not simple or easy narratives. ben okri’s
classic novel Dangerous Love, set in a slum in Lagos during the civil
war of 1970s’ Nigeria, reminds one of the desires and pleasures that
can coexist in even the most abject of conditions; and so do the
philosophical musings of Alphonso Lingis as he rekindles the affective sensualities of desire in the favelas of rio and slums in Manila,
among many other ‘desperate’ places.17 one also gets a glimpse of
the affective effects of popular music in the pulsating scenes of the
ilm City of God, as kids from the slum ind rapturous ecstasy in
the musky, sweaty, sweltering dancehalls of the favela. This is not to
romanticize the dificulties and brutalities of grinding poverty and
10
city futures
persistent terror, but rather to recuperate the constitutive humanity
and, by extension, generative powers of the ordinary.18 For policy
purposes it is worth remembering that literary registers that turn
our gaze to the informal, the interior and the interstitial, away from
the grand swells of exploitation, offer crucial insight and guidance
into how one can deploy an awareness and respect for the ordinary
in seeking to transform the city.
Fourth, urbanists serious about transformative change must be able
to work dextrously with a wide array of policy tools and instruments.
dexterity comes in handy because urban change is massaged at a
multiplicity of pressure points across the city and its institutional
scaffolding. Public resources are typically organized into sectoral
services such as water, sanitation, transportation, roads, electricity,
housing, and so forth. Traditionally these services are underpinned
by vast specialist knowledge rooted in particular modernist disciplines. during the past three decades, it became evident that urban
services need to be planned and deployed in a more coordinated
fashion to improve outcomes and, as a consequence, these disciplinary boundaries have been pushed to become more porous. Policy
frameworks such as Local Agenda 21, local economic development
strategies, livelihoods approaches and the like, generally rest on a
multi-sectoral approach, stressing the interdependencies and linkages
between services.
More recently it has also become clearer that the spatial scale
at which a service is delivered matters a great deal for how one
conceptualizes and operationalizes inter-sectoral coordination and
integration. For example, sanitation services depend on the nature
and scope of water catchment dynamics at regional scales that extend
well beyond the boundaries of a city. At the same time, the delivery
of sanitation-related services at a household scale must be closely
linked to the planning and delivery of a set of services that constitute
a local area, amenable to neighbourhood or quarter development.
What may constitute a progressive set of policies at a regional scale
related to the political economy of water catchments and management may not coincide with what is progressive at a neighbourhood
scale. Consequently, one has always to have one’s strategic wits about
oneself so as to avoid grave strategic errors in promoting what may
introduction
11
seem to be a very principled and morally defensible policy at one
scale, but simultaneously disempowering at another scale of organization and struggle.
Fifth, all forms of urban imagination and intervention are inherently political and therefore prone to critique and mobilization.
However, if various dimensions of urban imaginaries and practices
are not effectively articulated, possibilities of transformation dissipate
into the ether. The irst step in understanding the possibilities of
strategic articulation is to recognize the ways in which the urban polity
is sliced into various overlapping and mutually implicated institutional
sites of engagement and contestation. In any urban polity the following ive generic sites of politics can be identiied: (1) representative
political forums, such as local government councils, the executive
arm of the local authority and various avenues for more direct participation by citizens in structures such as ward committees, district
public assemblies, and so on; (2) neo-corporatist political mechanisms
that comprise representative organizations, typically the government,
the private sector, trade unions and, occasionally, community-based
organizations (i.e. stakeholders) focused on macro-policy deliberation,
coordination and consensus – these structures are less widespread but
growing in importance under the policy imperatives of ‘partnerships’
and ‘strategic planning’; (3) direct action or mobilization by social
movements against state policies or to advance speciic political
demands for response or incorporation into government programmes
and/or in relation to business actions or inluence; (4) the politics
of development practice – grassroots engagement in social, environmental and economic development projects to beneit targeted groups
and/or areas; and (5) symbolic political contestation as expressed
through discursive exchange and projection in the public sphere.19
These are obviously only conceptual distinctions. In gritty real-life
conditions these institutional domains are intimately connected, and
often an action in one institutional arena can trigger responses in
another. I continuously return to this model, which provides the
political thread of the book.
The second step in grasping the possibilities of strategic articulation is to adopt a more nuanced approach to reading urban politics
as expressed in competing discourses, diverse and divergent urban
12
city futures
actors, networks and coalitions, and, most importantly, the governance cultures within which these actors and associated discourses
are embedded. The recent work of Patsy Healey is most instructive in this regard. Her model of the dimensions of governance
suggests that there are three dimensions to local (political) power
dynamics. In the irst instance, speciic episodes (e.g. attracting a
particular high-proile event, or addressing a particular basic service
need like sanitation services, or dealing with street children) tend
to structure and drive political attention. As these episodes unfold,
working their way to a plan, a programme, a project/business plan
with an attendant budget, one can identify the actors involved (and
marginalized), the strategies they deploy in seeking to secure their
interests; all of which may not be that predictable, because informal
agreements and deals may inluence how politicians, or oficials for
that matter, act on a speciic issue. In addition, the way these issues
are framed, talked about and relayed – discursive formations – is
critical to understand what is being included/excluded from debates
and decision-making. What’s more, the issues addressed in an episode
are always dealt with in speciic institutional sites, which are associated with particular ‘rules of the game’ that must be adhered to.
Indeed, if one relects on the ive political domains listed above (as
well as their interfaces), clearly very different kinds of politics get
mobilized and driven in different institutional sites. Crucially, how
issues are debated, dealt with, resolved or not, is informed by the
deeply embedded governance culture of a locality or region. In a
governance culture actors typically know what they can and cannot
say; they know when to play to the media gallery and when not
to; they know how to speak for particular interests without saying
they are speaking for sectional interests; and so on. Again, these
cultures tend to be highly particular in each municipality and also
in different provinces or states depending on the larger balance of
forces and discursive parameters in the public sphere. Clearly, one
cannot explore strategic political articulation in the absence of a
detailed enough map along the vectors intimated in this governance
model (see Table 1.1). 20
only when urban actors are able to position their politics within
a framework mapped across the various dimensions of the urban
introduction
TABLE 1.1
13
dimensions of governance
Level
dimension
speciic episodes
• Actors: roles, strategies and interests
• Arenas: institutional sites
• settings and interactive practices:
communicative repertoires
Governance processes
through which bias is
mobilized
• Networks and coalitions
• stakeholder selection processes
• discourses: framing issues, problems,
solutions, etc.
• Practices: routines and repertoires for acting
• speciication of laws, formal competences and
resource low principles
Governance cultures
• range of accepted modes of governance
• range of embedded cultural values
• Formal and informal structures for policing
discourses and practices
polity, and grounded in a rigorous understanding of the speciicities
of the governance culture they seek to inluence, does it become
possible to foster a politics of radical incrementalism and recursive
empowerment.
There is no single answer to the global challenge of urban justice,
so sorely lacking in every crevice of the world’s cities. There is no
magic bullet that can solve the multiple and interwoven dimensions
of brutalization and exclusion that work so contemptuously in most
cities. All we have is a way of ‘walking’/traversing the city, which
in turn immediately changes shape as one moves through its folds
and shadows, trying to igure out what combination of strategies and
tactics can be summoned to thicken the energies for transformation
and renewal.
Outline of the book
In view of this conceptual underpinning of the book, the logic of
the chapters is the following. First of all I summarize the most
recent urbanization trends data, disaggregated by regions of the
14
city futures
global south. This is important because it alerts readers not only to
the scale and urgency of the issues involved but also to the vastly
different settings that predominate in various parts of the world.
This constitutive heterogeneity is an important reference throughout
the book. second, the book engages with the two most high-proile
mainstream policy responses – the shelter for all and good urban
governance campaigns – championed by international development
bodies such as UN–Habitat, the World bank and Cities Alliance.
In the two chapters devoted to this I highlight the main tenets
of these initiatives and offer a critique of them in order to lay the
basis for an alternative perspective that works with what is valuable
in the mainstream consensus but also seeks to supplant it with a
more robust argument. The central premiss of the critique is that
mainstream urban development policies tend to depoliticize urban
development policy objectives and instruments, which paradoxically
makes it even harder to truly advance the normative ambitions of
the 1996 Habitat Agenda, the wellspring of the two campaigns for
urban reform. Thus the central chapter offers a theoretical exposition of the kind of politics – that is, radical democratic – that is
required as a foundation for the emergence of sustainable lives and
livelihoods. Chapter 5 offers a leshed out argument of the ive
domains of political practice mentioned before, but it also serves as
a foundation for the second half of the book, which is in a more
propositional register.
In Chapter 6, the book takes a brief detour to foreground insurgent
practices and dynamics in the city. Given the focus of this chapter,
and its destabilizing function in relation to the cleaner rational form
of argument in chapters 5, 7 and 8, it purposefully takes on a different tone. The purpose is to foreground the indeterminacy of
everyday life – usually missed – of particularly the poor, as expressed
through their stubborn appropriation of the city for the purposes
of survival and reproducing, often highly precarious, livelihoods.
Given the inordinate dificulty academic and policy discourses have
with capturing the rich phenomenology of the everyday, I draw on
examples from literature and cultural practices, to illuminate the lived
realities of the city. Without suggesting any possibility of a linear
instrumental appropriation of these dynamics for transformative
introduction
15
urban development policy, the purpose of this chapter is to remind
us of the undercurrent of ordinary inventiveness that necessarily
shadows the efforts of the urban poor to keep limb, life and the
aspirations of a better future alive.
Chapter 7 takes on a more conventional procedural logic to specify
more plainly the central elements of my reading of an alternative
urban development framework. A conceptual model is presented
which draws attention to the relationship between radical democracy
and levers for systemic change towards more sustainable and resilient
urban patterns. The chapter offers a set of concrete tools for networks and coalitions of urban radicals to work at the border zones
of mainstream policy discourses but decidedly against the grain to
show up limits and contradictions, with an eye on specifying more
effective alternatives amenable to being scaled up in the actions of
local states, civil society organizations and sections of the business
community that are serious about contributing to more inclusive,
sustainable and equitable city futures. The inal chapter attempts to
get even more practical and provides a policy framework to address
urban poverty in a multidimensional framework, and cognizant of
the larger, globalized political economic forces that drive rising levels
of inter- and intra-regional inequality. The chapter concludes with a
hypothetical exploration of how the various elements of the book’s
overall argument come together in the idea of ‘tipping points’: that is,
unique, city-speciic interventions that are rich in cultural resonance
and effectively address the systemic drivers of a profoundly stubborn
problem within a particular city. It is my belief that if progressives
adopt a more proactive, forward-looking and creative approach to the
rich potentiality of our cities across the global south, the prospect
of city futures where the right to the city is the norm stops simply
being a dream.
2
Urbanization trends
and implications
This chapter seeks to provide a particular perspective on the complex,
uneven and often confusing dynamics of urbanization as it plays out
in different parts of the south. A plethora of books and magazine
articles on the crossing of a ‘majority urban world’ threshold in 2008
have made their appearance in the recent period, which reduces the
need for detailed statistical presentation of the scale, pace, direction
and differential impact of urbanization across the world. Although I
draw on some of the urbanization trends data of the United Nations,
I mainly aim to provide a reading, an interpretation, of what is
unfolding to lay the basis for the discussions that follow in the rest
of the book. The aim is not to provide a comprehensive review of
urbanization statistics; david satterthwaite, whose work is seminal
in this regard, does this effectively.1 The core argument is that we
are witnessing the second wave of urbanization – in contrast to the
irst wave that took place in europe and North America between
1750 and 1950. The current wave is taking place within a particular
geopolitical and economic moment in the history of humanity, which
presents daunting pressures and decisions for urban citizens and
especially activists, leaders and managers as they igure out how to
cope and lourish.
urbanization trends
17
The most useful label (albeit one open to a wide range of interpretations) for the contemporary political economy of territorial development (at various interlinked scales – local, sub-national, national,
regional, global) is of course globalization. As a dense constellation of
various economic, political, social, cultural and ecological processes,
globalization drives particular economic and spatial dynamics in cities
and towns across the world. on the economic side, globalization
imperatives for market access and asymmetrical integration hold
serious implications for the territorial infrastructural imperatives of
urban development, especially as the bulk of economic value-added
comes from service sectors that are largely knowledge-intensive. Thus,
in most cities and towns of the south, public decision-makers are
forced to address both economic and social infrastructural imperatives from a very limited and constrained iscus and invariably ind
themselves in the invidious position of having to make trade-offs,
or at best sequencing decisions, about where public resources will be
invested. It is this choice, or trade-off, that I want to delve into in
this chapter by drawing on the work of stephen Graham and simon
Marvin, who trace and theorize the rising importance of ‘splintered
network infrastructures’. 2
Globalization also seems to induce particular spatial dynamics in
the evolution and management of urban territories and systems. In
particular, greater spatial segregation and often exclusion of the urban
poor are in evidence as cities jostle to become ‘world class’ and ‘globally connected’, at least for the enclaves of professional knowledge
workers who reside there. The starkest expression of urban division
and exclusion is the dramatic rise in slums in the global south over
the past three decades. It is also this feature of the contemporary
condition that is receiving the most policy attention. I therefore
spend some time going over this literature in order to tease out
where we stand in the global policy debate about the relationship (or
trade-offs) between investing and managing economic versus social
reproduction and public goods infrastructures. Through this review
it becomes apparent that most local governments in the south are
caught in a terrible bind of contradictory policy imperatives, which
create fertile ground for powerful vested interests in cities, which
are either tied into globalized circuits of capital or beneit from the
18
city futures
absence of regulation and equity within zones of informal exclusion,
to become even more entrenched.
Dimensions of the second wave of urbanization
In the State of the World Population 2007, the population division of the
United Nations introduces a useful lens with which to think about the
signiicance and scale of contemporary urbanization.3 It is worthwhile
quoting the report at some length because of its foundational value
for the discussion that follows:
The irst urbanization wave took place in North America and europe
over two centuries, from 1750 to 1950: an increase from 10 to 52 per
cent urban and from 15 to 423 million urbanites. In the second wave
of urbanization, in the less developed regions, the number of urbanites
will go from 309 million in 1950 to 3.9 billion in 2030. In those 80
years, these countries will change from 18 per cent to some 56 per
cent urban.
At the beginning of the 20th century, the now developed regions
had more than twice as many urban dwellers as the less developed (150
million to 70 million). despite much lower levels of urbanization, the
developing countries now have 2.6 times as many urban dwellers as
the developed regions (2.3 billion to 0.9 billion). This gap will widen
quickly in the next few decades.
At the world level, the 20th century saw an increase from 220 million
urbanites in 1900 to 2.84 billion in 2000. The present century will match
this absolute increase in about four decades. developing regions as a
whole will account for 93 per cent of this growth, Asia and Africa for
over 80 per cent.
between 2000 and 2030, Asia’s urban population will increase from
1.36 billion to 2.64 billion, Africa’s from 294 million to 742 million,
and that of Latin America and the Caribbean from 394 million to 609
million. As a result of these shifts, developing countries will have 80
per cent of the world’s urban population in 2030. by then, Africa and
Asia will include almost seven out of every ten urban inhabitants in
the world.4
To achieve a perspective on the magnitude of these shifts, it is
revealing to historicize the declining time needed for one billion
urban dwellers to be added to the total (Table 2.1).
The vast bulk of the new urban dwellers that swelled the numbers
from the 1960s onwards have been in developing countries. Table 2.2
19
urbanization trends
The declining time needed for 1 billion additional
urban dwellers5
TABLE 2.1
World’s total urban population
Time taken
0–1 billion
10,000 years (c. 8000 bce–1960)
1–2 billion
25 years (1960–1985)
2–3 billion
18 years (1985–2003)
3–4 billion
15 years (2003–2018)
Urban population by region, 1950–2000, with
projection for 2010 (million inhabitants) 6
TABLE 2.2
1950
1970
1990
2000
2010
33
85
203
294
408
234
485
1,011
1,363
1,755
70
163
315
394
474
europe
277
411
509
522
529
North America
110
171
214
249
284
region
Africa
Asia
Latin America and Caribbean
oceania
World
8
14
19
22
25
732
1,329
2,271
2,845
3,475
provides a more precise breakdown of these shifts and captures how
the growth rates in Africa and Asia in particular are very signiicant
and will remain so, according to United Nations projections, until
2030.
The big leaps in urban populations to which it is worth drawing
attention occur from the 1970s onwards. This is highly signiicant
because the world economy also deepened the long-term process of
profound restructuring that today we refer to in shorthand as globalization. As will become clear in a moment, globalization processes
were underpinned by profound technological shifts – computerization
20
city futures
– that have far-reaching territorial implications. Nation-states become
less central to economic coordination and regulation and both supranational and sub-national scales of economic activity and regulation rise in importance. Furthermore, economic activity, especially
high value-added activities, becomes more and more dependent
on information and knowledge management – that is, intangible
services that do not require an agricultural or manufacturing industrial base. Moreover, agricultural and manufacturing activities that
succeed in making their production and distribution processes more
mechanized, computerized and knowledge-driven (e.g. informed by
specialized information about market segments to ensure higher
prices for tailored products) survive in the new economic context.
Those countries and localities that do not have access to investment
capital, appropriately skilled workers, good communications and
transportation links to worldwide markets face profound economic
marginalization and even obsolescence.
Longitudinal data demonstrate that agricultural activity (in contradistinction to manufacturing and services) has been contributing less
than 30 per cent of GdP in developing countries since 1965 and
plummeted further to 11 per cent by 2005.7 This is highly signiicant
given that the majority of populations in Asia and Africa will be in
rural areas until at least 2025.8 In other words, economic opportunities
are only likely to grow in urban areas, except where rural economies
are able to reposition into service activities that accompany tourism
and high-value agroprocessing. This trend has existed for some time,
which explains much of the dramatic migration of rural populations
to urban areas – jobs and the hope of better future prospects are
largely only available in urban areas.
The lipside of this picture is that manufacturing and services
now contribute 90 per cent of GdP in most developing countries.
even in sub-saharan Africa, which is only 39 per cent urbanized, 89
per cent of GdP comes from industry and services.9 However, the
economic nature of industry/manufacturing and services has dramatically changed over the past three decades. In the case of manufacturing, the rise of ever more sophisticated machines that could
exploit technological breakthroughs in computer chip miniatur ization,
whilst exponentially increasing processing capacity and dropping in
urbanization trends
21
cost, meant that the industrial production process could be radically
transformed to move away from standardized mass products to a
highly variegated output that could tailor-make products for various
niche markets; a process that is referred to as lexible specialization,
characteristic of the post-Fordist production system. In this context,
those manufacturing irms that were able to capture wealthy consumers by producing design-intensive niche products succeeded. What
this shift involved, of course, was a devastating impact on labour.
on the one hand, fewer workers were needed, resulting in massive
lay-offs of semi-skilled and unskilled workers. Also, those who could
retain their jobs had to become a lot more skilled and expert in
running more complex, adaptive and rapidly changing production
systems. As a result, a new international division of labour (NIdL)
began to emerge in the 1970s.
The NIdL refer to a spatial division of labour at the global scale.…
Under the oIdL [old international division of labour], the global
periphery was seen and theorized as the provider of many goods and
raw materials for processing in ‘core’ countries in Western europe
and North America. In exchange for these materials, the periphery
received inished goods manufactured in the core. The economic
activities in the global core and periphery are changing under the
development of the new international division of labour. A process of
vertical uncoupling, subdivision, and/or subcontracting of production
results in the periphery developing low-skilled, standardized operations
such as manufacturing assembly or routine data entry, while the global
core retains high skilled knowledge- or technology-intensive industry
and occupations. Through deskilling of labour, and the functional and
physical separation of various tasks in the corporation, this process
creates ‘roles’ for places in the world economy.10
The NIdL is usefully illustrated by Nike’s worldwide production system in which the high value-added activities remain in the
North and low-wage activities are undertaken in the south. but
even in the south there is further differentiation between countries
that handle subcontracting relations with factories where the actual
assembly takes place. In the case of Nike, design aspects that go
into the conceptualization of the shoe take place in the UsA; the
fostering of markets through extremely expensive advertising campaigns premissed on customer-based research remains in the UsA;
22
city futures
the management of moving of the goods to the point of assembly
and the inished products to the retail outlets in the North and
middle income countries, are handled by countries such as Taiwan
and korea. The actual assembly takes place in two categories of
countries: high-end products that require higher levels of skill in
Taiwan and korea; low-end product assembly in China, Indonesia
and Vietnam.11 In this geographically stretched production and retail
system, all of the high-value activities – essentially services – remain
in the North, and routine manufacturing assembly functions are
performed in developing countries where the cities structure their
infrastructure investments and regulatory systems to capture this
kind of economic activity.
It is vital to appreciate that only a section of developing countries
were able to build their economies on the basis of these structural
economic shifts, namely the newly industrialized countries (NICs),
also known as the Asian Tigers. The skewed pattern is relected in
various indicators, but let us simply focus on shares of world exports
given the importance of vigorous trade relations in maintaining an
economic foothold. In 1980, east Asia and the Paciic accounted for
about a 3 per cent share of world exports and this had increased to
9 per cent by 2002. However, over this period sub-saharan Africa
declined from a 3 per cent share of world trade (the level of east
Asia) to 0.7 per cent!12 Territorially, what happened in the developing
countries that did participate in the NIdL is striking. Most of the
NICs introduced policies to establish enclaves of production – export
processing zones – where the conventional regimes of taxation and
labour regulation were suspended. Furthermore, high-quality transportation, logistics and other infrastructures would be provided tax
free (at least for the initial years) in order to lure investors.13 These
initiatives became the anchor points for an export-oriented industrialization model that underpins the dramatic growth of southeast
Asian countries since the late 1960s. The developmental model of
the NICs was to subsidize the production activities of transnational
corporations (TNCs), whilst investing heavily in education so that
they could steadily monopolize skilled manufacturing off a low
wage base. In this way, as the ICT revolution gained pace, they
became more and more pivotal to globalized production chains. In
urbanization trends
23
urban management terms what this meant was major investments
in economic infrastructure to secure and retain the manufacturing
activities of TNCs. In this division of economic activity, the North
retained coordination, product design and marketing functions, which
in turn became more and more proitable because competitiveness
depends increasingly on data and knowledge management functions.
This brings me to a brief discussion on the rise of service sectors
over the last three decades as the world absorbed a further 2 billion
urban dwellers.
by the late 1990s, the shares of agriculture, manufactures/industry,
and services were 6 per cent, 36 per cent and 58 per cent, respectively.14 Typical economic activities that make up services are: inancial
services, insurance, real estate, legal services, media and communications (especially advertising), tourism, transportation, research and
development or knowledge production, and so forth. In an increasingly globalized production system, the coordination functions of
TNCs are very important because they ensure optimal eficiency
in terms of tailoring products to ever changing specialized demand
from ever growing market segments. Thus, the greatest economic
value accrues to highly skilled, specialized activities that make up the
service industry. saskia sassen has been tracing the spatial/territorial
signiicance of particular global cities that attract and concentrate
the most lucrative and specialist economic services that the globespanning web of TNCs have relied on since the early 1990s. In her
work she demonstrates that these various knowledge-driven services,
paradoxically in a wired world, depend on close proximity and territorial concentration to perform optimally.15 In other words, there are
very particular locational factors that inform the decisions of these
companies. In her reading, tellingly, there are no primary global cities
in the south. However, what is striking is that many cities in the
south and North (bypassed by the high-end services circuit) aspire
to become global cities and will do just about anything to achieve
that status. In other words, there is profound status and prestige
associated with being a hub for high-end knowledge-intensive irms,
especially in the inancial services sector.
over the past forty years, when 2 billion urban dwellers were
added to the global total, the economic function of urban territories
24
city futures
has undergone a profound change. This has made it possible for some
places to achieve unimaginable levels of prosperity while the majority
of urban settlements have become profoundly economically marginalized. Furthermore, even those places that have beneited have become
increasingly unequal and now manifest very profound internal barriers
between the economically active and the excluded.16 Those cities and
towns that aspire to be ‘globally competitive’ are compelled to accept
that economic success requires major sacriices and interminable
inequality. This is a very large claim; to substantiate it, I want to draw
on the pathbreaking work of stephen Graham and simon Marvin,
who unpack the infrastructural underpinnings of the emergent global
economic system, anchored as it is in urban territories.
Splintered network infrastructures
The argument developed by Graham and Marvin starts off with the
observation that towards the tail end of the irst wave of urbanization
in the early twentieth century, european and North American cities
(and to a signiicant degree Japanese cities as well) sought to roll out
vast technological infrastructure to ensure access to water, power
and communications, as well as urban highways. From the 1930s
onwards, emphasis fell on the receding of ‘technological networks
of ducts, pipes, conduits and wires’ below the ground and out of
sight, making modern cities appear to hum along seamlessly. ‘Power,
water and transport services became normalized within broader
constructions of urban consumptions and culture. Increasingly, they
were also delivered within public or private monopolies constructed
at urban, regional or national scales as part of the wider elaboration of national welfare states.’17 Critically, there was an underlying
assumption that basic water, power, sewerage and communications
services were public goods or at least quasi-public goods. In other
words, they were planned, inanced and managed in a way that
envisaged universal coverage irrespective of the economic position
of the population. And, of course, after the Great depression of
1929, and thereafter the post-World War II era, there was certainly
no shortage of poor people in these cities. Underlying this trend was
a deeply held ‘high-modern ideal of a unitary, orderly city, integrated
by networked infrastructure.’18
urbanization trends
25
This ideal was never fully realized in Northern cities, and was only
seen to apply to the settler segments of colonial cities and towns in
the developing or colonized world. In fact, a central plank of the
regime of governmentality in many colonies was precisely to use
infrastructure as the marker of inclusion and exclusion; the emblem
of colonizer/civilized and colonized/savage. It is important to keep
this in mind when one relects on the dramatic numbers of urbanites
in today’s cities who have either limited or no access to basic services.
Many of these cities were never intended or designed to service their
populations. Graham and Marvin suggest that the Western ideal of
universal service coverage has come under severe attack during the
past three decades – again, at the same moment that the second wave
of urbanization picked up pace. Graham explains:
standardized public and private infrastructure monopolies are receding
as hegemonic forms of infrastructure management. We are starting to
witness the uneven overlaying and retroitting of new, high performance urban infrastructures onto the apparently immanent, universal
and (usually) public monopoly network laid down between the 1930s
and 1960s. In a parallel process, the diverse political and regulatory
regimes that supported the ‘roll-out’ of power, transport, communications and water networks towards the rhetorical goal of standardized
ubiquity are, in many cities and states, being ‘unbundled’ or even
‘splintered’, as a result of widespread movements towards privatization
and liberalization.… What this amounts to … is the uneven emergence
of an array of what I call ‘premium network spaces’: new or retroitted
transport, telecommunications, power and water infrastructures that
are customized precisely to the needs of the powerful users and spaces,
whilst bypassing less powerful users and spaces.19
This radical and highly inequitable urban management agenda can be
traced empirically through four interrelated processes: ‘the “unbundling” of urban infrastructure provision; the erosion of comprehensive urban planning and the construction of new consumption spaces;
the emergence of infrastructural consumerism; and the widespread
shift towards extended and auto-mobilized cityscapes.’20
In the irst instance, the unbundling of urban infrastructure provision takes place through privatization and/or corporatization. The
latter refers to institutional models where the state retains ownership
of an entity but adopts private-sector management principles and
26
city futures
governance structures to improve its eficiency. Typically, corporatization includes a move away from cross-subsidization of services
to a model where users pay or they are not allowed to access the
service. The country-by-country experiences of these processes are
highly unique and complex, well beyond the scope of my discussion.
The point I want to make here is that with the movement towards
the privatization or corporatization of infrastructure for services,
the potential for cross-subsidization to afford a better quality of life
for the urban poor diminishes. In fact, what happens is that user
markets get inely segmented and those who want optimal levels of
service insist that they get access to a level of quality that is commensurate with what they pay. Given their political clout as a class,
those who can afford optimal levels of service tend to get what
they want. Also, in many developing countries, as explained before,
where governments are desperate to attract foreign investors, they
often subsidize and/or prioritize the infrastructure needs of TNC
investors over local populations. As a consequence, infrastructures
are embedded in ways that connect the wealthy parts of cities to the
global economy, particularly with respect to communications and
transportation, often bypassing large swathes of the city inhabited
by the poor.
The second aspect is the erosion of comprehensive urban planning
in favour of project-based infrastructure investment. If one thinks
about this for a moment, it is a completely expected consequence
of the irst trend. As the private sector enters the infrastructure
market, their primary concerns will be proit maximization and the
minimization of risk. These imperatives compel them to insulate their
infrastructure projects from economic leakage by cross-subsidizing
those who cannot afford to pay for the service. Furthermore, they will
see a large population without the means to pay as a risk to achieving
their projected return on investment. As a result, their entry into the
market will often be contingent on contractual agreements with the
state that they can ring-fence their project from larger problems in
the city. The predictable consequence of this is that the urban territory is further balkanized between those areas where infrastructure
is proitably provided and those areas without. 21 Typically, in these
cases, the state also does not have the resources or revenue streams
urbanization trends
27
to extend infrastructure networks to the poor because it has lost the
advantage of economies of scale.
The third aspect, the construction of infrastructural consumerism,
refers to the growing tendency to tailor infrastructure provision
to a highly differentiated segmentation of the population. retailers have for some time, of course, used consumer segmentation
and geodemographic targeting techniques to construct and expand
brands and ensure sustained market share. In the post-Fordist era of
ine-grained market segmentation, linked to ever more inely tuned
product design and marketing (so that all consumers can feel like
very special individuals), the same rationale has spilled over into
the domain of infrastructure provision. To illustrate the power and
signiicance of market segmentation, I reproduce a segmentation of
Cape Town (my place of residence), into nine categories that coincide with income, settlement characteristics and percentage of total
suburbs and households (Table 2.3). The starkest and most recognizable example of infrastructure consumerism is the dramatic rise of
gated suburbs across the urban world. In these gated settlements,
developers offer high-income earners an exclusive existence with
access to very high quality communications infrastructure, state-ofthe-art security, often with private security irms, dedicated cleaning
services, and so forth. These infrastructural designs are tailor-made
to the needs and aspirations of the segments of these cities that can
afford to pay a premium for services, but it also means that this
income becomes lost to a larger, publicly controlled investment and
development strategy to address the full gamut of need across the
urban territory. Infrastructural enclaves such as gated communities
invariably sediment the fragmentation of urban infrastructure and
space as well as reducing the capacity of the state to fulil its public
good role to ensure equitable access and patterns of development.
The fourth dimension of splintering urbanism is the rise of the
polynucleated urban region and decentralization. A disturbing trend in
most medium, large and mega cities across the south is to emulate the
American urban form of long, stretched-out, sprawl-like developments
that enable their middle classes in particular to live a consumptiondriven, car-based and insular existence. In the North and some of the
early urbanizing areas of the south, the trend towards car-oriented
28
city futures
TABLE 2.3
Geodemographic segmentation of Cape Town 22
Cluster group
key characteristics
silver spoons
elite, largest consumers, getting
richer
14
7
Upper middle class
established, mature,
conservative, professionals, gated
19
9
Middle suburbia
Tight budgets, mid-level jobs,
bargain hunters, big spending on
educating children
20
10
Community nests
Mixed, Afro-cosmo, shifting,
small spaces, stylish, café
culture, dense
1.5
2
Labour pool
High-density family
neighbourhoods, stable jobs,
secondary education, struggling
9.5
6
New bonds
New sA families, youngish,
targets of the developers
13.5
13
Township living
old places, few jobs, youth
cultures, soul of the new south
Africa, buzzy, vulnerable
4.5
11
Towering density
Teetering, high hopes, few
options, the educated leave
as soon as possible, limited
reinvestment
dire straits
old places, overcrowded,
services collapsing, high
unemployment, decaying
below the breadline shack settlements, desperation,
insecurity
% of
% of
suburbs households
13
22
2
3
3
15
sprawl has been reinforced by the costs associated with retroitting
old infrastructure in urban cores installed in the irst half of the
twentieth century. This trend, in turn, has combined with engineered
consumer demand for greenield sites that can guarantee high-modern,
clean-slate property developments unencumbered by the fabric of the
urbanization trends
29
historical built environment. In these spaces the ideal of insulated
modern lifestyles is ostensibly guaranteed, a desire that feeds off
the rising levels of urban fear as violence and insecurity escalate in
the context of profound social inequalities. The underlying thread
of these two tendencies is the mass diffusion of car cultures – the
quintessential emblem of modernity in many developing countries. 23
The car culture that produces kilometres of asphalt and concrete
that carries the middle-classes to their secure suburban enclaves are
of course part of ‘a whole system of supportive infrastructure, from
highways to service stations, to drive-through fast food centres and
out-of-town malls and auto-access leisure and retail complexes.’24
It is important to appreciate that the dramatic shift in approach
to urban infrastructure, whether economic, social or public, was
underpinned by a profound ideological argument that states, whether
in the North or south, were the problem, not the solution. This
neoliberal logic suggested that key to sustained prosperity was to
create an ‘enabling’ or liberating environment for markets to function
optimally because the only durable solution to the crises of employment and sustained economic growth was unfettered competition.
This neoliberal consensus arose from neoclassical economic models
and very quickly found expression in institutional theory, which
informed how states had to be reorganized to become more lean,
strategic and enabling, as opposed to being geared towards a mass
delivery of public services. The problem for many developing countries in the 1980s was that the inluential bilateral agencies dealing
with development support all subscribed to this ideological outlook
and tied their inancial and technical support to compulsory reforms
to bring market forces into play in national and especially urban
management functions. 25
Again, it is important to stress that these processes were unfolding
at the precise time that agricultural activities went through the loor
and large numbers of people were forced to seek a viable life and
prospects in towns and cities. As a consequence, cities with highly
inadequate urban infrastructure adopted an approach in which the
state abdicated from investing in urban infrastructure in favour of
policies that would attract private-sector actors into the infrastructure
markets. of course, as explained earlier, private-sector irms were in
city futures
60
55
54
Mexico
Peru
51
brazil
51
Latin America
78
Thailand
83
65
Asia
71
south Africa
benin
Africa
kenya
72
Indonesia
93
72
India
30
FIGURE 2.1 scale of informal economic activity in developing
countries: informal employment as % of non-agricultural employment,
selected regions and countries, various years (1995–2000)26
the business of making a proit and would only cherry-pick low-risk
and high-return projects tied to proitable segments of the economy
while refusing to enter into delivery arrangements if the users could
not pay market-based consumption fees. This absurd scenario played
out somewhat differently in many cities where (local) politicians were
so deeply embedded in economic activity that they simply could not
be bothered to igure out what needed to be done to address the
vast and ever growing need for urban services by many people too
poor to pay. Against this backdrop, it is not surprising to learn that
in most urban areas in sub-saharan Africa informal settlements and
economic activities, largely unmoored from urban infrastructure,
unless clandestinely tapped into it, are the norm not the exception.
The African situation may be extreme but it is certainly not isolated.
Informality is increasingly the most prominent form of urban growth
in very many parts of the south (see Figure 2.1).
The rise and rise of slums
slums are a further expression of structural informality. According
to the United Nations, there are four indicators that express the
physical condition of slums: ‘lack of water, lack of sanitation, overcrowding and non-durable housing structures. These indicators, also
known as shelter deprivations, focus attention on the circumstances
urbanization trends
31
regional distribution of the world’s urban
slum dwellers (2001) 27
TABLE 2.4
region
Total urban
population (1,000s)
slum dwellers as
% of region total
231,052
71.9
1,211,540
43.2
Latin America and Caribbean
399,385
31.9
Middle east and North Africa
145,624
29.5
Transition economies
259,091
9.6
Advanced economies
676,492
5.8
World
2,921,184
31.6
developing countries
2,021,665
43.0
179,239
78.2
sub-saharan Africa
Asia Paciic
Least developed countries
surrounding slum life, depicting deiciencies and casting poverty as
an attribute of the environment in which slum dwellers live. The
ifth indicator – security of tenure – has to do with legality, which
is not as easy to measure or monitor, as the status of slum dwellers often depends on de facto or de jure rights, or lack of them.’28
based on this deinition, the UN produces a number of informative
statistical overviews.
It is anticipated that all future growth of slum populations will
occur exclusively in the developing world. Figure 2.2 captures the
projections of slum growth up to 2020, which demonstrates clearly
that the vast bulk of new slum dwellers will be in Africa and Asia.
However it is important to bear in mind the substantial number of
existing slum dwellers in other parts of the developing world whose
living conditions are unlikely change in the near future, if current
conditions remain similar into the future.
based on these projections, senior UN–Habitat oficials
conclude:
Poverty and inequality will characterize many developing-world cities,
and urban growth will become virtually synonymous with slum formation in some regions. Asia is already home to more than half of the
32
city futures
1.6
World
1.4
1.2
developing regions
1.0
0.8
0.6
0.4
0.2
0
developed regions
1990
FIGURE 2.2
2001
2010
2020
slum population projections, 1990–2020 (millions) 29
global slum population (581 million), followed by sub-saharan Africa
(199 million), which has both the highest annual urban growth rate (4.58
per cent) and the highest slum growth rate (4.53 per cent), and Latin
America and the Caribbean (134 million).30
This is a startling acknowledgement if one considers the Habitat
Agenda declaration of 1996 made at the Habitat II global conference
in Istanbul. That event emerged with a sense of conidence and
optimism that the world understood what was required to achieve
a turnaround in the shelter, governance and poverty crises that
characterized most cities in the south. I will return to these policy
agendas in the next two chapters, so will refrain from unpacking
and relecting on them here.
What is important to draw attention to in this context-setting discussion is the qualitative aspects of everyday life in slums, especially
since the emerging consensus seems to be that they will become a
major part of our urban future and may even be the dominant form
of urbanism in much of the south, especially Africa. The irst point
to make is that slums are in no way homogenous or essentially the
‘same’ in different cities and towns and across national and regional
categories. There is a real danger that the material deprivation that
accompanies slum life becomes the sole lens through which these
communities, households and urban actors are understood and
engaged. Moreover, whilst policymakers and academics struggle to
urbanization trends
33
come to terms with the pervasive nature of slums, slum dwellers of
course get on with the business of living, loving, exploring, working,
no matter how dangerous, precarious or erratic it may be. Noble
interventions by outside agencies to ‘improve’ the living conditions of
slum dwellers or enhance their ‘livelihoods’ can easily be initiated at
a complete disjuncture from how people hold their (precarious) lives
and aspirations together, and potentially, inadvertently, undermine
very delicate survival practices.
second, slum areas are not ungoverned, even though the formal
state institutions may have little administrative oversight or engagement with these communities because of the absence of household
services, effective policing, health care and the like. ethnographic and
literary research is unambiguous about the multiple layers of governing that ill or rework the vacuum the state creates by its absence or
obsolescence. The most obvious, and in some cases visible, presence
is that of criminal gangs that use the illegibility and density of slums
to anchor their production and smuggling activities. Insights into
these dynamics in kingston, rio de Janeiro and Cape Town show
a very similar symbiotic relationship between increasingly transnational criminal syndicates and local populations that provide the
foot soldiers, surveillance and often physical protection for these
gangs.31 The gangs in turn invest in the social and other services
of the community to prevent outright destitution but never to the
extent that they actually solve anything for the long term. Within this
patronage relationship there is also almost always a palpable current
of fear, as these gangs use in part a regime of violence and intimation to entrench their control and sovereignty. strikingly, alongside
drug- or weapons-smuggling gangs, most slums are also sutured by
a variety of religious organizations that offer respite and rationality
to make sense of the drudgery of always hustling to keep destitution
at bay. In addition to these two dominant forms of social structure
there are also a myriad other, often more luid and provisional, social
structures that provide an entry into various networks of engagement,
opportunity, pleasure, risk, exploration and mobility.32 These social
ields are composed of highly improvised (popular) cultural, ethnic,
economic, trading, political and self-help groups. This social–cultural
morphology suggests dense, sometimes conlictual, and always highly
34
city futures
TABLE 2.5
Cost of water in Accra, Ghana (2006)33
Water source
Cost
($/100 l.)
Users
sachet (500 ml.)
8.01
General public, street drinking
sachets (30-pack)
4.45
General public, household drinking
bucket from kiosk
1.87
Households relying on shared
standpipe
Community shower
1.33
Informal settlement dwellers,
bathing only
Vendor
0.27
Mixed-income neighbourhood
without access to piped water
Water pipe
0.05
Households with pipe connection
precarious settings within which urban development policy must
intervene. It is very hard to ind a full appreciation of these counteror para-governmentalities at work in most policy models that emanate
from mainstream urban development agencies. I shall explore this
theme more closely in the next chapter.
Finally, from a normative, rights-based point of view, it is imperative to underscore that even though it is a highly complex and
tricky affair to intervene in slums without making the situation
even worse because of uni-dimensional assumptions about what is
really going on, it is also clear that interventions are required. The
UN–Habitat is absolutely correct to draw attention to the fact that
‘slums, and the informal economic of which they are a part, are
the physical manifestation of urban poverty.’34 Furthermore, the
projected continuation of ‘inequality in access to services, housing,
land, education, health care and employment opportunities within
cities [has] socio-economic, environmental and political repercussions,
including rising violence, urban unrest, environmental degradation
and underemployment.’35 one simple illustration reinforces the point
forcefully: the urban poor of Accra who reside in slums without
access to piped water pay exponentially more for access compared
to other urban residents in the city, as graphically illustrated in Table
2.5. It is therefore essential to use the political and policy opening in
urbanization trends
35
mainstream debates around the ‘crisis’ of unprecedented slum growth
to foster a more ambitious, radical and transformative politics, as
suggested in later chapters. However, this will only be possible if one
can shift the underlying assumptions of mainstream policy models
about the kind of politics and power relations that will indeed push
forward systemic change.
What is to be done about urbanization?
The urbanization of poverty constitutes one of the major challenges
of our times. Its underlying causes are well known – rapid and
unprecedented urban growth, inequitable distribution of wealth,
and the inability of the formal economy to create suficient jobs,
combined with the failure of public policy to secure people’s access
to basic needs.36
This is a profound analysis from the Head of UN–Habitat of what
perpetuates the conditions outlined in this chapter; in crude terms, it
is 70 per cent economics and 30 per cent state failure. This coincides
very closely with the argument I have been presenting here: locating
the responsibility of municipalities to deal with accelerated rates of
urbanization at the same moment as the global economy undergoes
a series of deep structural changes, which drives particular territorial imperatives. For example, the rise of more design-intensive
and export-oriented manufacturing activity drives a demand for
high-quality transport, communications and freight logistics infrastructures. similarly, those countries in the south that can be classiied as middle-income countries seek to compete with each other and
Northern countries to attract ever larger slices of the rapidly growing
and highly lucrative inance-related services sectors as well as tourism.
In a world of ierce competition, governments see it as imperative to
prioritize economic infrastructures, whether it be for export-oriented
manufacturing or growing service sectors, above the social reproductive ones that especially poor households require to improve their
living conditions. What these trends point to is the profundity of the
policy, governance and, one could even argue, legitimacy dilemmas
urban development decision-makers and activists face in the global
south. My central contention is that the policy frameworks and tools
promoted by mainstream development agencies such as UN–Habitat
36
city futures
and the Cities Alliance do not help local actors to make decisions
in a way that advances transformative urban change. They certainly
do not empower them to deal decisively with economic inequality
and structural unemployment – deined as the key underpinning of
urban poverty, by the leader of UN–Habitat.
As the following two chapters will demonstrate at greater length,
the mainstream urban development approach operates on the following assumptions about how to respond effectively to the urbanization of poverty, which is the core story implicit in the existing and
forecasted growth of slums:
• As a start, recognize the need for explicit engagement with the
phenomenon of urbanization since many states, especially in subsaharan Africa, still operate in a default mode that believes the
answer to uneven and underdevelopment is rural development.
• once the political awareness is in place, swiftly move to an effective multi-level governmental response, which includes a national
policy framework on urbanization and within a decentralized
model, programmatic and inancial support for municipalities to
respond to the various dimensions of urbanization: appropriate
land management policies, tenure security, integrated policies (as
opposed to sectoral responses) to ensure affordable access to basic
services, and democratic participation.
• reform governance institutions to enable better coordination and
coherence between the state, business, labour organizations and
civil society organizations. Ideally, the coherence will come from
a shared vision for the city or town about where it wants to position itself in the medium to long term and translate into concrete
programmes that will see them, in unison, marching towards that
vision.
• Finally, create a variety of partnerships between the state and business, or the state and civil society organizations, to deliver on the
various needs of the urban poor and respond to the imperatives
of ‘sustainable’ urban development.
This, admittedly crude and stylized, summary of the essence of the
mainstream urban development approach can be discerned in both
of the leading global campaigns of UN–Habitat – ‘shelter for all’ and
urbanization trends
37
‘good urban governance’ – developed to drive urban policy reform.
This policy model is deeply lawed because it is unlikely to galvanize
urban actors who are interested in and committed to economic
justice to ind their voice and drive systemic reforms. Why? on the
one hand, the UN–Habitat campaigns argue for increased investment in slum prevention, more participatory democracy, pro-poor
tenure policies, and so on; and on the other hand, they support and
legitimate economic development policies that focus on improving
the business climate, prioritizing economic infrastructure in order to
attract investment, privatizing or corporatizing certain urban services
where appropriate, offering growth-enhancing tax incentives, and so
on. These policy approaches are not readily compatible, and, in the
absence of a clear hierarchy of public good before private gain, it is
inevitable that such a policy muddle creates an ideal set of conditions
for those with power and inluence in the city to reproduce their
interests, at the expense of the poor, with little dificulty. In my
reading, the primary reason we are left with such a problematic model
of urban development is the undertheorization and underemphasis of
contestation-based politics that can surface and engage with power
differentials in the city. It is exactly this question, then, that animates
my reviews of the two primary urban development policy planks:
shelter for all (reviewed in Chapter 3) and good urban governance,
linked to city development strategies (reviewed in Chapter 4). The
remainder of the book then proceeds to offer a different conceptual
approach, which works through the useful aspects of the mainstream
models but pushes it beyond their limitations.
Conclusion
The second wave of urbanization, which is largely conined to the
south, could not have come at a worse time. When technological
innovations offered solutions to the challenge of sanitation, health
and reliable access to energy, these were assumed to be a public good,
and ostensibly provided for urban populations in the North. This
ideal persisted even in times of deep economic crisis and especially
in post-war reconstruction times. However, as many cities and towns
in the south come to be confronted with equivalent challenges, they
are under tremendous pressure to think of urban infrastructure in
38
city futures
relation to securing optimal productive platforms for mobile local
and global capital, and to subject the institutional forms of service
delivery to market actors, or at least market forces. This is creating a dualistic urban system: the globally connected infrastructural
enclaves in the city versus the informal, almost disconnected and
abandoned city, where the urban poor are subjected to inhumane
living conditions.
In telling this particular story (there are many others that can
be told given the great variety and complexity of urban change) I
have obviously not covered a range of pertinent and increasingly
pivotal issues. For example, I have said nothing about the fact that
the vast majority of urbanites in the south actually live in small
and medium-sized cities, contrary to the popular focus on mega (10
million plus) and meta (20 million plus) cities. It is envisaged that
the current proportion of 60 per cent of urban dwellers who live
in urban settlements with populations smaller that 1 million (10
per cent) and smaller than 0.5 million (51 per cent) will continue
to remain into the foreseeable future. This reality represents very
different conditions to the ones typically discussed in relation to
5 million plus (7 per cent) and 10 million plus (9 per cent) cities.
I have also said nothing about the demographic character of cities
and towns in the south; the fact that a distinctive youth bulge will
shape the dominant identity and character of these places. equally,
I have ignored the growing debate on climate change and cities, and
how this particular policy option is breathing new life into the urban
sustainability agendas. Lastly, I have only hinted at the fact that
categories of work (if work can be found) are profoundly different
to what urban dwellers in the south knew or had access to just one
generation ago. Given the centrality of work to questions of identity,
social capital, household structures and the like, this is pivotal in
understanding the nature and dynamics of urban life in the south.
Given the limited length of this book, it is obviously impossible to
cover all of the relevant issues. What I have decided is to structure
the review and analysis to get at the nub of the dominant policy
models that purport to advance an agenda of democratic inclusion,
economic justice and cultural pluralism. It is now time to consider
in greater detail mainstream urban development solutions.
3
Mainstream agenda 1:
shelter for all
We reafirm our commitment to the full and progressive realization
of the right to adequate housing, as provided for in international instruments.… We commit ourselves to the goal of improving living and
working conditions on an equitable and sustainable basis, so that
everyone will have adequate shelter that is healthy, safe, secure,
accessible and affordable and that includes basic services, facilities and amenities, and will enjoy freedom from discrimination in
housing and legal security of tenure. [Moreover,] providing legal
security of tenure and equal access to land to all people, including
women and those living in poverty; and undertaking legislative
and administrative reforms to give women full and equal access
to economic resources, including the right to inheritance and to
ownership of land and other property, credit, natural resources and
appropriate technologies. (Habitat Agenda, paras 40 and 40(b))
The right to adequate housing was heavily contested at the Habitat
II Conference in Istanbul in June 1996, primarily because the United
states was vehemently opposed to it. This is one battle it lost, not
least because newcomer on the global scene, south Africa, took
a very strong position on the issue. Correctly, progressives in the
urban development ield celebrated the endorsement of a rights-based
approach to housing, shelter and, by extension, land, as a momentous
victory. However, by 2004, UN–Habitat admitted that ‘since the City
40
city futures
summit in Istanbul, it has become all too apparent that the conditions
of the world’s poor have not been improved, but have continued to
deteriorate.’1 Thus, on the heels of the authoritative The Challenge of
Slums: Global Report on Human Settlements 2003, UN–Habitat unveiled
a reined agenda to drive the ‘Global Campaign for secure shelter’.
since this document distils most clearly the organization’s view on
shelter, and consolidates arguments made in previous publications
and related programmatic documents, I will restrict my discussion
in this chapter to its contents. In reviewing the various policy pronouncements of UN–Habitat it is clear that this document is the
most developed expression of the mainstream perspective on dealing
with the overwhelming growth of slums and the poverty associated
with it in most parts of the south.
What is particularly refreshing about the position paper (hereafter
referred to as ‘the Advocacy Tool’) is that it allows for complexity
and multiple tenure conditions as they have historically emerged in
different parts of the world. It studiously seeks to avoid a simple ‘onesize-its-all’ approach but at the same time is very clear and strong on
what it regards as the fundamental elements of a rights-based approach
to shelter. The Advocacy Tool is also clear about the scale and signiicance of market failure with respect to the rights of the urban poor
in terms of tenure security and access to shelter. This is noteworthy
given the impact of Hernando de soto’s rabid free-market tract The
Mystery of Capital, which appeared a few years before and found great
favour among many development agencies. one of the questionable
aspects of the Advocacy Tool’s conceptual approach is the continued
promotion of the discourse of slum eradication. on the one hand it
is understandable because it emerges out of Goal 7, target 11: ‘the
improvement of the lives of at least 100 million slum dwellers by the
year 2020’, but on the other hand it is also clear that slum-eradication
discourses can easily become a foil for perpetuating illegal slum evictions, as we witnessed in Harare (zimbabwe) in 2005 and 2006.
In light of this, what follows in this chapter is irst a brief contextualization of the shelter-for-all campaign and its links with the
broader campaigns that low from the Millennium development
Goals (MdGs). Thereafter I explore the six core tenets of the
shelter-for-all campaign, paying particular attention to the arguments
shelter for all
41
and approach with regard to tenure security. The following section
explores ive policy areas that arise from this campaign and require
more thought and deepening if the transformative potential of this
campaign is to be realized.
Context of the shelter for all campaign
The Millennium summit in september 2000 was an attempt by
the United Nations to redeine its relevance and role in the global
development effort. It coincided with a shift in mood in mainstream
development policy ideas in the aftermath of the Asian crisis and an
acknowledgement by World bank economists such as Joseph stiglitz
that there was something fundamentally wrong with the neoliberal
orthodoxy about free markets, decreasing state involvement through
privatization and the disregard for the environmental and social
consequences of the ‘growth-is-all-you-need’ model of development.
In this ideological milieu the UN attempted to carve out a new
development consensus that was premissed on human rights, a strong
developmental role for the state and regulated economic development
that was more socially inclusive and environmentally conscious, if not
quite sustainable. However, in the aftermath of the long list of global
development conferences since the rio environmental summit in
1992, there was also a determination to be more practical, concrete
and outcome-oriented in establishing a development consensus. The
Millennium development Goals were thus born and address eight
areas: poverty and hunger; primary education; women’s equality;
child mortality; maternal health; disease; environment; and a global
partnership for development. each goal was further broken down
into speciic targets to be achieved by 2015, with the exception of
the slum improvement target, which was set for 2020.
Target 11, in conjunction with target 10, which deals with safe
drinking water and sanitation, became an important galvanizing
point for UN–Habitat as it also repositioned itself – after a period
of internal pressure and attack within the UN family – to become
more vocal and effective. Thus, UN–Habitat restructured itself to
do four primary tasks with regard to slum eradication: monitoring
secure tenure and slum upgrading; analysis of political, social and
economic factors that impact on tenure and informal settlements;
42
city futures
campaigning through rights-based advocacy around the solutions
available to achieve the target; and promoting operational readiness
in member states through policy reform and capacity-building that
can support ‘instruments for the improvements in tenure security,
shelter, services, and employment in slum areas.’2
In light of this policy-institutional approach, the Global Campaign
for secure Tenure (GCsT) became the central plank to advance
the commitments member states made in the Habitat Agenda to
providing Adequate shelter for All. The GCsT, at the highest design
level, focused on preventative and adaptive strategies. The former
focuses on a perspective and response that moves away from trying
to stop migration from rural to urban areas, but rather concentrates
on how such patterns can be slowed down and managed more effectively to realize a more dispersed pattern of urban settlements, more
amenable to economic and social management. Adaptive strategies
are deined on the basis that developing countries need to come to
terms with the enduring reality of large-scale informal settlements.
once acceptance occurs, a substantial policy scaffolding needs to
be developed and instituted. The adaptive focus provides guidance
on what these policies are and how best to institutionalize them
in various contexts. The absolute starting point of adaptation is an
unambiguous move to ensure security of tenure. Thereafter, a vast
array of policy considerations come into play.
In practical terms, adaptive strategies are cost-effective programmes and
projects aimed at providing, in a sustainable manner: decent housing
or house improvement schemes, including micro-credit for low cost
housing; a range of affordable tenure options which give tenure security
to the poor; Water and sanitation; disaster preparedness and prevention; Community-led safer cities initiatives; solid waste management
services; Transport infrastructure and services; Attracting investment
through appropriate regulatory framework [sic] and increased productivity; environmentally sound urban policies; Promoting inclusion,
gender awareness and participatory decision making; and building local
capacities through decentralization, legislative and institutional change
and strengthening local governments.3
However, this rather ambitious longer-term agenda is pursued
through a more methodical focus on what the Campaign toolkit
calls ‘key messages’:
shelter for all
43
• Protecting and promoting housing rights for all to ensure enjoyment of full urban citizenship for the urban poor.
• secure tenure is essential for city stability, human dignity and
urban development.
• Gender equity: promoting the role of women in development and
the removal of all discrimination.
• Partnership: city governments working with people’s organizations
can promote sustainable urban development.
• There should be an alternative to forced evictions which
violate human rights, in the form of negotiated resettlement if
necessary.
• Provision of transparent and accessible information on urban land
markets can reduce corruption and speculation.
• Provision of affordable well-located land for human settlement is
essential for the future of the city.4
I explore each of these themes in closer detail in the next section,
although the main emphases fall on tenure security, civil society
participation and the regulation of land markets, before I conclude
with relections on the silences in the campaign.
Tenets of the global campaign for secure tenure
As I signalled in the introduction to the chapter, this policy framework set out by UN–Habitat is astute and impressive given the range
of interests and issues that it needs to balance. In particular, given my
broader argument in the book for deepening a rights-based approach
to urban transformation, I ind the centrality of a rights discourse
useful and important. The GCsT advocacy framework explicitly identiies it as a major problem and weakness in the overall shelter effort
that the right to housing is largely ignored and frequently violated. In
response, the GCsT seeks to draw attention to the legal obligations
on states to take it seriously, and has enrolled the ofice of the United
Nations High Commissioner for Human rights, who in turn has
appointed a special rapporteur on adequate housing. Interestingly,
in 2007 the special rapporteur carried out a review of south Africa’s
housing policies and programmes. In one recommendation he points
out the imperative for south Africa: ‘To consider intervention in the
44
city futures
market to regulate the current high and unaffordable prices, and to
check against land and property speculation.’5 This is fascinating
because it is, of course, the dominance of property rights, particularly
private property rights, which are enshrined in the constitution,
that play a big part in the inability of south Africa to give effect
to the progressive realization of housing rights. Unfortunately, the
tension between private property rights and housing rights are left
hanging in the GCsT, which weakens the transformative potential
of the document. This is a curious oversight since the document
itself recognizes the role of unregulated, speculative land markets
in perpetuating slums.
Tenure security
The guts of the GCsT, and its strongest conceptual part, is the
discussion on tenure security. The overarching argument of the
document is that the most important reform to achieve in the push
towards the broader goal of shelter for all, as envisioned in the Habitat
Agenda, is to address the large-scale problem of tenure insecurity.
From this vantage point, the campaign prioritizes tenure security as
opposed to promoting particular kinds of tenure. In fact, the GCsT
advocacy tool usefully spells out the spectrum of tenure relations
that can be found; what needs to be done at the macro level to
improve the overall context of tenure security; and then how to put
in place a system to bring greater certainty and clarity to what will
invariably be a very complex and luid tenure scenario. And, because
of the wide spectrum of tenure arrangements (see box 3.1 below)
that it regards as prevalent and in complex relation to each other,
the policy framework points to the potential dangers associated with
rapid regularization of land ownership to achieve individual freehold
title because of potential unintended consequences such as market
eviction through downward raiding.6 The perspective of the GCsT
comes through particularly clearly in the following argument:
Land tenure and property rights are more complicated than the conventional categories of legal/illegal, or formal/informal suggest. Most
urban areas contain a range of semi-legal categories and maybe even
more than one legal system, as in countries where statutory, customary
and religious tenure co-exist. In this sense, it is preferable to consider
shelter for all
45
tenure and property rights as a continuum with different shades of grey
as well as black and white categories. Land tenure issues relect cultural,
historical and political inluences; therefore policy should recognize
and relect local circumstances.7
This perspective makes sense once one appreciates the range within
the continuum of tenure arrangements, each with unique advantages
and limitations for the urban poor, that can generally be found in
urban areas in the south.
In light of this diversity, what is more important to UN–Habitat
is ‘residential tenure’ as opposed to access to land-based freehold
title, the preferred solution of Hernando de soto.8 The residential
tenure bias is in response to the reality of informal settlements
as a substantial, if not dominant, component of the urban fabric.
The core issue for the GCsT is the imperative to establish formal
legal recognition of diverse tenure arrangements that proliferate and
coexist in informal areas, because they observe that even in cases
where there may be de facto administrative recognition through ‘the
provision of municipal and urban services, and the associated collection of revenue’, insecurity in the face of exploitative discretionary
authority can remain high.9 In other words, tenure is enforceable but
not justiciable, which, for UN–Habitat, disqualiies it from being
considered secure tenure. This is a very signiicant position to take
because in increasingly large portions of the developing world a situation is arising where some basic services are extended to informal
areas but the underlying tenure issues are not addressed, making
such investments accrue to intermediaries that control these areas
beyond the regulatory purview of the state and on very exploitative
terms for the urban poor.10 Also, when market opportunities come
knocking through downward raiding, there is no protection for these
communities, and households will simply be washed away to another,
probably more remote, insecure location.
I now want to return to the argument made by de soto that
bestowing freehold title is the most effective way to reconnect slums
and informal settlements back into the mainstream fabric of the city.
This is an important debate to review because most governments and
private-sector interests that join up with governance partnerships
or city strategy forums are likely to be seduced by the simplicity
46
city futures
BOX 3.1
Tenure systems and their characteristics11
Freehold
Provides ownership in perpetuity.
Advantages: high degree of security; freedom to dispose, or use as
collateral for loans; maximizes commercial value, enabling people
to realize substantial increases in asset values.
Disadvantages: costs of access generally high; collateral value may
not be relevant if incomes are low or inancial institutions are weak;
property values can go down as well as up and may trap the unwary
in properties worth less than they paid for them.
Delayed freehold
Conditional ownership: title is granted on the completion of payments or when developments have been completed.
Advantages: same high degree of security as freehold, providing payments are made as required or developments completed;
freedom to dispose, or use as collateral for loans; maximizes commercial value, enabling people to realize substantial increases in
asset values.
Disadvantages: failure to maintain payments or undertake developments may result in eviction and loss of funds invested; collateral
value may not be relevant if incomes are low; property values can
go down as well as up and may trap the unwary in properties worth
less than they paid for them; expectations of increased values can
divert investments from more productive sectors of the economy.
Registered leasehold
ownership for a speciied period: from a few months to 999 years.
Advantages: as secure as freehold, but only for the period speciied in the lease.
Disadvantages: requires legal framework; costs of access generally
high.
Public rental
rental occupation of publicly owned land or house.
Advantages: provides a high degree of security provided terms
and conditions of occupation are met.
Disadvantages: limited supply may restrict access; often badly
located for access to livelihoods; terms often restrictive; deterioration if maintenance costs not met.
shelter for all
Private rental
rental of privately owned land or property.
Advantages: good security; maintains social cohesion.
Disadvantages: open to abuse by disreputable owners; deterioration
if maintenance costs not met.
Shared equity
Combination of delayed freehold and rental, in which residents
purchase a stake in their property (often 50 per cent) and pay rent
on the remainder to the other stakeholder.
Advantages: combines the security and potential increase in
asset value of delayed freehold and the lexibility of rental; residents can increase their stake over time, ultimately leading to full
ownership.
Disadvantages: needs legal framework and eficient management.
Co-operative tenure
ownership is vested in the co-operative or group of which residents
are co-owners.
Advantages: good security if protected by legally enforceable
contract; provides tenants with lexibility of movement.
Disadvantages: requires a legal framework; restrictions may reduce
incentives to invest; requires double registration irst of land and
of association.
Customary ownership
ownership is vested in the tribe, group community or family. Land
is allocated by customary authorities such as chiefs.
Advantages: widely accepted; simple to administer; maintains
social cohesion.
Disadvantages: may lose its legal status in urban areas; vulnerable
to abuse under pressure of urbanization; poor customary leadership
may weaken its legitimacy.
Religious tenure systems (e.g. Islamic)
There are four main categories of land tenure within Islamic societies. Waqf is religious trust land and is potentially very signiicant in
addressing landlessness, whilst mulk, or individual full ownership,
is also protected in law; miri, or state owned/controlled land which
carries tassruf or usufruct rights, is increasingly common, whilst
musha/mushtarak, is collective/tribal ownership.
47
48
city futures
Advantages: facilitates family/group tenures and accessible and
affordable land management procedures.
Disadvantages: because they are outside the commercial land
market, waqf lands are often ineficiently managed. Inheritance
disputes can cause land conlicts.
Non-formal tenure systems
These include a wide range of categories with varying degrees of
legality or illegality. They include regularized and unregularized
squatting, unauthorized subdivisions on legally owned land and
various forms of unoficial rental arrangements. In some cases,
several forms of tenure may coexist on the same plot, with each
party entitled to certain rights.
Advantages: some of these non-formal categories, such as squatting, started as a response to the inability of public allocation
systems or formal commercial markets to provide for the needs of
the poor and operated on a socially determined basis.
Disadvantages: as demand has intensiied, even these informal
tenure categories have become commercialized, so that access by
lower income groups is increasingly constrained.
of the freehold tenure route, which is but one in the continuum of
practices prevalent in most urban areas. In his book The Mystery of
Capital, de soto seeks to do nothing less than solve the problem of
global poverty. He provides a compelling argument which centres on
the idea that the solution is already present in all cities, towns and
countries, awaiting enlightened and bold decision-makers to grasp it.
The solution is to transform widespread informal (or ‘extra-legal’ in
his parlance) tenure and economic conditions into formal or legally
recognized assets that individuals can use as a resource to access
capital, which in turn can propel their entrepreneurial initiatives
and further investments in their assets. And since the vast majority
of urban dwellers live in unregistered and informal arrangements,
all that is required is to transform such arrangements into formal,
recognized conditions – through freehold title deeds and business
permits – and the latent power and energy of the poor will be
unleashed, solving the problem of poverty. This model rests on
shelter for all
49
three core arguments: (i) people will only invest in their housing and
business if they feel secure of their tenure status; (ii) access to credit
can only be provided if there is a systematic legalization of informal
settlements and business, which assumes a massive undertaking to
bring all land and property into a cadastral system; and (iii) the best
practical means to achieve this is to provide universal title ownership through individual freehold title that can result in a coherent
titles system that is linked to enforceable rights.12 Apart from Peru
and many other Latin American countries where large-scale titling
programmes have been and are being pursued, the Tanzanian government also commissioned de soto and his team to run this model for
Tanzania.13 so, there should be no illusions about the impact and
discourse-shaping effects of this work.
since the publication of de soto’s The Mystery of Capital, a number
of critical reviews of the book and, especially, the implementation
of his ideas has followed. In essence these concur that none of the
three pillars of the policy model holds water. For example, reviews
of a large-scale titling programme in Peru, which involved the issuing
of 1.4 million titles between 1996 and 2004, did not necessarily lead
to access to credit. Apparently, for most lending agencies, a regular
job was more important.14 speciically, only 1.6 per cent of titleholders had obtained loans using the property as collateral by the time
76 per cent of these titles had been issued in Peru.15 This empirical
trend is a damning indictment of the essence of de soto’s model.
Furthermore, empirical trends in Latin America also reveal that
large numbers of people access informal credit even when there is
no effective perception of tenure security. This undercuts the notion
that freehold title is a precondition for access to credit.
At a deeper, legally conceptual level, edesio Fernandez points out
that what remains undeveloped or deined in de soto’s work is the
sociology and political economy of legal systems: in other words,
the assumption that there is ‘a universal, a-historical “natural” legal
deinition’ of property rights is simply a iction. Historical evidence is
clear, according to Fernandez, that the state treats ‘different forms of
property rights (inancial, industrial, intellectual, etc.) and the social
relations around them’ differently in order to ‘accommodate varying
degrees of state intervention in the domain of economic property
50
city futures
relations’.16 As a consequence of this ahistorical perspective on legal
systems and the political-cultural norms that underpin and surround
them, de soto also misses ‘dialectically contradictory relationships
between legality and illegality’. However, the most important and
damning critique of an uncritical, ahistorical drive to conduct blanket
titling to solve (urban) poverty is that it fails to appreciate the dangers
of freehold title in terms of the overall urban system. Fernandez
argues cogently:
[e]xisting research has shown that while the recognition of individual
freehold titles can promote individual security of legal tenure it does
not necessarily entail sociospatial integration. Unless titling is undertaken within the context of a broader set of public policies that address
urban, politico-institutional and socioeconomic conditions, legalization
programs may actually aggravate the processes of exclusion and segregation. As a result, the original beneiciaries of the programs might
not be able to remain on the legalized land, although that should be
the ultimate objective of regularization programs, especially on public
land.17
on this note, I will return to my review of the GCsT advocacy
tool publication. It provides a clear set of arguments around the
limitations and problems associated with freehold title,18 which echo
the points levelled against de soto. In light of this caution about
freehold title, the GCsT promotes a focus on rental lease and groupbased forms of tenure as areas of policy thinking that require more
work and, especially, improved institutional functioning where it is
in fact being addressed. In fact, what emerges in the document is
that the rental sector particularly is seen as key:
[F]or low-income families, rental – which is the most used form of
tenure – is seldom formal or regulated in many countries. Agreements
are arrived at informally, with little or no recourse to legal advice, and
the agreements are enforced in a non-legal manner. Indeed, a major
part of the campaign will have to address the urban-poor segment of
the rental sector, and the tension that exists between secure tenure for
tenants and sub-tenants, and the property rights of the owners. both
in percentage and in policy terms, addressing the informal rental sector
will be one of the most signiicant challenges for the campaign, and on
which will have the most impact for the urban poor.19
shelter for all
51
However, working in the rental and group-based systems implies a
high level of capability within state and support institutions, which
is not a trivial matter given the low levels of effective decentralization and inancial devolution that remain a dominant factor in many
developing countries. In fairness, the GCsT recognizes the necessity
of not only institutional capability but also institutional thickness:
‘Partnerships, a user-friendly justice system, [clearly a big ask], and
the role of well-informed NGos is critical in the creation of good
lessor–lessee relationships.’ Furthermore, the ‘exclusion that women
face in the titling process applies with regard to leases, and requires
speciic measures, such as joint registration and joint recording in
the name of both spouses.’20 What is perhaps less clear is how such
capacity will be developed and what happens in the interim whilst
local states get empowered and capacity is developed. Furthermore,
the document fails to explain its optimism about the likely private
sector involvement in providing loan inance to group-based tenure
bodies. 21
A core message of the GCsT is that ‘all forms of secure tenure
can only be effective when they operate within an enabling legal
framework, and they are supported by good governance and an
administrative capacity.’22 The question this immediately raises is, to
what extent are these preconditions likely to exist? Moreover, what
are the factors that militate against their existence? For example,
if informalized and backstreet deal-making is the norm, how does
one really engage and root out patronage-based politics? In most
developing countries with relatively young or fragile democracies,
political parties are embedded in the broader context of limited
economic opportunities and a desperate need for access to scarce
public resources. In these contexts, clientalist and patronage politics
are a way of life. 23 Can weak local states be ‘ixed’ in a short period
of time? In any case, are there any irm indicators or evidence that
national political-cultural factors that undermine substantive and
funded decentralization of functions are likely to change in the
immediate future given trend patterns over the past decade? It is
important to contextualize these lines of questioning by reference to
the aftermath of devastating structural adjustment policies that have
eroded national power, authority and capability. None of these central
52
city futures
governance questions is satisfactorily addressed or even lagged in
the campaign materials. of course, there is constant reference to the
linked campaign on good urban governance, but, as I show in the
next chapter, these kinds of issues are not addressed in that domain
of work either.
Furthermore, market pressures and trends are underestimated
in the document. one reason why effective regulation of land and
property markets is dificult is that developing countries are typically
highly dependent on a relatively small tax-paying class that sustains
the coffers of the state, and often also the individual interests of
senior politicians in the ruling party and the state. Considering the
impact of the globalization of property markets and, increasingly,
real-estate and developer companies, it is apparent that the regulatory
power of states with regard to developers and investors is limited.
And, as the GCsT recognizes, without strong regulatory intervention
in land markets through appropriate tenure systems and land-use
instruments, advancing the approach advocated for by the GCsT will
be very dificult. In this context, it is a serious omission that there is
not a more explicit and detailed argument about speciic regulations
and regulating systems to structure and steer land-use patterns more
effectively. Practically, I have in mind the typology proposed by
robert riddell, which includes, inter alia: eminent domain, negotiated purpose, land banking, central directive, a wide array of zoning
categories, growth boundary, transferable development rights, waivers,
purchased development right, user levies, development bonuses.24 It
seems that an emphasis on particular kinds of tenure that are optimal
for the urban poor cannot be divorced from a larger framework of
urban management instruments that needs to be in place to impact
decisively and effectively on urban land markets.
This gap in the approach to tenure security as a pathway to
adequate shelter throws up the question, what are the elements of
the bigger picture? Clearly, the irst aspect is access to basic services
within a framework that guarantees access for those who are too
poor to pay. Also, tenure regularization must unfold in tandem
with a ‘locality-within-a-region’ approach to the extension of basic
services. In other words, infrastructure investments and maintenance
systems for a particular informal settlement must be designed and
shelter for all
53
planned with explicit reference to a larger urban regional approach
– in part because the way services are extended and maintained offers
crucial opportunities to deal with unemployment and informal service
providers who can be enrolled into more regularized and contextsensitive models of delivery. In another sense, a regional approach is
crucial because the infrastructural response must be consistent with
regional-level objectives to achieve a more environmentally sustainable urban form and system – that is, a system that progressively
reduces unsustainable patterns of consumption and production and
facilitates more equitable spatial patterns and relations. I will return
to this issue in the next section because it deserves more attention
in urban development debates.
Last, in terms of the bigger picture agenda that should frame
strategic approaches to tenure, is the question of the quality of the
built environment that characterizes informal settlements, but also
strategic arteries in the city that connect slums to each other and the
larger urban system. When I speak of quality of the built environment I am referring to the architectural, urban design and planning
criteria that inform slum-upgrading programmes. The tendency is to
focus on individual households, or a small cluster of overpopulated
slum clusters, but very seldom is there an explicit recognition of the
centrality of design-based criteria (beyond the functional issues of
cheapest material per monetary unit) to the calculus about how to
improve living conditions in a slum. brazil, Chile and Colombia have
important examples of how to bring high-quality public spaces that
promote security, especially the safety of women and children, and
luid movement corridors and pathways into informal areas to create
a profoundly different sense of place, even if the dominant mode
of shelter construction is makeshift and a hotchpotch of solid and
temporary materials. 25 The important beneit of a spatial approach
that is also design-rich is that it affords innovative opportunities to
create democratic deliberation processes among local residents, and
between them and the state, about what physical expression can be
given to the identities and aspirations of a particular community.
This particular issue is reinforced in Chapter 6 where I explore different aesthetic and phenomenological registers to think about and
through slums. on the note of participation, I now want to turn
54
city futures
to the UN–Habitat embracing of slum dwellers’ organizations as a
partner in achieving its long-term vision of shelter for all.
Secure tenure, slum upgrading and participation
The GCsT is peppered with references to the importance of women’s
participation in improving the tenure situation of slum dwellers.
There is also a fascinating discussion on the growth of vulnerable
children in the context of the AIds pandemic as a particular category
of vulnerable people in informal settlements. This is a commendable
conceptual and policy focus throughout the whole family of interrelated shelter and governance policy streams of both UN–Habitat
and the other urban development agencies gathered together in the
Cities Alliance. I have one quibble though. Throughout the document, the participation of women is equated with gender equality.
There is, of course, an obvious truth to this given that in most
developing countries, women remain primarily excluded from and
marginalized in decision-making processes; a highly detrimental
situation because the literature is fairly conclusive that development
resources controlled by women tend to have better developmental
outcomes, especially for children. However, it is also well established
that women are not automatically in favour of gender equality and
can for various cultural and social reasons be as vociferous as men in
reinforcing gender stereotypes and deferring decision-making to men.
In light of this it is necessary for the GCsT to reine its thinking on
gender equality and what is required concretely to shift both men’s
and women’s attitudes and behaviours with regard to gender roles
and a reconiguration of power relations.
I now want to turn to the UN Millennium Task Force report
on Improving the Lives of slums dwellers, titled A Home in the City
(hereafter also referred to as the ‘task force report’). This report sets
out compellingly what one can describe as the emerging consensus on
how best to understand and transform slums in the global effort to
achieve target 11 of the MdGs. 26 I want to home in on the report’s
robust perspective on the pivotal role of civil society organizations in
addressing the challenge of slums, and, within this, particularly the
position and methodology of federations of slums dwellers. This is
of relevance because there is clearly cross-fertilization between what
shelter for all
55
the core argument of the task force report is and the one promoted
in the GCsT. 27 The policy perspective adopted, and advocated, in
the task force report constitutes an important shift in mainstream
thinking about effective interventions to address urban slums.
A Home in the City followed closely on the heels of the important
UN–Habitat Global report on Human settlements of 2003, The Challenge of Slums. In this report the paradigm-shift away from a narrow
slum clearance/sanitation approach to one of gradual systematic
improvement in partnership with slum dwellers was unambiguously
consolidated. Furthermore, The Challenge of Slums also went to considerable lengths to demonstrate the structural underpinnings of urban
inequality that frame the formation and growth of slums in the world;
again, a critical political economy perspective that further opened the
door for progressive civil society interests to advance arguments about
the importance of a politicized rights-based discourse in dealing with
understanding and improving slum areas. As I suggested at the outset,
these recent shifts in mainstream policy discourses are undoubtedly
important achievements in promoting a more transformative approach
to urban development politics and praxis.
Given the salience of a savings-based mobilization methodology
of organizing slum dwellers, it is itting to relect more critically on
this ‘achievement.’ It seems to me that that there was a ‘thinning’ of
social life and sociality in slum areas in the imaginary about social
citizenship that was being invoked by the emerging consensus. I
am therefore ambivalent about the elevation of a particular social
mobilization model of various homeless people’s federations across
the world as necessarily the most effective way of building onto
capacities within poor communities. My ambivalence stems from the
fact that I agree with much of the analysis in the UN Millennium
Task Force’s report about the methodology and effectiveness of these
organizations (see chapter 2 in the report), and further appreciate
the strategic signiicance of having such a bottom-up democratic
perspective ensconced in global discourses about urban development; yet, at the same time, I am concerned about the reiication
of a particular social mobilization model with respect to expressing
social citizenship in the context of urban slums28 (in Chapter 6, I
underscore the importance of these movements).
56
city futures
There are indeed outstanding features in the methodology that
member federations of shack/slum dwellers International have
forged organically over time, and mostly through tough struggles, but
it remains a model that emerged in very particular cultural-historical
circumstances. When a grassroots methodology is elevated to a generic
mode of social intervention, it potentially runs into problems. For
example, a review of the south African Homeless People’s Federation
revealed that elements of the savings-based model do not work in all
contexts. signiicantly, the model tends to ‘impose’ a moral regime
on the participants in the movements that holds the potential of
being authoritarian, especially when internal democratic processes
and cultures are still nascent. As a result, the highly disciplined and
ritualistic methodology of these organizations does draw strong lines
of inclusion and exclusion inside the communities where they operate,
even though they supposedly operate on non-sectarian principles. This
is not to detract from the excellent work the various federations do
but merely to lag that putting forward their model as the approach
for civil society participation in slum improvement and prevention
is not without dangers. The increasingly inluential task force report
does not go far enough to unpack some of these issues.
What’s more, and related, the task force report and the GCsT
tend to treat the four stakeholder groups – organizations of the poor,
the private sector, government and NGos – in slum improvement
and prevention as too homogenous. on the civil society side this
tendency leads to a too-narrow focus on a particular model of poor
people’s organization. on the private sector side the focus is simply
on leveraging investment and not broader issues such as the roles
that can arise from different categories of business. Private-sector
behaviour in general in shaping market sentiments about appropriate
and optimal levels of redistribution in a society is as important as
the material contribution of the private sector through inancing
of urban infrastructure. As a result there is not enough emphasis
in either report on the broader environment-shaping role of the
private sector that shapes discursive boundaries about how the slums
question is deined in societal terms and, most importantly, what
everyone in the city can do to intervene. This goes to the question
of culpability in the growth and persistence of slums and associated
shelter for all
57
living conditions in cities where the middle class live very different
lives, and can potentially contribute to solving the issues through
myriad contributions that address social cohesion, solidarity and
bridging social capital.
Linked to the previous blind spot, slum dwellers are painted
in homogenous terms, which stem from the social mobilization
model and generality of the recommendations proposed in the report.
Pragmatically, it is understandable that slum dwellers are depicted
in one-dimensional terms, but of concern are the consequences for
policymakers who come to these issues for the irst time. In other
words, if such decision-makers encounter real communities in all their
rich and contradictory diversity, they may regard the general approach
of the report as too idealistic or simply unviable. In fairness, the task
force report does at certain points draw attention to how identity
markers of difference can ‘affect the severity with which problems
are experienced’, but this is not teased out strongly enough. This
leads to another concern.
The task force report does not pay attention to the beneits,
limited and perverse as they may be, that slum situations offer some
of the poor who live there. Any slum improvement intervention
must be sober about why it may be beneicial for some people to
want to continue their livelihoods in a context of an informal settlement and not formal housing or a more formalized environment. As
slums exist currently, they are teeming with life, social networks and
economic linkages. It is often impossible to re-create these livelihood
options and possibilities outside of highly luid and malleable physical
conditions that are best offered by informal areas. It is important
to shed light on these aspects of slum life, without romanticizing
them, because policymakers are often bafled by the resistance that
come from some slum dwellers to upgrading proposals. Furthermore,
upgrading initiatives must, of course, work with an intimate understanding of the existing livelihood strategies of those affected, as
the vast literature on livelihoods and asset-based poverty reminds us.
This was missed in south Africa where the government is confronted
by the dilemma that people who have been awarded a ‘free’ house
with basic services by the government sell it way below the value at
the moment of transfer, only to return to an informal settlement,
58
city futures
because they need some inancial liquidity to carry out trading that
can only be done in an informal setting as the land-use and property
regulations are too restrictive in formal townships.
The point of this section has simply been to problematize current
mainstream thinking, which has moved considerably from where
it was a decade ago on questions of slum resident participation in
settlement policies, in order to contribute to what I think is a valuable and potentially empowering framework for the future of urban
development processes. In Chapters 4 and 5 it will become clearer
how one can think more broadly and multidimensionally about civil
society dynamics and participation in urban development discourses
and processes.
Infrastructure and environmental dimensions
In this last section I want to dwell on the infrastructural implications
of the approach to urban sustainability promoted in the GCsT: ‘A
sustainable policy for shelter and slum upgrading also entails the
promotion of linkages between service delivery, employment and
income generation.’29 This ambition is consistent with the argument
made in the larger, overarching State of Human Settlements 2003 report:
‘slum policies should seek to support the livelihoods of the urban
poor, by enabling urban informal sector activities to lourish, linking
low-income housing development to income generation, and ensuring
easy access to jobs though pro-poor transport and low-income settlement locations policies.’30 In this, arguably pro-poor, perspective, a
vital area of major reform is missed. Yes, of course it is essential to
ensure that infrastructure provision is conducted in the most labourintensive manner and linked to procurement provisions that allows
local people in the slum to be incorporated into the construction
and maintenance of the infrastructure. This bias goes almost without
saying, but what is arguably more important is to redeine the nature
of urban areas by systematically transforming the nature and ecological impacts of urban consumption and production activities.
Practically, what this means is a much more ambitious macroframework for urban infrastructure, which could then circumscribe
particular strategies for informal areas. Mark swilling argues that
from a city-wide systems level, down to the design of neighbour-
shelter for all
59
hoods and households, a number of transitions need to be pursued in
order to make cities simultaneously more environmentally sustainable,
socially inclusive and economically resilient.31 These transitions are:
• To renewable energy alternatives and greater energy eficiency,
as renewable infrastructures require long lead times to come on
stream. signiicantly, from an employment perspective, campaigns
to retroit and build differently can have a substantial knock-on
effect in terms of stimulating new niche market products and
services; and there is no reason why these growth areas cannot
be regulated to ensure absorption of unemployed people in slum
areas.
• To a zero-waste position for the city or town because all waste
outputs are turned into productive inputs for other economic
processes. International precedents and experience make this a
low-threshold reform to pursue with vigour. In fact, in most
developing countries waste-recycling activities characterized by
bad working conditions are widespread. However, what is missing
is a broader municipal policy that builds onto and augments what
urban informal recyclers have been doing all along.
• To sustainable transport systems, with a particular emphasis on
public transport. Again, good practice in cities like Curitiba,
bogotá and Porto Alegre makes this a very viable area of major
reform. Given the centrality of transport to a wide range of social
and economic processes, this is arguably the easiest entry point to
begin to reposition incrementally the infrastructure approach of
a city or town. The fast-growing problem of congestion is also a
good incentive to get middle-class buy-in for dramatic reform in
this area.
• To the mandatory use of sustainable construction materials and
building methods. even in countries where local government is
still nascent, most municipalities have the power to prescribe, in
combination with national guidelines, speciications for the use of
construction materials and levels of insulation that dramatically
increase the energy eficiency of dwellings.
• To sustainable water use and reuse of treated sewage. swilling
points out that grey ‘water re-use systems are viable at household
60
city futures
and neighbourhood levels, and neighbourhood-level sewage treatment systems are also viable, with the treated efluent feeding
into nurseries, orchards or back into houses to lush toilets. The
system can be coupled to better management of the commons
such as wetlands, recreational spaces, etc.’32 There are also numerous policies to use public-works type programmes to involve
large numbers of unemployed people to address leaks. Again, it is
relatively easy to draw linkages between more sustainable practices
and the informalized or self-organized work categories that make
sense in slum contexts.
• To local and sustainable food. This is probably one of the most
important and potentially rich areas of intervention. Given the
environmental health conditions in many slums, the importance
of good nutrition cannot be overstated. An intervention that can
make a massive difference to food security and proitable urban
agriculture with signiicant labour-absorbing potential would be
neighbourhood-level markets where small-scale growers, who represent a vital counterpoint to irrigation-based food production,
can display and sell their produce. Apart from the economic and
health beneits, this can also greatly contribute to urban design and
quality of place, issues which need more attention, as suggested
earlier.
• To a city-wide commitment to reinforce and support equity and
fair trade at all levels if possible. This is, of course, an area of
focus that is almost reaching maturity in Northern contexts, but
it seems to me that there is little preventing (particularly) middleincome countries making it fashionable for their middle classes
to consume ethically and organically, where feasible.
This is obviously not a comprehensive list but it indicates that an
overly narrow focus on extending basic services to the poor, without
thinking about the broader environmental sustainability and job
creation potential, is simply not wise at this stage. of course, given
the dominant ideologies that continue to underpin infrastructure
discourses, as mentioned in Chapter 2, along with rapidly growing
need and limited resources, these kinds of transition will not be that
easy to make. However, nor will the tenure reforms discussed earlier,
shelter for all
61
nor the desire for participation and power on the part of the urban
poor to shape urban development futures.
All of these redeinitions of urban management imply dramatic
changes in the orientation and capabilities of sub-national governments; they also imply a space for deep political contestation, negotiation, deliberation, agreement and more contestation because it is
impossible to reorient public priorities and budgets fundamentally
without a modicum of political agreement and determination. And,
by deinition, this has to be political engagement within sub-national
states but also between government representatives and representatives
from civil society organizations, business and universities. However,
in reading across the various UN–Habitat policy prescriptions, one
is struck by the conidence that enough participation and stakeholder
engagement will produce the necessary consensus and buy-in to drive
urban reform. These assumptions ind their starkest expression in
the Global Campaign for Urban Governance, to which I turn in
the next chapter. My aim is to demonstrate that without a fully
developed understanding of ‘the political’ – inherently conlictual
power relations – in the city, the prospects of moving good policies
into institutionalized practices are rather slim.
4
Mainstream agenda II:
good governance
sustainable human settlements are those that, inter alia, generate a
sense of citizenship and identity, cooperation and dialogue for the
common good, and a spirit of voluntarism and civic engagement,
where all people are encouraged and have an equal opportunity to
participate in decision making and development. (Habitat Agenda,
para. 32)
The increasingly central focus on the role of organizations representing slum dwellers, such as shack/slum dwellers International (sdI),
in the discourse of UN–Habitat and the UN Millennium Project, as
discussed in the previous chapter, illustrates the rise of participatory
development discourses in policy discussions on dealing with urbanization and particularly the growth of slums. In this chapter I want
to explore the mainstream policy approach to urban governance as
exempliied in the policy frameworks of UN–Habitat, and the increasingly inluential Cities Alliance. speciically, it requires a review of the
Good Urban Governance campaign of UN–Habitat, which has been
in circulation since 1999, and the Cities development strategy thrust
of Cities Alliance. My core argument is that at a normative level the
UN has made crucial advances to underwrite and extend the debate
on the right to housing and, more broadly, the right to city, themes
irst broached at Istanbul II in 1996. However, in my reading, the
good governance
63
underlying assumptions of both policy thrusts about local participatory democracy are deeply lawed and require closer scrutiny in order
to arrive at a more robust conception of democratic governance that
is conducive to greater intra-urban equity and inclusivity.
Origins and context
After a lurry of UN-sponsored international development conferences in the irst half of the 1990s, it was the turn of the urban
agenda to be showcased in 1996. An impressive global gathering
was assembled in Istanbul – that magniicent enigma of a city that
deies any form of conceptual capture – to deliberate on how best to
understand and respond to the challenges of worldwide urbanization.
In policy terms this gathering represented a high-water mark for
sustainable and human development protagonists in the UN system
who were trying to push back against the devastating effects of
the narrow neoliberal economic approach that came to overshadow
development policy and mainstream support during the 1980s and
early 1990s. Given that cities were regarded as the centrepiece of the
economic growth/productivity agendas of the World bank, it was
seen as a crucial frontier to consolidating a more holistic, democratic
and integrated approach to development. This is strongly evident in
the Habitat Agenda declaration that was adopted at the end of the
UN–Habitat summit, as evidenced in the following excerpt:
during the course of history, urbanization has been associated with
economic and social progress, the promotion of literacy and education,
the improvement of the general state of health, greater access to social
services, and cultural, political and religious participation. democratization has enhanced such access and meaningful participation and
involvement for civil society actors, for public–private partnerships,
and for decentralized, participatory planning and management, which
are important features of a successful urban future. Cities and towns
have been engines of growth and incubators of civilization and have
facilitated the evolution of knowledge, culture and tradition, as well as
of industry and commerce. Urban settlements, properly planned and
managed, hold the promise for human development and the protection of the world’s natural resources through their ability to support
large numbers of people while limiting their impact on the natural
environment.
64
city futures
It is important to bear in mind that by the mid-1990s, the expansion of democratic systems in the developing world was still recent.
Many postcolonial experiments had run aground through authoritarianism combined with asymmetrical insertion into global markets,
which saw the dramatic decline in value of primary commodities
from the late 1960s. It was only towards the end of the 1970s and
in the early 1980s that democratic experiments across the world
started to take a foothold again, manifested in an outbreak of multiparty democratic systems during the 1980s and 1990s. This trend was
further bolstered by the fall of the berlin Wall and the symbolic
disintegration of the ediice of actually existing socialism as it was
practised in the soviet Union and its surrogate states. Importantly,
neoliberal economic thought also achieved its apogee during this
period, a further impetus to dilute the power of the state, which
happened to be by and large undemocratic and authoritarian. There
was unfortunately a neat convergence between market fundamentalism associated with neoliberal economic thought and the push for
multiparty democracy across the world; and in existing democracies
like India or Argentina, neoliberalism lourished under the drive for
state withdrawal from services delivery to counteract the perceived
ineficiency and corruption of these machineries.
The point about this recollection is that by the beginning of the
1990s, the discourse of multiparty democracy was hegemonic and
virtually total. However, in most developing countries this simply
meant a reinforcement of state power in national government, especially the executive. Local democracy was typically underdeveloped,
in large part because national departments, or their surrogates at a
local level, performed most services. As a consequence, much of the
scholarly and policy debates on democracy at the dawn of the 1990s
focused on the need to decentralize and devolve state power to local
levels if democratic cultures were to become culturally embedded
and to ensure more responsive and effective service delivery by the
state. even though most nation-states in the context of the UN
system would pay lip service to this approach, they did very little
by way of substantive local reforms to move in the direction of
deep decentralization and/or devolution.1 Apart from the persistent
tendency towards centralization, there was also persistent reluctance
good governance
65
to adopt participatory mechanisms to make elected leaders and their
staff more accountable and connected with ordinary citizens and
their organizations.
It is against this backdrop of weak democratic systems, limited
commitment to decentralization and participation that the text and
approach of the Habitat Agenda needs to be considered. It is therefore understandable that the document is peppered with themes
such as ‘enablement’, ‘partnership’, ‘participation’, ‘civic engagement’,
‘solidarity’, ‘decentralization of authority’ and ‘capacity building’. The
reference to enablement signalled the need for states to formulate
and institionalize legal frameworks and iscal systems that guarantee
decentralization, partnerships and participation by civil society and
the private sector in local governance processes. Moreover, in the
declaration it is strongly asserted that the solution to urbanization
characterized by poverty, economic exclusion, slum conditions and
negative environmental impacts is indeed sustainable development,
which in turn is premissed on democratic governance: ‘democracy,
respect for human rights, transparent, representative and accountable
government and administration in all sectors of society, as well as
effective participation by civil society, are indispensable foundations
for the realization of sustainable development.’2 A few years after
Habitat II, the UN–Habitat launched a global campaign to advocate
for, and embed, good urban governance.
Global Campaign on Urban Governance
The Global Campaign on Urban Governance (GCUG) is the second
part of a twin-track strategy to advance the Habitat Agenda. In the
previous chapter I considered at some length the other track, the
Global Campaign for secure Tenure. GCUG is striking for its bold
discourse, which comes on the back of a very signiicant restructuring and repositioning process that UN–Habitat went through
in the late 1990s. The outcome of this repositioning exercise was
that UN–Habitat resolved to take on more of an advocacy role,
presumably because the normal methods of diplomatic policy building
proved unsatisfactory or the fact that the urban agenda was simply
not achieving traction as a high-proile development issue. The other
aspect of the newfound boldness was the explicit poverty-reduction
66
city futures
focus underpinned by the principles of equity, urban justice and
urban citizenship. These are potentially powerful principles that are
suggestive of radical reform.
Flowing from these principles, the campaign sets its sights on the
policy ideal of realizing an Inclusive City ‘because inclusive decisionmaking is at the heart of good urban governance’.3 According to the
concept paper, local contexts in cities and towns are always marked
by ‘the messy reality of competing interests and priorities’, and it is
therefore essential that the institutions charged with balancing and
reconciling competing interests are as inclusive as possible because
inclusivity guarantees ‘the greatest likelihood for sustainability’.4 There
are a number of conceptual leaps made here which it is important to
interrogate more closely, a task I shall return to once I have explained
more fully the scaffolding of the concept paper. Now it is important
to point out that the paper also stresses the particular importance of
including women in urban governance and development processes
because they represent the most vulnerable and excluded group alongside older people, youth, the disabled and children. Inclusivity is also
located within a rights-based approach to development, which implies
an approach to ‘poverty reduction based on the full complement of
civil, cultural, economic, political and social rights’.5
Conceptually, the position paper then moves on to deine a range
of norms that substantiate what good urban governance means.
These are: sustainability, subsidiarity, equity, eficiency, transparency
and accountability, civic engagement and citizenship, and security,
which are all deined as interdependent and mutually reinforcing.
The bulk of the concept paper is then devoted to unpacking each
of these principles by spelling out what they may mean if translated into practical actions. In this regard, the objectives are mostly
incontestable and the practical measures suggested are indeed farreaching. Considered differently, if municipalities across the global
south implement even half of the objectives and practical measures
proposed in the policy paper, it will produce an overnight revolution in local governance in those societies. A wide array of ‘cutting
edge’ urban management reforms are endorsed and promoted by
the document: for example, participatory budgeting, full information
transparency on the part of governments, quotas for women in
good governance
67
local councils because of their systematic disempowerment in most
societies, full inheritance rights for women, and so on. Indeed it is
hard to quibble with most of the proposed objectives and practical
measures.
In particular I want to lift out three of the policy positions which
provide an important set of reference points for a radical urban
agenda. First, the foregrounding of the urban poor is an important
step forward. In most cities in the world, the urban poor remain
largely voiceless, excluded from decision-making and usually the
biggest sufferers of painful urban reforms, whether in the economy,
the environment or the built environment. Also, where local democratization processes are under way, the poor often continue to be
excluded, as elites (who straddle political and economic domains)
quickly achieve dominance over nominally democratic systems for
cultural, historical and economic reasons.6 second, the strong emphasis on a comprehensive rights-based approach to development is
important because it leads one to a set of political claims that can
expose the unequal distribution of resources more clearly, which in
turn could serve as a basis for multi-pronged mobilization strategies,
including litigation. As we have seen in south Africa and India,
where there are strong legal institutions, this can produce important
gains for the poor when the state is compelled to address failures
in the realization of rights of the poor. Third, the focus on the
indivisibility of the various areas of reform is very signiicant and
important to reinforce. often reluctant states tend to window-dress
their democratization efforts with one or two symbolic measures
and leave the larger functioning of their economies unreformed.
The approach of the policy paper makes it clear that such attempts
at policy sophistry are wrong and unacceptable. Finally, the attempt
to give concrete expression in terms of practical policy/institutional
measures is really valuable for urban coalitions that seek to advance
urban transformation through multi-pronged reform campaigns.
However, the policy paper also suffers from a number of serious
weaknesses, which may be unavoidable due to the fact that it is a
UN document and must by deinition ind a language and common
denominator, or, rather, sophisticated implicitness, that is accommodating of the diverse interests of member countries. Nevertheless,
68
city futures
given the inluence and mandate of the UN it is equally important to
point out the consequences of issues left unsaid or glossed over. The
biggest problem with the paper is that it leaves power unexplained
and therefore unexposed. There is no explicit line drawn between the
conditions the document seeks to remedy and the causal drivers of
those conditions. In particular, there is no explanation of why urban
exclusion, inequality and systematic dispossession are by and large the
norm in most cities of the global south, and, more importantly, of
how these conditions persist, often get worse, despite public policies
that are nominally pro-poor. This is particularly important because
modern forms of rule by postcolonial states rely on justiications (or
public discourses) for their actions that may be progressive at the
level of formal rhetoric but deeply unjust in terms of the systematic
and routine exploitation of the urban poor. such governing discourses
allow the state not only to tolerate but also effectively to facilitate
the exploitation of the poor, by failing to regulate elite and privatesector actions effectively. This insidious form of modern rule7 is one
of the most important aspects of urban governance that requires
direct engagement if we are to advance the principles promoted by
the UN–Habitat concept paper on urban governance.
Another major problem with the concept paper is that it projects
too homogenous and uncomplicated a view of the urban poor, as if
they are a single category. For instance, when the document argues
that ‘the ability of the urban poor to inluence local decision-making
greatly determines the “pro-poorness” of local strategic planning’,8 it
obscures the fact that if one does not disaggregate the urban poor in
terms of locality, economic positioning, religious and ethnic identity,
generation, political sympathies, and so forth, one can design and
propagate very bad participatory processes and institutions. In most
cities of the global south social life and identities comprised a myriad
complex issure lines and ever-changing moods. Also, poor sectors are
marked by a variety of hierarchies and lines of internal exclusion and
domination, which can produce ‘winners’ and ‘losers’, ‘insiders’ and
‘outsiders’, among the poor. effective governance processes aimed
at transforming unequal power relations must be highly sensitive to
these dynamics and refrain from constructing the large numbers of
urban poor as in any way homogenous or singular.
good governance
69
My last major problem with the concept paper is that it relies
heavily on a consensus-based model of urban politics. This is explicitly
asserted in the idea that stakeholder forums that bring together the
various actors in the city are best placed to ‘agree on a broad-based,
mission statement and long-term vision for the city, using tools such
as strategic planning’. The assumption is that deliberative democratic
forums are most likely to facilitate an explicit process of surfacing differences in the city, and through carefully guided processes
arrive at agreements on how best to move forward. These assumptions were directly informed by the UN’s extensive experimentation
and experience with City Consultation processes through the Urban
Management Programme (UMP) and the UNeP City Consultations
which have been running since the late 1980s. I will briely focus on
the UMP experience because it was more directly inluential in shaping
the content of the Urban Governance Concept Paper under review.
Initially, when it was founded in 1986, UMP simply represented an
inter-agency attempt to pool resources and intelligence in various
aspects of urban management. This evolved into a focus on ‘City
and Country Consultations, which [brought] together national and
local authorities, the private sector, community representatives, and
other stakeholders within a country to discuss speciic problems’ 9
related to various urban management themes. Later on, after 1996,
this was further deepened under the ‘Participatory Urban Governance’
theme of UMP. In 1999 I carried out a conceptual review of UMP’s
experiences to distil policy guidelines on advancing participatory
urban governance systems and cultures, which took me to the four
regions in the World where UMP was anchored (Latin America, the
Middle east, south Asia and sub-saharan Africa).10 From this review
it was clear that stakeholder-based city consultations have become
the dominant policy consensus as the more effective mechanism to
achieve agreement at city level on the key priorities facing the city, but
also to develop so-called action plans that guaranteed that agreements
were acted on, by local authorities in particular. This was regarded as
the most effective way of achieving participatory democratic cultures
and outcomes.
Interestingly, the focus on stakeholder-based, dialogical11 processes
mirrored a trend in Northern cities, where strategic planning became
70
city futures
the buzzword from the early 1990s onwards, inding its most celebrated expression in the example of the renewal of barcelona. on
the back of that experience and many others around the world, Jorge
borja and Manuel Castells offered the following deinition of urban
strategic planning:
strategic planning is a way of directing change based on participatory
analysis of a situation and its possible evolution and on drawing up of an
investment strategy for the scarce resources available at critical points.
The diagnosis takes into consideration the settings (globalization),
the territory (its various dimensions) and government (or system of
public agents). special consideration is given to dynamics under way,
social demands, critical points, obstacles and bottlenecks and potential.
The diagnosis is used to determine the foreseeable situation, possible
scenarios and desirable situation, which is taken as the starting point
for laying down projects to attain it.12
strategic urban planning rests irmly on the foundation of
a consensus-based model of urban politics. It is so pervasive and
compelling that an entire programme comprising all the big urban
development players – the World bank, UNdP, UN–Habitat, key
multilateral donors, and so on – has been established, called Cities
Alliance. Their mandate is ‘scaling up successful approaches to urban
poverty reduction.… by promoting the positive impacts of urbanisation, the Alliance supports learning among cities of all sizes, and
also among cities, governments, international development agencies
and inancial institutions.’13 Given their level of resources, reach and
inluence, especially vis-à-vis the Global Good Governance campaign
of UN–Habitat, I will devote the second half of the chapter to their
conception of urban governance through city development strategies
– that is, forms of strategic urban planning. Through this discussion
I will elaborate my critique of the consensus-based model of urban
politics.
City Development Strategy
City development strategy (Cds) emerged to prominence in 2000
as one of four building blocks of the World bank’s new urban and
local government policy framework. In this policy framework the
following conceptual understanding was put forward to explain what
good governance
71
a Cds entails and the link with the World bank’s role in supporting
urban development. Cities in Transition explains that a Cds is
a strategy that relects a broadly shared understanding of the city’s
socio-economic structure, constraints, and prospects (the analytical
assessment) and a shared vision of goals, priorities, and requirements (the
strategic plan of action). This city development strategy is both a process
and a product that identify ways of creating the conditions for urban
sustainability along the dimensions of livability, competitiveness, good
management and governance, and bankability. … each city development strategy exercise would be unique, but all would generally involve
three broad phases. A irst, ‘scoping out’ phase would provide a quick
assessment of the readiness of the city, the chief concerns of its oficials,
and the industrial, commercial, and banking interests. These indings
would form the basis for a second, more in-depth analysis of the local
economic structure and trends, the potential obstacles – institutional,
inancial, environmental, and social – and the strategic options. A third
phase would focus on outside assistance, particularly on how the bank
and other agencies could help the city achieve its goals.14
Through a partnership between the World bank, UN–Habitat and
bilateral donors involved in urban development, a new vehicle was
created in 1998 to drive two ‘action areas: citywide slum upgrading,
and the formulation of City development strategies. These activities
provide support to local capacity to implement the Habitat Agenda
and directly attack urban poverty.’15 In this publication of Cities
Alliance, they deine Cds in a somewhat different tenor to the
World bank:
A City development strategy is an action-plan for equitable growth in
cities, developed and sustained through participation, to improve the
quality of life for all citizens. The goals of a City development strategy
include a collective city vision and action plan aimed at improving
urban governance and management, increasing investment to expand
employment and services, and systematic and sustained reductions in
urban poverty. Achieving this overall goal will occur through a wide
variety of approaches in different cities around the world, with local
and national conditions determining both the chosen approach and
the inal outcomes.16
It is immediately apparent how the Cities Alliance approach seeks
to strike a different chord to the World bank’s blatant primary
72
city futures
concern with using Cdss to enhance economic performance and
bankability. The Cities Alliance approach foregrounds a concern
with poverty reduction and a more inclusive sense of participation compared to the bank’s focus on ‘the chief concerns of its
[local government] oficials, and the industrial, commercial, and
banking interests’. However, since the irst exposition on Cds by
Cities Alliance a much clearer and comprehensive approach was
unveiled in 2006 with the publication of Guide to City Development
Strategies: Improving Urban Performance.17 Given that Cities Alliance is
involved in around 160 cities in the global south with Cds processes,
propagating and pursuing the approach of the 2006 document, it is
of great relevance to spend some time reviewing its perspective and
underlying conceptual assumptions.
The central message of the Guide to City Development Strategies is
that it is incumbent on all cities to become much more proactive
in shaping and directing the future growth and development of
their territories. Proactiveness involves: the formulation of a bold
but realistic and shared vision for the city; agreement on a limited
number of strategic thrusts or priority areas that will be pursued to
work systematically towards the vision; and the drafting of an action
plan that sets out how, practically, each strategic thrust will be implemented in terms of actors involved, costs and time frames. Getting
to a position where Cds forums can identify the right strategic
priorities and appropriate responses requires developing a rigorous
and up-to-date assessment of the strengths, weaknesses, opportunities
and threats (sWoT) that confront the city using a combination of
empirical trends data (inclusive of forecasting models) and qualitative
information about the ‘perceptions’ of key actors in the city who are
important ‘mood shapers’. The data gathered are iltered through a
stakeholder forum comprising diverse actors in the city:
local government (the mayor), the knowledge community (a leading
academic in a related policy ield), large-scale domestic business (normally the Ceo or manager of a leading, fast growing cluster anchor
irm), the informal business community (such as the head of the street
traders’ association or taxi association), the foreign business community (the manager of one of the leading multinationals anchoring a
cluster), public health and the environment, and labour (or workers’
association).18
good governance
73
Critically, one of the governance issues that must be understood is that
the Cds is the product of a forum that exceeds local government, and
its vision, strategies and action plans pertain to all the stakeholders
involved. It is therefore not a tool that sets out the role and actions
of local government but rather one that seeks to complement, inform
and guide the administrative and urban management institutional
mechanisms of local government such as spatial plans, annualized
strategic plans, sectoral plans for transport, education, health and so
forth. This is an important issue, to which I will return later.
The underlying policy idea is that in a highly competitive and
increasingly integrated global economy it is vital for all cities to adopt
a razor-sharp strategy about how best to position their territory in that
context in order to minimize negative impacts, anticipate potential
shocks, and exploit comparative and competitive potential. Given the
nature of urban governments in most parts of the developing world,
marked by ineficient and overly bureaucratic structures with limited
resources and powers, the idea of a deliberate, proactive strategy is a
far-reaching proposition. Furthermore, given that democratic cultures
and institutions are not very well developed or effective, the core idea
of a Cds being a co-created process and product is also signiicant.
Lastly, the insistence that the strategy must explicitly address the
imperatives of poverty reduction and environmental health represents
a signiicant challenge for most local governments, which tend to
prioritize the needs of elites and middle classes, who are perceived
to be the main drivers of local wealth and prosperity – that is, the
tax base of local government. The most recent exposition on Cds by
Cities Alliance represents an important policy shift as strategic planning methodologies are combined with a pro-poor discourse, linked
to environmental concerns, and underpinned by the imperatives of
achieving sustained economic growth in a globalizing economy.
Looking back to the irst expositions on Cds in the late 1990s
and the more recent work available on the Cities Alliance website,
it is apparent that an ideal-type Cds process rests on the following
three assumptions, among others:
• A shared vision of the future is deinable through deliberation
and negotiation between various, preferably all, stakeholders and
74
city futures
such a ‘consensus vision’ can serve as a basis to inform choices
about trade-offs, alignment and investment of scarce public and
private resources.
• A well-structured process (inclusive and rigorous) of dialogue
will lead to an outcome that is the sum total of the best possible
‘rational consensus’ about the nature of problems and what needs
to be done to address them.
• The diverse and wide-ranging challenges facing the city are knowable, intelligible and can be broken down into discrete parcels of
knowledge to inform targeted interventions or interventions.
I will now engage in a closer reading of the Guide to City Development
Strategies document because it relects the core of the contemporary
‘progressive’ mainstream consensus about how to address simultaneously growth, poverty reduction, environmental health and political
inclusion. Put differently, the Cds approach is regarded as the surest
route to the realization of the normative principles and development
ideals of the good urban governance agenda discussed earlier in the
chapter. More importantly, Cdss are spreading like wildire across
cities in the global south and therefore represent a critical site of
contestation about how to organize democratic engagement and
policy debate about the deep challenges associated with rapid and
differential urbanization. Given the vast scope of the Guide to City
Development Strateg y, I will explore three central issues: the potential
and problems of dialogical forums, which hold the integrity of Cds;
the conception of drivers of economic performance in terms of
inclusivity/exclusivity; and the prospects of a holistic and balanced
developmental outcome if the model is adopted. Given the overall
focus of this chapter, I devote most of the following discussion to
the irst of these three issues.
Dialogical forums and democratic quality
The widespread assumption in most urban governance models at
the moment is that participatory processes are a prerequisite for
more legitimate and relevant policy processes and outcomes. This
position inds expression in the idea of a Cds forum in the Guide
document. The role of the Cds Forum is principally to deine the
vision, process the data that arise from the sWoT analysis, and
good governance
75
come to an agreement on the strategic priorities that arise from such
an analysis. The Guide document also provides a series of guiding
questions on ive thematic areas that will invariably arise in such a
strategic review processes: ‘Livelihood, such as job creation, business development, and sources of household income; environmental
sustainability and energy eficiency of the city and the quality of
its service delivery; spatial form and its infrastructure; Financial
resources; and, Governance.’19
Two issues are immediately important from a participatory democratic point of view: the composition of this group and the inluence
of their decisions on the daily workings of local government, which
is subjected to more rigorous democratic oversight instruments compared to corporatist forums. 20 It is important to recall that a Cds
is not meant to be a local government plan or strategy but rather
a co-crafted and co-owned strategy that sits between local government, the business community, including representatives of informal
trading associations, civil society organizations and academia. The
imperative is to achieve consensus and buy-in across the key sectors
and issures of the city in order to focus energies and achieve the
beneits that potentially arise from joint action. Consensus also helps
to eliminate unnecessary ineficiencies and can lead to joint action
to remove obstacles to growth, economic inclusion, and so forth.
However, in the Guide document there is an overriding pragmatism
to make sure that the Cds process is as quick as possible to avoid a
loss of momentum and interest. Thus, it envisages a relatively small
Cds stakeholder Forum on the assumption that the participants
have good linkages back to their constituencies and come into the
process with strong mandates and/or a clear perspective on what
the views of their stakeholder groups are. This is how the document
envisions the scope and form of participation:
It is expected that each member of the stakeholder committee will be
truly representative of a large network of the people of the city and
relects their concerns. If the group is larger than 10, it is too large and
will tend to be ineffective in dealmaking, as well as being too unwieldy
to convene. The Cds process is essentially based on collaborative planning; extensive literature on collaborative planning indicates the need
for small-group strategic development, with carefully chosen members
76
city futures
who truly relect their constituencies and can speak and bargain on
behalf of these constituencies. 21
The obvious question that arises is: who determines who gets ‘carefully chosen’ and makes the judgement call that the chosen indeed
‘truly relect their constituencies’? Also, many more fundamental
questions are left unaddressed. For example, if this burst of work is
not subjected to the normal, even if highly unsatisfactory, checks and
balances of democratic systems within local government, how much
inluence is it allowed to have over the budgetary allocations of the
municipality, which arguably is subject to the oversight mechanisms
of a representative democratic system? This is not a trivial question
because if one considers the vast array of infrastructure, economic,
settlement and spatial issues prioritized through the Cds process, it is
clear that if the Cds is to be successful, it will essentially colonize and
direct public expenditure that sits in municipal, provincial/regional
and national budgets that deal with key infrastructures of the urban
built environment. In light of this, and the normative principles
embedded in the good governance campaign of UN–Habitat campaign discussed earlier, there is potential slippage here that can do
great harm to the agenda of participatory governance.
To underscore this critique I want to turn briely to the very literature on ‘collaborative planning’ that the Guide purports to take as its
inspiration and guidance. Through this literature it becomes apparent
that the democratic benchmark for multi-stakeholder deliberation is
rather higher than intimated by Cities Alliance. The rise of strategic
planning, initially mainly in Northern cities, runs in tandem with the
theoretical discourse on collaborative planning. It is in the context of
institutionalizing strategic planning that stakeholder-based dialogical
forums have come to the fore. As mentioned earlier, for Jorge borja
and Manuel Castells strategic planning can only be successful if it
involves a wide spectrum of stakeholders from various backgrounds
in the city: ‘strategic planning is a way of directing change based
on a participatory analysis of a situation and its possible evolution’, and further achieves beyond everything else ‘the dissemination
of strategic thought, the process being more important than the
results themselves’. Crucially, the ‘participation of the public and
private agents is an indispensable condition of strategic planning and
good governance
77
distinguishes it from other forms of planning’. 22 This has obviously
been taken up by the mainstream consensus embodied in the policy
frameworks of Cities Alliance and UN–Habitat. However, it is the
communicative planning school of thought (and their critics) that
have gone furthest in theorizing the political implications of this
approach to urban planning and its reliance on stakeholder-based
participation mechanisms.
According to the communicative planning school of thought,
dialogical processes are effectively structured mechanisms to surface
and confront the ‘dilemmas as regards co-existence in shared spaces’. 23
The assumption is that the city is composed of a rich diversity of
social actors (with diverse interests and divergent senses of place),
rooted in multiple and disjunctive territories, with often divergent
claims. This diversity, along with the multiplicity of exogenous and
endogenous forces that impinge on urban development, produces a
profoundly complex array of challenges. Therefore, for Patsy Healey,
this approach rests on
a dynamic relational view of urban life. Its focus is on relations and
processes, not objects. It emphasizes dynamics not statics, and the
complex interactions between local continuities and ‘social capital’
and the innovative potential. It ‘sees’ multiple relations transecting
the space of the city, each ‘driven’ and ‘shaped’ by different forces,
interacting with each other in different ways, bypassing, conlicting,
coordinating in complex trajectories. It recognizes that these social
relationships, although shaped by powerful forces, often outside the
space of a particular urban areas, are actively socially constructed. In
the social processes of deining meanings and identities and in the
routine ways of living in the city, people make the multiple times and
places, its differentiations, cohesions and exclusions, and its power
dynamics. 24
It is important to remember that this dynamic, shifting and complex
reality of cities is much more intense in the global south because
of the coexistence of formal and informal cities at scales that dwarf
the challenges of Northern cities, as demonstrated in Chapter 2. In
view of this constitutive ‘multiplexity’, as Healey prefers to call it,
the following rationale underpins the need for dialogical governance
and planning mechanisms. by deinition such complexity in the city
can only be addressed through synectics – an approach to solving
78
city futures
problems based on creative thinking of a group from different areas
of expertise and knowledge. Therefore, it follows that in order to
forge sustainable economic, political and social ecologies for cities it
is essential that these diverse social actors confront each other with
their divergent claims in order to arrive at dificult, politically situated,
decisions about whose claims will be addressed, in what sequence
and with what resources. since assent and compliance depend on
the legitimacy and inclusivity of the process, it is essential that as
many stakeholders as possible participate in such dialogical forums.
Further on, communicative theorists assert that it is not impossible
to arrive at legitimate, contextually situated agreements without some
measure of shared values, which ideally can be expressed through
a shared vision about the future. 25 However, in a context of deep
social cleavages and structural inequalities it is not that easy to
arrive at shared values, or to come to an agreement that is real
and broad enough to incorporate the interests of both the urban
elites and the urban poor, ‘encroachers’ and ‘informals’, especially
since these categories are shot through with very profound lines of
differentiation and even inequality. Clearly, the idea that one can
satisfy the requirements of meaningful consensus-building forums
through the methodology proposed by Cities Alliance is dificult
to sustain. However, to illustrate properly the political (legitimacy)
problems with the methodological approach in democratic terms, it
is instructive to explore how the challenge of economic growth and
inclusion is handled in the Cds framework.
Drivers of economic performance
The basic argument of the Guide is that cities must pay a lot more
explicit attention to how they are going to grow their economies
‘sustainably’ and achieve a much higher degree of economic inclusion as growth takes off. The latter question is approached through
the lens of livelihoods and leads to a policy emphasis on the poor
health, education and limited livelihood options of the urban poor.
Growth is tied to competitiveness, which in turn is linked to ‘business
climate’. one of the major instruments to drive both equity concerns
and economic growth is of course infrastructure investment. The
Guide asserts that:
good governance
79
Infrastructure assessment and investment planning are complex and
require careful attention in Cds processes. often, tradeoffs are
required (and synergies may exist) between equity objectives (providing
basic services to all members of urban society at affordable rates) and
economic objectives, which may be facilitated by expressways, ports,
airports, and so on. 26
This assertion demonstrates the point made earlier that the strategies that arise from the Cds Forum are meant to impact on public
expenditure in a major way, but it also hints at the trade-offs that must
be made in deciding how to ensure economic competitiveness. such
an analysis is inherently ideological and politically contested because
it is not clear how to pursue a growth path within the parameters of
the neoliberal global economic order and realize poverty-reduction
objectives at the same time; a profound dilemma that is effectively
glossed over in the Guide to City Development Strategies document.
For example, in Splintering Urbanism the evidence is overwhelming that network infrastructures – transport, telecommunications,
energy, water and streets – privileged in the current global economic
climate demand of cities the prioritizing of the connectivity systems
of high-end service and manufacturing sectors, as well as the security and mobility needs of the middle class and elites.27 Thus, large
chunks of capital investment go into expressways, ports, airports,
telecommunications networks, and the like, squeezing out investment
in more mundane infrastructure that could dramatically improve the
quality of life of the urban poor disconnected from basic services or
underinvested health and education systems. This sense of economic
infrastructure prioritization is simply reinforced when the Guide suggests that cities need to ‘benchmark’ themselves against comparable,
competitor and aspirational cities – that is, cities in the race to take
the lead on satisfying the ferocious appetites of particular economic
sectors which tend to skew the investment priorities of cities away
from the poor. The analysis of UN–Habitat in its 2001 Global Report on
Human Settlements speaks most directly to this issue in their discussion
of the uneven distribution of the beneits and costs of globalization.
The UN–Habitat report 28 explains how a ‘hyperglobalist’ view of
globalization has come to dominate policy discourses, which leads
to a particular way of thinking about the role of cities:
80
city futures
Those holding this view … tend to believe that the increasing globalization of the economy is inevitable. They also consider globalization as
beneicial and that it will eventually have advantages all over the world
… In this scenario, the nation state is seen as losing its role in a world
that chiely involves interactions between transnational business and
city or regional governance. economic globalization is seen as a natural
process and city governments should ensure that its citizens derive the
maximum beneit from it. Cities should adapt their policies to conform
to the imperatives that the process demands. 29
due to the existing conditions of widespread urban poverty and
inequality, the UN–Habitat report suggests that the hyperglobalization approach to the role of city governments in mediating economic
development dynamics will further exacerbate the problem. Furthermore, the report notes, it tends to produce governance cultures within
which economic interests become decisive in decision-making with
regard to urban planning and management priorities. In this environment, city visions can be dangerous things when business-dominated
growth coalitions in the city use strategic planning processes to push
policies that will attract foreign investment. ‘The aim is to ensure that
this vision [for the future of the city] informs other policies of the
city, including the strategic land use plan, and expenditure priorities.’30
Given the simplistic, or rather apolitical, way in which the dynamics
surrounding prioritization of urban policies are discussed in the Cities
Alliance Guide document it is dificult to avoid the conclusion that
it reinforces a hyperglobalization approach to urban competitiveness
imperatives, despite the reference to balancing competitiveness with
poverty reduction and environmental health concerns. What is missing
is a more rigorous political economy assessment of the obstacles that
stand in the way of a deep, probably conlictual, strategic dialogue
between not only diverse but fundamentally opposite interests in
the city. The facile promotion of small (no more than ten), mobile,
rapid deliberation forums to deine and drive a Cds is a recipe for
political manipulation by the powerful, which could, if successful,
fundamentally skew the priorities of municipalities, which would then
take their cue for their infrastructure budgets from the vision and
strategic argument of the Cds forum. When the ideas of ‘small’ and
‘rapid’ gets combined with equally simplistic notions that ‘tradeoffs,
as well as synergies, exist between equity objectives (providing basic
good governance
81
services to all members of society at affordable rates) and economic
objectives (which may be facilitated by expressways, ports, airports
and the like)’,31 the likelihood of transformative Cds outcomes (in
the form promoted by Cities Alliance) becomes far-fetched.
Prospects of holistic development outcomes
It is irrefutable that the Guide to City Development Strategies strives to
help city governments to use strategic planning tools and dialogical
forums to formulate tailor-made strategies that will effectively deine
and deliberate the trade-offs that need to be made in the short and
medium term regarding investment decisions and service standards
(and prices) to achieve a locally deined vision. What the preceding
discussion suggests is that the methodology proposed by the Cds
is deeply lawed because of the lack of an explicit treatment of the
power dynamics that underpin city politics and ultimately structure
governance relations. For instance, local governments are treated in
the document almost as blank institutions that can simply change
course and adopt a new approach to urban planning, management
and co-governance, as if their existing functioning is not steeped in
profound historical, cultural and economic systems which shape an
incentive architecture that serves to reproduce the system. Tradeoffs between equity and competitiveness are proposed as if they are
genuine and not predeined by a powerful set of discourses about
becoming ‘modern’, ‘world class’, ‘globally connected’; discourses
that make certain interests and groups appear rational or irrational,
reasonable or radical, and so forth. discursive terrains in cities make
it possible for particular kinds of voices and interest groups to be
seen and recognized (as I will demonstrate more clearly in the next
chapter) and therefore considered acceptable to participate in deliberations about priorities and the terms of negotiation that underpin
so-called trade-offs.
To illustrate the dificulty of conducting ‘real’, ‘hard’ and largely
conlictual debate on the city, it is useful to diagrammatize the different categories of decisions that need to be made in the course of
urban planning and management processes. Figure 4.1 differentiates
between three categories of public investment: household, economic
and public. Household infrastructure refers to basic services such as
82
city futures
Municipal mandate
Public focus
Household focus
�
services to address
basic needs
Urban system
maintenance
Asset
maintenance
Public investment
focus
Urban system
transformation
economic infrastructure
and boosterism projects
Market focus
Partnership
dependent
FIGURE 4.1
Municipal priorities and trade-offs32
water, waste, sanitation and electricity, which come either bundled
with low-cost housing or in situ upgrading programmes. economic
infrastructure refers primarily to network infrastructures such as
transport, telecommunications, energy, water and streets, which are
built to enhance the economic desirability and functionality of the
city. The form, quality and extensiveness of these infrastructures are
driven by global expectations of transnational businesses that are
lured to invest in particular city regions. Lastly, public infrastructure
includes: public transport, public spaces, urban accessibility through
equitable land markets, public health, environment, social–cultural
facilities to pursue and enhance identity, and so forth. Furthermore,
the existing built infrastructures require ongoing maintenance and
renewal, which can be deined as a further pole in the matrix of
prioritization. At any point in time in the (political) life of city
good governance
83
governance, trade-offs are made in relation to the size of the budget
of the municipality and what is deemed to be politically important.
In the current global climate, the tendency is emphatically to
invest heavily in the economic attractiveness of cities, which implies
large-scale investment in economic infrastructure and a serious of
boosterism projects such as sports stadiums, art galleries (such as
the Guggenheim Musuem in bilbao), signature architectural buildings, all of which undoubtedly crowd out and undermine pro-poor
spending and investment in public infrastructures that serve everyone
in the city. The interests that maintain this conception of political
pragmatism are pervasive and deeply entrenched and unlikely to be
dislodged by the facile conception of trade-offs embodied in the Cds
Guide of Cities Alliance. This is a large claim on my part, which is
why the next chapter is devoted to a detailed conceptual elaboration
of how to think about urban politics and radical transformation.
5
Reconceptualizing the political
in cities
Without transgression, without the red boundary, there is no danger,
no risk, no frisson, no experiment, no discovery and no creativity.
Without extending some hidden or visible frontier of the possible,
without disturbing something of the incomplete order of things
there is no challenge, no pleasure, and certainly no joy.1
Limitations are … conditions of possibility. However, to accept
given limitations as that which determines all that is possible would
make being unbearably heavy. Limits are truly enabling when, having
given something its form, … the form engages with its own limits
to fashion its own style. Foucault’s notion of transgression signiies
work on enabling limits. 2
In light of my repeated criticism of mainstream policies and argument that the true nature of differential power inequalities in cities
is under-speciied and under-theorized, it is important to lay bare
the reasons for my critique and what an alternative approach could
look like. In this chapter I adopt a more conceptual tone to clarify
the theoretical strands that feed into an embracing of radical democracy as the most useful and productive approach to urban politics,
which always boil down to complex and profound trade-offs between
competing priorities, as argued in the previous chapter. Furthermore,
if progressive actors in cities are to position themselves not only
to critique but also present alternative ways of thinking about and
reconceptualizing the political
85
intervening in cities, it is imperative that they do so with a razor-sharp
perspective on political landscapes and opportunities. In this sense,
this central chapter is a vital foundation stone for the propositional
and policy-oriented chapters that follow, particularly Chapters 7
and 8. This chapter starts off with a distillation of seven theoretical
premisses that inform the theoretical framework for urban politics
which I introduced at the outset. The remainder of the chapters offer
a more detailed discussion of that framework, deined as a relational
model of urban politics. The informing sensibility of this chapter is
the evocative idea of transgression at the edge of mainstream consensus in order to subvert and remould new and more empowering
agreements on sustainable forms of city building.
Conceptual premisses
The conceptual model that follows draws on a variety of recent
theorizations in urban studies, political science, policy studies, urban
planning and development studies. The common denominator is
a concern with culture as constitutive of the social, alongside the
economic and political. With the cultural turn in urban theory, and
social theory more broadly, comes an awareness that language, discourse and symbolic meanings are central to the incessant processes
of identity construction and the realm of agency in the spaces of the
everyday. Conceptually, the challenge is to adopt an approach that
recognizes the structuring effect of the economy, bureaucracy and
discursive diagrams of power without relinquishing an appreciation
of agency.3 The following conceptual reference points fall squarely
within this tradition of theorization and serve as a foundation for
the alternative approach to urban politics that I propose in the next
section. due to space constraints it is unavoidably abbreviated and
at best suggestive.
1. Urban politics must be imagined, practised and institutionalized on
an ethical basis. Ideally, this is a human-rights-based framework
that legally guarantees access to opportunities to lourish as a
creative individual ensconced in multiple communities of afinity,
which may or may not be in close proximity.4 For example, in
south Africa, a strong basis for such an approach exists due to
86
city futures
the constitutional entrenchment of all human rights – political,
civil and socio-economic – and it is of course also endorsed in
the good urban governance campaign of UN–Habitat. It is vital
to maximize this political potential in all spheres of citizenship
and political practice.
2. democracy is a necessary precondition for a vibrant political
space that allows for regulated contestation of perspectives that
are invariably imbued with particular interests. Formal liberal
democratic norms and institutional procedures that rest on representative democratic institutions and the rule of law are inadequate
to address the structurally embedded relations and systems of
inequality that characterize capitalist modernity.5 More is needed.
In this regard, the ideas of scholars who espouse the beneits
of radical democracy are the most convincing and promising.6
More on the institutional expressions of radical democracy will
be explored below.
3. The institutional design and functioning dimensions of urban
politics are crucial for the effectiveness and democratic content
of political practices. Institutions are not merely containers of
political intent, but rather mediate in a fundamental sense how
interactions between diverse political actors (and agendas) are
structured and channelled.7 This awareness brings into view the
importance of organizational dynamics and cultures of both state
and non-state political actors, but also the importance of translating new political agreements into ‘the routine practices of frontline
oficials [in government] if they are to make real differences to
people’s life chances and to give real respect to people’s individual
life circumstances’.8 In many ways, the conceptual model put
forward in this chapter adds up to an attempt to illuminate the
institutional interdependencies between various political domains
in the city.
4. The conceptual distinctions between ‘government’, ‘governmentality’ and ‘governance’ are useful to understand and recast the
potential and limitations of the local state, especially in an era of
neoliberal dominance. In my usage, ‘government’ refers in practical
terms to the structures, institutions and organizations of the state
that regulate social practices.9 ‘Governmentality’ is a Foucauldian
reconceptualizing the political
87
concept which refers to ‘the complex array of techniques – programs, procedures, strategies and tactics – employed by both
non-state administrative agencies and state institutions to shape
conduct of individuals and populations’.10 Governance denotes
the relationality of power as it lows through networks between
the state and institutional actors in the market and civil society.
However, ‘governance is not a homogenous agent, but a morass
of complex networks and arenas within which power dynamics
are expressed and deployed’.11 The purpose of this alternative
conceptual model is to bring these multiple networks and arenas
of urban governance into view so that more ine-grained critical
research can be conducted. I also hope to provoke investigations
into practicable visions about radical politics that can produce
more socially just and environmentally conscious outcomes – that
is, political discourses that emerge from practical struggles to test
and transcend the discursive limits of governmentality practices
of the state.
5. The full measure of the urban political terrain can only be apprehended via an appreciation of spatiality. Cities can be understood
spatially in terms of densities, proximities, intensities and their
effects. Furthermore, the particular form of the spatial coniguration that arises in a city shapes the horizons of possibility.12 If the
horizon is extremely limited, spatial coniguration continues to
produce segregation, fragmentation and exclusion. Alternatively, if
the horizons are more open, we are more inclined to use the rich
multiplicity of spatial practices to unleash new ways of interaction
and engagement. However, if the multiple spatialities of the city are
repressed or erased (in oficial texts and regulations), it is virtually
impossible to construct a radical democratic ‘cosmopolis’, in the
parlance of radical planner Leonie sandercock. In other words,
recognition of the inherently heterogeneous time-spaces of the
city feeds into political questions about how the city is imagined
and represented. At its core, all urban struggles are in one sense
or another about the politics of recognition and determination of
identity.
6. This ‘multiplex’ perspective of the city rests irmly on a nonessentialist conception of identity and community. kian Tajbakhsh
88
city futures
explains that ‘identities are not expressive of a deep “essentialist”
core, but are best seen as contingent and articulated through
interdependent and overdetermined practices structured by both
conscious intention and unconscious desire.’ In other words, ‘complexity is the a piori feature of social identity’.13 Invariably the same
applies to the notion of ‘community’. Frances Cleaver (among
many others) has successfully demonstrated how ‘“community”
in participatory approaches to development is often seen as a
“natural” social entity characterized by solidaristic relations.’14 she
then goes on to critique this approach systematically, by pointing
out the absence of ‘coterminosity between natural (resource),
social and administrative boundaries’.15 Furthermore, she points
out how processes of conlict, negotiation, inclusion and exclusion
have been poorly analysed in the development literature, with a
tendency to romanticize community relations. This has arguably
become worse with the rise of social capital literature during the
past decade. The same argument can then be extended to the
notion of the ‘urban poor’, which is often used interchangeably
with ‘community’. earlier I highlighted why homogenizing the
urban poor is dangerous and conceptually problematic.
7. Finally, it is important to acknowledge that political contestation
unfolds around speciic, discursively constructed, points of crisis
and imperatives to reproduce the political economic system. What
is regarded as a crisis and inds its way into the public domain
via the media is an important area of contestation. representative
democracy, collective and insurgent practices of poor classes,
and mundane practices to realize development projects rely on
the public recognition of certain issues as valid political problems. Usually this is relected in the discourses that circulate in
(popular) media via newspapers, radio, television and, increasingly,
cyberspace. More and more, successful political mobilization of
interests relies on capacity to set the agenda and frame the issues
of the day. This point brings me back to my irst assertion about
the importance of an ethical horizon in political engagement.
It seems clear that the potentiality of a rights-based discourse
can only be realized through practical struggles that translate
everyday violations into claims, demands, remedies and solutions
reconceptualizing the political
89
that ind recognition and expression in the public domain. In
other words, politics is mainly about substantive content, but is
also about performance. The question is, how does one reimagine
political agency at a subjective and collective level in ways that
can transcend governmentality through performative practices in
all domains of political action? Hopefully, the conceptual model
elaborated in the next section will serve as a suitable starting point
to answering this question.
Sketches of a conceptual model of urban politics
This section is the heart of the chapter and the book. Here the aim
is to capture the multiple, interconnected and overlapping spaces
of political practices in the city. As proposed in Chapter 1, in conceptual terms it is possible to delineate at least ive domains of
rights-based
democratic framework
‘top-down’
Neo-corporatist
stakeholder forums
at city scale (Cds
Forum) and/or
lower levels
representative
political forums
and participatory
mechanisms
Political sphere
democratization
development
practice at
neighbourhood
scale
Public sphere
social
mobilization
through direct
action
interfaces
‘bottom-up’
FIGURE 5.1
symbolic politics
through discursive
action
domains of political engagement in the relational city
90
city futures
political engagement between the state, the private sector and civil
society at various scales, ranging from the global and national to the
local: (1) representative political forums and associated participatory
mechanisms; (2) neo-corporatist political forums such as the ones that
develop city development strategies, which comprise representative
organizations, typically the government, the private sector, trade
unions and community-based organizations; (3) direct action or mobilization against state policies or to advance speciic political demands;
(4) the politics of development practice, especially at the grassroots;
and (5) symbolic political contestation as expressed through discursive
contestation in the public sphere. Figure 5.1 depicts these ive political
domains in addition to distinctions between the political and public
spheres that are continuously (re)constructed through engagement in
each of these ive spheres and their interfaces.
The value of this exercise is that it allows one to rethink political
practice from multiple angles. Moreover, it opens up new ground for
imagining more creative progressive political strategies to undermine
and subvert the oppressive functioning of dominant interests in the
city. The model rests heavily on Foucault’s understanding of power
and therefore locates discursive and symbolic dimensions of political
practice as central to re-reading political institutions and agency.16 I
will briely elaborate each domain in terms of key deining features,
types of political practices, inter-connections with other domains
and possible pitfalls.
Domain one: representative politics
Political representation refers to the formal political system that
characterizes national, provincial/regional and municipal government. At all levels, the main avenue of political participation in this
process is through political parties that are elected. The democratic
effectiveness of electoral systems depends in large measure on the
democratic nature of the respective political parties along with their
rootedness in their constituencies.17 It also depends on the quality
and maturity of the institutional rules and systems that structure the
functioning of political chambers, council and committee meetings,
and associated mechanisms for transparency, responsiveness and
accountability.
reconceptualizing the political
91
The policy framework in the UN–Habitat concept paper on urban
governance provides a solid foundation for participatory local governance where the full diversity and conlictual interests of the city can be
expressed. Naturally this depends on ‘political commitment’ to formulate more practical policies to create various participatory governance
mechanisms such as citizen juries, participatory budget councils,
integrated development planning forums, area-based political committees, citizen opinion surveys, participatory action research studies
to test policy preferences and options, transparency guidelines and
support systems, and so forth.18 beyond political commitment, it also
depends on the tangible accountability of the elected politicians.
The literatures on urban regimes, growth coalitions and elite pacts
demonstrate the subtle and blatant ways in which (organized) business
interests that rely on public investment frameworks and spending (for
transport, land-use zoning and preparation, environmental guidelines,
etc.), exert their inluence over the decision-making and functioning
of local government.19 If one approaches participatory instruments
with a naivety about these relations they easily become a camoulage
for what is really going on in the city. The point about participatory
local governance is to increase the democratic oversight of active
citizens, especially those whose human rights are systematically denied
due to inadequate services and lack of opportunities. However, this
is unlikely to take root unless citizens are well organized, and are
supported by municipal government to organize themselves actively
into independent and articulate voices.20 These qualiiers point to
the importance of the political values and practices of the political
parties that hold majority power in the council. even though it is
a neglected subject in the literature, it is clear that the democratic
culture – open or closed – within political parties is a vital aspect
in embedding meaningful participatory local governance.
I began with a discussion of the representative domain of political
practice because it is in this domain that an enabling climate can be
constructed for the lourishing of political agency in other domains of
social action. This is why the reforms advocated for through the Good
Urban Governance Campaign are so important but also dangerous if
left undertheorized in terms of power relations in the city. speciically, municipal government (with visionary leaders) is an important
92
city futures
precursor for the establishment of ‘neo-corporatist’ forums to undertake strategic planning regarding the future trajectory of the city. In
fact, close synergy between the municipal development policies and the
broader Cds that emerges from multi-stakeholder governance forums
is essential. However, given the built-in bias towards more organized,
well-resourced and articulate voices in multi-stakeholder forums, the
elected politicians have a vital role to play in ensuring that marginal
and poorly organized interests in the city, who should be the primary
beneiciaries of the developmental local government mandate, can also
ind their issues infused in the deliberations. There are few guarantees
that this is likely to happen, but this does not negate the conceptual
assertion. When I elaborate on autonomous agency by marginal and
poor classes and groups below it will become clearer that I locate this
conceptual assertion within a larger theoretical diagram of agonistic,
conlict-ridden contestation between various political agendas in the
city. seen from that position, it is legitimate to invoke the democratic
expectation about the ideal role of elected politicians.
There are many other dangers when it comes to the functioning
of representative politics, which underscore the danger of vesting all
hope for radical democracy in the emergence of effective representative democratic institutions. Much more is required, as the remainder
of the chapter will demonstrate.
Domain two: neo-corporatist stakeholder forums
stakeholder-based forums refer to formal deliberative institutions
that provide a regulated and predictable space for negotiation and
contestation between state, civil society and private-sector representative organizations on urban issues of (mutual) concern, even if for
different reasons. Commonly they are referred to as multi-stakeholder
forums. In their book Local and Global, Jorge borja and Manuel Castells
set out the case for the necessity of these kinds of deliberative spaces
to co-create strategic plans for the city.21 They frame their argument
against the backdrop of the impact of globalization processes on
cities. such impacts make it more important than ever that public
infrastructure investments (especially transport and communication)
are carefully made in terms of a larger strategic vision of where the
urban economy is headed. by deinition, such a vision cannot be
reconceptualizing the political
93
the fabrication of municipal planners but must arise from properly
structured processes of participation and deliberation, because it must
not only be viable but also politically embedded among the diverse
stakeholders in the city. Without legitimacy, strategic plans are bound
to run aground on the banks of political conlict and corruption.
The perspective of borja and Castells clearly operates on a shift
away from master planning to strategic planning to accommodate
the complexity of urban life. It also builds on the strong participatory thrust that propels discourses on greater decentralization and
deliberative democracy. This is an orientation that is echoed in the
literature on city development strategies by the Cities Alliance.
earlier, in relecting on the city development strategy tenets of
the Cities Alliance, I summarized the various lines of critique that
can levelled against it. However, before one becomes completely
dismissive of these arenas of political engagement it is worthwhile
to remember that the stakeholder forum mechanism was key to the
political resolution of the south African crisis of apartheid in the
early 1990s. At the dawn of the south African transition process (in
the late 1980s), a number of negotiation forums started to emerge at
a local level as white municipalities entered into negotiations to end
or circumvent rates- and service-charge boycotts. 22 These institutional
forms became somewhat paradigmatic throughout the transition
because they provided a model which allowed oppositional political
organizations to retain their relative autonomy whilst renegotiating
the terms of their relationship as the process of democratization
shifted power to the black majority and their representative organizations (former political liberation movements such as the African
National Congress, the Pan-Africanist Congress and the like). In
other words, the forums provided a guarantee against unilateral
decisions that would radically alter economic and political relations
in society. It is for this reason that many regard them as reformist
corporatist institutions that simply serve to entrench vested elite
interests by diffusing militant social action by subjugated classes. 23
should these criticisms lead us to reject the role of multi-stakeholder
forums in advancing radical democratic urban politics? I think not.
It is crucial to remain aware of the depoliticizing dangers of such
forums, along with the built-in tendency to cater for well-organized,
94
city futures
well-resourced and articulate political groups. Yet, given the complexity of urban development challenges it is imperative to build
broad-based agreement, even if provisional and continuously renewed,
about the future direction of the city. The obligations entrenched in
the UN–Habitat Agenda to progressively realize everyone’s socioeconomic rights must be the touchstone for the institutional rules
and agenda of such forums. In other words, in terms of institutional
design and functioning, provision must be made for ensuring adequate
representation of potentially marginalized groups and ensuring that
the search for consensus does not rule out the necessity of agonistic
engagement. The work of Michael Gunder and Jean Hillier, among
others, points to a series of useful principles that can be used to
ensure fair and critical deliberation, which does not preclude noninstitutionalized direct action or opting to exit. 24
However, the progressive potential of these mechanisms can only
be secured if civil society actors maintain their autonomy and actively
pursue political strategies that unfold in spheres of engagement and
communication outside of the chambers of stakeholder forums. The
leverage power of groups in forums representing the interests of the
poor and future generations will be dependent on the power of such
constituencies in the public sphere, in particular the power that comes
from direct action to shape agendas and lay claim to constitutionally
deined rights and entitlements. Furthermore, strong social organization at the grassroots potentially strengthens the accountability of
elected politicians. This relational dynamic can be harnessed to ensure
that conservative agendas that will further exploit the poor become
inconceivable for the political class. The multi-stakeholder forums can
then become discursive spaces where a more redistributive ‘consensus’
can be constructed and consolidated. The fact is that unless business
interests and the middle classes are publicly and incessantly compelled
to ascribe to the importance of redistribution, it is virtually impossible
to use local-government service provision and taxation as effective
tools to achieve greater equity in the city. Multi-stakeholder forums
can be important sites of contestation and engagement to socially
construct such political agreements. This is dependent on the social
power of the poor and other marginal groups established through
effective organization and mobilization around everyday struggles.
reconceptualizing the political
95
It is also dependent on the circulation of alternative discourses and
substantiating knowledge that demonstrates how distributive justice
can work to the beneit of all citizens in the city. As stressed earlier, it
is crucial to appreciate the relational interdependency between various
domains of political practice.
Domain three: direct action
direct action involves various forms of collective action by (disadvantaged) groups aimed at stretching the liberal democratic constitutional framework to its limit. 25 This implies that social movements
and looser, issue-speciic, social groups must claim their rights and
entitlements through non-violent social action focused on concrete
issues that shape the quality of life of their constituencies. In a sense,
the primary function of progressive direct action is to maintain political momentum for redistribution and realization of human rights,
especially socio-economic rights. of all the political practices in the
city, this type pushes most blatantly at the boundaries of the possible
(in discursive, political and juridical terms). direct action seeks to
disturb the tranquillity of ‘business as usual’, whereby local governance unfolds at arm’s length from the citizenry and politicians nestle
snugly in the bosom of elites. It potentially shakes up the middleclass lack of interest in life beyond the suburb – that is, livelihood
challenges in the slums and other spaces of marginalization. street
conlicts, clashes and destabilizations that spark off direct action are
prerequisites for political agreements to address urban inequalities.
such agreements will invariably involve attitudinal and behavioural
change among the middle classes, because they will have to fund
more aggressive redistribution and more effective government. (Not
that their inancial contributions are proportionately more signiicant
than those the poor already contribute simply to survive, despite
inadequate support from the state.)
To be sure, direct action is not about consensus. Invariably, it raises
the political temperature and solicits conlict from those who stand to
lose if demands are acceded to. From an agonistic political perspective
such conlict is necessary to combust crisis, which in turn can produce
political engagement and provisional agreements between opponents
to allow governance and management to carry on. The challenge is
96
city futures
to foster a political culture that is embracing of social mobilization
politics along with institutionally deined pressure-valves to absorb
and channel the energy unleashed by direct action. Participatory
mechanisms associated with representative political domains can be
useful mediating channels to ensure that the demands of claimants are
articulated to actual plans, agendas and budgets of local government
as requisite in terms of annual and medium-term planning processes.
similarly, task teams that undertake the work of multi-stakeholder
forums can expand their deliberations to address the claims and
issues of those on the streets. The oft-forgotten relational dynamic
of urban politics comes to the fore yet again.
In this light I am often frustrated with radical proposals for urban
politics that simply call for the poor to rise up and militantly refuse
to accept their conditions but then say nothing about what happens
when such claims are potentially acceded to, for any political gain
must be institutionalized in some form to be enduring and comprehensively adhered to. In other words, my conceptualization rejects
social mobilization for the sake of it – that is, militancy without a
purpose, without a potentially winnable demand. For example, it
remains unclear whether the recent wave of social protests in many
south African cities are merely reactive or premissed on a clear
strategy to articulate the diverse domains of political practice in
the city. Hard, ideologically pure rhetoric tends to militate against
relexive and adaptive political strategy. such rhetoric is impervious
to strategic, contingent political praxis.
Collective action through embodied public displays of protest,
celebration, deiance, or whatever, is not inherently progressive or
conservative. In my view, progressive direct action is marked by
the political philosophy and agenda of the movement and, more
importantly, the values of the actors who constitute the movement.
In many cities of the global south right-wing fundamentalist groups
are very effective at mobilizing their members to engage in public
displays of opposition and, sometimes, even hate-speech. Participation
by the poor and marginalized citizens in social movements or processes can have a profoundly empowering psychic effect, as we know
from the works and examples of steven biko, Paulo Freire, Mahatma
Gandhi, subcomandante Marcos, Frantz Fanon, Malcolm X, among
reconceptualizing the political
97
others. However, this is contingent on the democratic culture of
such organizations and the space for self-realization through experimentation and performative play. ostensibly progressive agendas do
not automatically translate into progressive interpersonal relations
between activists; nor do they translate into self-realization as part
and parcel of the larger social change desired by the movement.
What I have in mind here is a form of politics sensitive to issues
of interiority (psychic health) as well as exteriority.26 This culturally
attuned understanding of political agency is a vital part of redeining
progressive political agency in our times. surely our research of these
movements needs to be as attuned to the political strategies and
ideas as well as to the politics of self-realization. This is particularly
important in the next domain of political practice.
Domain four: grassroots development practice
so long as we conine our conception of the political to activity that
is openly declared we are driven to conclude that subordinate groups
essentially lack a political life, or that what political life they do have
is restricted to those exceptional moments of popular explosion.
To do so is to miss the immense political terrain that lies between
quiescence and revolt, and that, for better or worse, is the political
environment of the subject classes. It is to focus on the visible
coastline of politics and miss the continent that lies beyond. 27
The public heroics of social movements are usually what grab our
attention when we think about political agency in the city. However,
as the work of James scott suggests, the political terrain is much
broader and more variegated than this. I am particularly interested
in drawing attention to the everyday spaces and practices of grassroots development projects and their institutional frameworks. The
politics of development practice unfolds at the neighbourhood scale
(and beyond), where autonomous and state-dependent projects are
undertaken to improve the quality of life and livelihoods, to protect
against the vicissitudes of crime, violence and other shocks, and to
deliberate future trajectories for the community in relation to other
communities and the larger regional economic-ecological system.
In development studies there is a vast literature on the institutional
dimensions of community-based development processes, with particular
98
city futures
reference to anti-poverty programmes, which are most urgent for the
urban poor. 28 In a similar sense, one could categorize shoploor struggles to improve the quality of work and establish workplace democracy
in this category. both types of social practice involve the establishment
of practical rules and norms that can regularize interactions between
powerful interests (e.g. government departments with bundles of
resources for speciic programmes) and the various categories of poor
citizens in terms of effective ways of meeting the minimum standards
of ‘human dignity’ as espoused in national policies. In addition to
clarifying norms and standards, grassroots development practice also
involves the active construction of systematic projects to address a
variety of consumption, productive, information and political needs.
For example, savings associations, community gardens, neighbourhood
watches, public art clubs, soup kitchens, shelters for the abused, community crèches, drama societies, religious clubs, sports organizations,
primary health-care circles, and so on.
It is vital to appreciate the experiential importance of participation in
community-based associations aimed at improving the quality of life
of oneself and fellow residents. The recent work of Arjun Appadurai
on slum-dweller associations in Mumbai argues for the importance
of taking seriously ‘the capacity to aspire’ in thinking about this
issue. Appadurai develops a layered argument that development, and
especially its imagining, is deeply embedded in local cultures that
people draw on to function in a day-to-day sense. some of these
cultural resources will be consistent with dominant societal values and
norms that reproduce the acceptability of perverse inequalities. other
cultural resources may hold the germ of critique, of thinking about
alternative social conigurations that can lead to an improvement in
quality of life and sense of self. The challenge is to use the futureshaping essence of development practice to expand ‘the cultural
map of aspirations’ and in the process expand social citizenship and
especially voice. 29 It is inconceivable that such political faculties can
be cultivated outside an associational context. The argument can
be extended. social learning that arises from development projects
can socialize uninformed and unrecognized citizens into democratic
values such as accountability, transparency, (agonistic) deliberation,
inclusivity, review and majority decision-making. In this sense, it
reconceptualizing the political
99
preigures the democratic rules of the larger political game that
unfold in representative arenas. In other words, the experience of
organizational democracy in development projects can concretize the
meanings of democratic citizenship.
Furthermore, participation in development projects also enables
people to see the bits and pieces of the state and how they function
in contradictory ways at different scales. For example, those projects
which beneit from, for instance, dedicated poverty funds, learn that
the social development objectives of a national department may be
very different to the social development initiatives of local government. In the larger political game, strategic political positioning and
action depend on a differentiated understanding of the state and the
contingent opportunities for alliances, when appropriate.30 As long as
organizations of the poor fail to capitalize on the always contingent
contradictions between various arms of the state, they are unlikely
to move their agendas forward, let alone recalibrate the priorities of
the government.
Lastly, grassroots projects can be invaluable sites of experimentation with alternative ways of doing development. state bureaucracies
tend to be rigid, hierarchical and conformist institutions. Little room
is left for creativity, learning and innovation, despite incessant change
management efforts.31 In part, this is attributable to the organizational
logic of large rule-bound and driven institutions. In part, it is a
function of the need for political control and oversight over the
functioning of government. The literature on organizational change
and learning in the public sector suggests that these tendencies can
only be mitigated by powerful external pressures that either show
up the failures of government or provide compelling alternatives
that allow new discourses to come into play.32 on rare but very
important occasions, grassroots initiatives can demonstrate alternative approaches to development that can be absorbed by the state
and in theory lead to more equitable outcomes. A case in point is
the inluence of the south African Homeless People’s Federation on
the department of Housing in south Africa and the government’s
subsequent adoption of the ‘people’s housing process’ policy.33
These three instances make it clearer why grassroots development
associations are such an important aspect of the larger political
100
city futures
canvas in the city. However, it would be misleading to suggest that
it is easy to achieve these impacts because of the dangers associated with this category of organization. Many of these grassroots
organizations operate in an apolitical fashion and tend to reproduce
welfarist models of social change. such an approach delects attention from the structural underpinning of maldistribution of public
resources. These organizations are also prone to co-option because
of inancial dependency issues. This is less likely to be a problem
in cases where development projects also incorporate membership
fees/savings in the organizational methodology, but that is rare. one
insidious problem is the potential of development projects to dissipate
pent-up anger and militancy – the fuel of ‘spontaneous’ combustion
that is so essential for direct action.
In terms of the overall conceptual model proposed here, it is
important to review grassroots development practice in relation to
neo-corporatist forums and the departmental programmes carried out
by municipal government. due to the inherently tame and consensual
style of politics that one inds in this sphere, it can be anticipated
that umbrella organizations of this grassroots type are likely to
participate in multi-stakeholder deliberative forums ostensibly to
represent ‘the community’ voice. This makes such organizations of
strategic importance to social movements that may prefer to stand
outside the discursive ambit of deliberative forums. on many issues,
informal alliances with these organizations will complement public
actions to good effect. on other issues, social movements may wish
to back their positions and agendas in these forums through the
media and other forms of projection and agitation in the public
domain. on every issue of note in the city, symbolic politics will
be key, and symbolism thrives on waves of compelling and widely
shared messages. With this point it is appropriate to move on to
a discussion of domain ive of political practice: symbolic politics
through discursive action.
Domain five: symbolic politics
[P]ower is both embedded in and effectuated through a crucial
combination of knowledge and language, or what is called discourse. discourse in this sense is the complex mixture of ideas and
expressions through which individuals both perceive and in turn
reconceptualizing the political
101
try to explain social reality. discourse therefore also deines the
parameters and criteria people use to ascertain and calculate the
potential courses of action and to choose particular courses of action in
speciic circumstances. It is thus the primary … medium of both
understanding and action.34
Paradoxically, the symbolic or discursive domain is the most understudied and undertheorized compared to the previous four domains
of practice, because, as Michel Foucault suggests, we are surrounded
and enrolled by discursive power all the time. It is the ground we
move on, the air we breathe, because we cannot step outside of it if
we are to make a (conscious or unconscious) decision about our next
move. discourses provide a lens on the world, our everyday spaces
and ourselves. They constitute the everyday and specialist knowledge
we draw on to make sense of larger systems of power that shape
thought and behaviour through regulation of bodily practices. Put
differently, we internalize discourses about the issues it is appropriate
to consider, what to think about (or believe of) such issues, and how
to act in ways consistent with what we believe, and of course to
rationalize it if we do not manage to do so. All of this comes to us as
unquestionable truths and that is the core of the power of discourse.
It renders certain historically and politically constructed assumptions
as self-evident and obvious, beyond the remit of questioning or
reversal. For discursive power to work its magic, it must insinuate
itself culturally – that is, be embedded in our daily sensibilities and
practices, which are culturally speciic and contingent. Here I am
applying a notion of culture as
the historical transmission of a learned repertory of embodied human
practices expressed in symbolic codes through which individuals and
social groups develop and perpetuate a way of life. It is a set of signifying activities shaped by and infused with relations of power. Culture
implies not only language, values, beliefs, and mores, but material
objects and processes organized in time–space locations. Culture is
therefore a complex social ecology of object, subject, and intersubjective
relations.35
For my purposes in this chapter, I want to draw attention to
the political potency of discourses about the identity of the city and
the policy imperatives that low from it. In a recent article, Jenny
102
city futures
robinson highlights the problematic obsession of many local government managers in the global south with becoming ‘world class’ and
‘globally competitive’.36 The discourse on the imperative of becoming world class or globally competitive leads inexorably to policy
commitments to maintain levels of infrastructure that are deemed
world class and favourable to attracting foreign investors. If such
high-cost and high-maintanance infrastructures are not suficiently
in place, literally, then of course investment strategies need to be
devised to ensure that suficient resources are mobilized to make such
‘essential’ investments possible.37 If this means that fewer resources
are available for investing in infrastructure-poor areas, especially in
times of economic slowdown, then this is a rational sacriice for the
longer term good of the city. In this context, neo-corporatist forums
then become important sites of reproducing and legitimating such
discourses to the point of expunging oppositional ones, or at least
casting such perspectives as ‘out of touch with reality’. Crucially,
municipal discourses such as these are reinforced by national discourses as expressed through the macroeconomic commitments of
the government and the industrial strategy that prioritizes investment
in high-tech sectors that will enable emerging developing economies
to ‘compete’ globally, irrespective of whether the educational base
exists for the realization of such an economic trajectory. If one
relects on the underlying economic rationale of the Cds policy
discourses, it is apparent how they can be manipulated to legitimate
the economic preoccupation of urban elites to do whatever it takes
to become ‘competitive’ and ‘world class’, even if it involves decisions
that will cause the poor to suffer even more hardship in the short
term. In the rationality of such policy discourses, short-term suffering
is a necessary evil in order irst to grow the economy, which will
generate the resources eventually to attend more effectively to the
needs of the poor.
If cities in the global south are to become spaces of greater possibility for radical democracy and distributive justice, this domain
of political practice will have to be taken much more seriously.
symbolic contestation through the deconstruction and reconstruction
of dominant discourses is a prerequisite for achieving impact in terms
of political strategies in all four of the other domains discussed earlier.
reconceptualizing the political
103
symbolic politics functions through cultural resigniication and therefore implies more creative practices which target the media, especially
radio and popular newspapers; public spaces in the city, especially
streetscapes and squares invested with symbolic meaning; and spaces
of collective consumption, such as schools, clinics, libraries. symbolic
contestation clears the ground to ask fundamental questions about
given governmental discourses, such as: What are the underlying
rationalities of this discourse? What conditions make it possible for
this discourse to pass as given and valid? What are the goals of the
discourse? How can the elements of the discourse be challenged and
rearranged to turn the discourse on itself and make new meanings
and imaginings possible which can be pursued through direct action
or development practice or municipal policy? More presciently, to
return to my earlier concern about the identity of the city, a discursive sensitivity makes it possible to recast questions such as these:
Who is the city for? Whose identities and cultures are embodied by
representations of the city? How can the futures of the city be reimagined to relect a radical openess as opposed to the conventional
approach whereby there is only one alternative?38
Interfaces
The drawback of any conceptual model is that it superimposes a
false sense of structure on complex and luid social realities. The
conceptual model of urban politics developed here is no exception.
A lot of dynamics leak from the model to smudge the artiicial
boundaries between urban spaces and associated political practices.
As Arjun Appadurai reminds us, cultural identities and practices
are constitutively porous, relational and marked by dissensus within
some aspiration for consensus. For these reasons, it is important to
foreground the numerous spaces between different types of political practice. I will consider one striking example that is theorized
in the evocative work of Asef bayat on what he categorizes as ‘the
encroachment of the ordinary’.
Asef bayat, in the tradition of James scott, seeks to capture political agency in a zone in between what I would label direct action
and development practice.39 bayat studies the everyday practices of
survival and circumvention, undertaken at the expense of the elite,
104
city futures
that the ultra poor engage in to carve out spaces to dwell, move
around and earn an income in the city where their very presence is
deemed illegitimate and illegal. It is a nuanced and layered argument
which is best summarized by the author:
The notion of ‘quiet encroachment’ describes the silent, protracted
and pervasive advancement of ordinary people on those who are
propertied and powerful in a quest for survival and improvement of
their lives. It is characterized by quiet, largely atomized and prolonged
mobilization with episodic collective action – open and leeting struggles without clear leadership, ideology or structured organization.
While quiet encroachment is basically a ‘non-movement’, it is distinct
from survival strategies or ‘everyday resistance’. First, the struggles
and gains of people at the grassroots are not made at the expense of
fellow poor or themselves, but of the state, the rich and the general
public. For example, in order to light their shelters, the urban poor
tap electricity not from their neighbours, but from the municipality
power poles; to raise their living standard they do not prevent their
children from attending school and send them to work, but rather they
squeeze the hours of their own formal job in order to work a second
job in the informal sector. In addition, these struggles should not be
seen as necessarily defensive, merely in the realm of ‘resistance’, but
as cumulatively encroaching, meaning that the actors tend to expand
their space by winning new positions to move on to. This kind of
quiet activism challenges fundamental aspects of state prerogatives,
including the meaning of ‘order’ and control of public space. but the
most immediate consequence is the redistribution of social goods via
the (unlawful and direct) acquisition of: collective consumption (land,
shelter, piped water, electricity); public space (streets, intersections,
parking areas); and opportunities (favourable business conditions,
locations and labels).40
This provocative conception clearly has resonance and relevance
across the global south if one considers the slum growth trends
outlined in Chapter 2 and the evocative overviews by Mike davis
(Planet of Slums) and robert Neuwirth (A Billion Squatters). Yet it
would be incorrect to locate it as either direct action or politics
of development practice. It occupies a zone in between but is also
highly amenable for deployment in creative politics of discursive
contestation about who the city is for, even if not by the protagonists
of quiet encroachment themselves. This example will have to sufice
reconceptualizing the political
105
to stress the point that the model can only be seen as a heuristic
device to explore discrete domains of political practice and their
hybrid interfaces. Now for some comments on the inal elements of
the model depicted in Figure 5.1: political and public spheres.
Public sphere + political sphere = vibrant democracy?
In terms of the conceptual model, elected politicians carry out their
function primarily in two domains of political practice: the representative sphere and neo-corporatist forums. And together these
two constitute the formal ‘political sphere’ in the city, anchored in
the deliberations of the municipal council chamber. In the political
sphere the governmental priorities of the city are deined, contested
and reviewed through highly structured procedural mechanisms of
deliberation. both the content and the systems of deliberation have a
structuring effect on what is deined as legitimately part of the political sphere and what is not. As I have already argued, discursive power
and its underlying knowledges are the grids that deine the horizon
of political imagination and intervention. This political horizon is
mediated via the media and legitimating knowledge institutions such
as universities, technical colleges, think-tanks and opinion-poll survey
companies that relect back to society curves of opinion and attitudes
with a gloss of scientiicity. In the absence of dissent and conlict,
the political sphere can easily dominate and structure the broader
public sphere where state and civil society engagements are mediated.
In other words, top-down political practices can eclipse bottom-up
processes that emanate from civil society, effectively asphyxiating
democratic citizenship.
For this reason, it is vital to stimulate and animate a vibrant public
sphere. In the traditional Habermasian sense, the public sphere ‘is a
space which mediates between society and the state where the public
organizes itself and in which “public opinion” is formed’.41 In this
sphere, citizens engage discursively and rationally in public reasoning
to arrive at the greatest public interest on a given issue. My theoretical
starting points at the beginning of the chapter lead me away from
the rational deliberative model of Habermas in order to promote a
conception of the public sphere more favourable to the possibility and
hegemony of radical democracy. This refers to ‘a radical pluralistic
106
city futures
public sphere of contestive identities, moralities, and discourses. It
endorses a politics of diverse social, cultural and political movements
organized around the values of cultural recognition, direct democracy, and performative resistance.’42 This conception is premissed
on the insight of Chantal Mouffe that we can never fully reconcile
the tensions between equality (maximization of egalitarian spaces
of differences) and liberty (maximization of democratic rights), but
instead deploy the tension to animate agonistic contestation within
the ambit of universal human rights.43 The tension produces agonistic
pluralism in the polity. In summary, the argument here is simply for
a recognition that at the nexus of the present (everyday transgressions in combination with an agonistic public-political sphere), the
past (memory) and the future (open-ended), we are perched on the
edge of a politics of potentiality – that is, a transgressive politics of
radical democracy and distributive justice.
Conclusion
by crossing the limits of possibility one encounters transgression.
The perverse persistence of brutal inequality in cities of the south
requires a politics of transgression that valorizes agonistic engagement in a radical democratic public sphere. An ethic of transgression
is a prerequisite for political action that will shift the ‘frontier of
the possible’, following the injunction of ben okri. In this chapter
I have attempted to clarify a conceptual model of urban politics
that can serve two functions. on the one hand, it can stimulate
a stronger relational perspective of urban political practices across
a plurality of action spaces – formal and informal, symbolic and
concrete, collaborative and contestationary – with a sensibility of
agonistic pluralism. Too much of the current scholarship on urban
development is fragmented and partial, undermining our ability to get
a handle on what is going on and how the status quo is maintained
and bolted in place. This aspect of the model is about incitement
to more comprehensive analytical accounts of political practices in
the city – that is, the fullness of political identities in variegated
time-spaces of the city.
on the other hand, I have also sought to demonstrate that a radical
democratic practice in the city is multidimensional and constitutively
reconceptualizing the political
107
open-ended. If one considers the multiplicity of domains of political
practice alongside the subjective imperative of identity politics, it is
clear that progressive politics cannot be imagined a priori, or in simple
good/bad terms. A progressive agenda is by deinition a complex
lattice of numerous transgressive practices that span from psychic
interiors to the monumental spaces that symbolically ‘embody’ the
city for its citizens and the world at large. In between there are
an ininite series of strategic and tactical manoeuvres that can be
deployed to remake political identities, boundaries and horizons. It
is only at the coalface of practice and resistance that the tactical
coordinates can be deined and used as a resource to construct
focused political communities in difference and solidarity. such an
appreciation allows for the natural coming together of an unlinching
critique of the workings of dominating power, especially during our
neoliberal times, and reverence for the complexity and indeterminacy
of political practice. For me, echoing James Holston, this constitutes
the challenge, pleasure and joy of insurgent citizenship for the city
yet to come.44 The next chapter takes a detour via ‘the insurgent’ to
balance out the formalistic policy argument that follows.
6
Informal everyday urbanism
At the core of the mainstream view on cities, and slums, in the
developing world is a topos that locates these places on a continuum
from nascent/informal to developed/post-industrial, with the latter
representing the apex of human achievement in city building. This
is explicitly captured in the Guide to City Development Strategies, which
proposes a ‘stylised urban development trajectory’, with an economic continuum from informal economy to high-tech, high-design
amenity services.1 Implicit in this kind of perspective is a desire
progressively to move the chaotic, malfunctioning city of informality
towards a situation of order, comprehension and optimal functioning,
with the humanist intent of course that everyone who lives in the
city should enjoy a reasonable and digniied quality of life. on the
back of this desire for steady improvement is a belief in the power
of (rational) planning and deliberation to agree on the necessary
actions/interventions to improve the quality of life of, especially,
the urban poor and vulnerable, as we saw in Chapter 4. In this
mindset it is broadly accepted, even if not always practised, that to
get this right the intended beneiciaries must be actively involved and
drive the process. This narrative tends to function on the basis of
an assumption that modern, gleaming, skyscraper-illed cities, with
adequate networked infrastructures in place to support them, is the
only and ineluctable way into the urban future.
everyday urbanism
109
This is a dangerous policy mindset because it reinforces and legitimizes a form of governmentality – disciplinary, control and regulatory
actions – that makes it acceptable to intervene recklessly in the lives
and livelihoods of millions of poor people without appreciating the
delicate networks and strategies these denizens rely on to survive the
city in the domain of the informal. Thus, the purpose of this chapter
is to foreground the practices, dynamics, potentialities that reside
beyond the state’s reach and understanding, but are fundamental to
the ‘multiplex’ identities of the territories subjected to various forms of
urban development.2 In the irst section I argue that it is as plausible
to build a conceptual model of the city from the perspective of the
slum as it is from the perspective of the formal, concrete-and-steel city,
as is normally done. This attempt at a conceptual inversion is used as
a prelude to explore the city from the bottom up, or rather through
the eyes of the majority of poor denizens who appropriate the city for
their own ends. The examples range from Asef bayat’s paradigmatic
work on the ‘encroachment of the ordinary’, to an exploration of the
mobilization logics or counter-governmentalities of the shack/slum
dwellers International, to imaginative re-representation of slums in
Caracas, and then to promising examples where these logistics, along
with an interest in public culture, are the resources of reformulation
of the nature and potentialities of the urban in the south. The central
theme of this chapter, and of the book, is that a deeper appreciation
of cultural identities and dynamics that play out in the lived realities
of daily life and symbolic manifestations is a prerequisite for more
appropriate urban transformations.
Conceptual inversion
In a recent book by Nigel Coates, Guide to Ecstacity, the modernist urban imaginary is fundamentally challenged and supplanted
by the imaginative invention of an alternative conceptual map and
vocabulary to try to deine what alternative urbanisms may feel, taste,
sound, look and smell like.3 Given the fresh and subversive novelty
of this affective imaginary, a few deinitional fragments from the
book are quoted here:
[I]n ecstacity … we should rise to the challenge of how locality, identity, freedom, diversity and security can be addressed together.
110
city futures
ecstacity models a world that emphasizes local identity rather than
some corporate ideology. Its particularity is in its variety, not its uniformity. As if in a borgesian multidimensional space, it reinstates the
empathy between the imagination and the everyday. It sets out to unite
and respect the multiplicity of the world we live in rather than erect
the sort of barriers that exacerbate misunderstanding.
Furthermore,
ecstacity is about ideas, relations and blended conditions. Its premise is
that, irst and foremost, the city should be a place of experience before
the formal stylistic or functional qualities of buildings [or dwellings].
In it, architecture – or its own broad version of it – is a vehicle for
a looser and more open framework that stimulates the space in each
of us … it sets out the city as if a dynamic paradigm for each of its
multi-various inhabitants, every one of whom can act as both stimulator
and respondent.
Granted, the architecturally driven vision of Coates can be seen as
a mere distraction by an eloquent fantasist who takes energy and focus
away from the pressing problem of slums and their attendant poverty.
However, my reading is that our present thinking about meeting the
challenges of slums is profoundly impoverished precisely because we
locate these places with their teeming complexities in a black box
devoid of complex agency and determinacy, which is nonetheless
unconsciously ascribed to parts of the modern city that are considered
developed or settled. Thus Coates’s argument can be interpreted as
an extension of a long tradition of urban anthropology and sociology
which seeks to ascribe and analyse patterns of agency among all city
dwellers, whether in slums or not.4 It is of course the implications of
such literature that have given rise to the shift in urban development
policy discourses away from ‘needs’ and ‘absences’, to focus instead
on the ‘assets’ and ‘capabilities’ of urban dwellers; a move that has
spawned the burgeoning literature on urban livelihoods.5 There is no
doubt that this seam of research and theorizing has greatly improved
the capacity of local governments, NGos and other urban development agencies to understand better the opportunities for support and
enhancement of local practices in slums.
However, my argument here attempts to go somewhat deeper. In
my reading, unless we are able to re-imagine fundamentally the nature
everyday urbanism
111
of the urban and the multiple potentialities of the city, by virtue of
the culturally sutured practices of the diverse people who live there,
we will not be able to move beyond essentially technocratic conceptualizations of city improvement. The question that I am groping
with is this: why can we not see slums as constitutive of the city as are,
say, the suburbs, or the central business districts, or the luminous
commercial retail spaces that serve to anchor middle-class existences
in the postmodern city? Given that in most cities in the global south
the majority of citizens live in slums, is it not time to rethink our
epistemic categories and redeine the city through the practices of the
slum, and other areas, in order to come to terms with ‘the complexity
of human nature, and how it wobbles constantly between pragmatism
and signiicance, between pleasure seeking and survival.’ 6 And, of
course, to explore how the complexity of human nature is expressed in
the creation, experience and remaking of space as an incessant series
of manoeuvres to make life worthwhile and meaningful, even if the
desire that dominates is to ind a job, or anything that will generate
cash, or a corrugated sheet of metal to fortify a leaking wall of a
shack, or enough to buy a cold beer at the local drinking hole where
the woman of your dreams works as a cleaner…
It is in this sense that I think the Ecstacity provocations of Coates
are apt. We have to step back, climb outside our mental cages and
completely rethink the ways in which we talk about, imagine and
seek to impact on life and desires in slums. This means being able
to locate slums within a larger matrix of urbanism which contextualizes not the slums alone, but the very possibility of the suburb, or
the high-consumption gay spaces in the city, or sites of leisure and
retail concentrated in shopping malls that stand as sentinels at the
edges of sprawled cities. From this angle, we are forced to question
the adequacy of our concepts, policy frameworks and, of course,
good intentions.
Clearly, a fuller, rounded and dense matrix of urbanism can only
be approached and grasped through a strong cultural perspective.
As intimated before, it is precisely such a perspective that I ind
singularly missing, or, rather, thin in the mainstream accounts of the
city, and especially the dynamics of slums. Instead, what is typically
projected is a litany of statistics to capture (physical and social)
112
city futures
infrastructural and economic absences, stylized accounts of livelihood patterns to give one a sense of everyday economies and levels
of dependency on mutual support and/or state investments, and
possibly broad brush-strokes on levels of associational involvement,
especially in organizations focused on livelihood improvement. These
informational coordinates are, of course, important and relevant, but
they typically reveal a lot less than they conceal. Without a nuanced
exploration of social and psychic dynamics in poor areas, our understanding of these communities and the urban system within which
they are embedded will remain inadequate for the realization of the
imagination and politics that can lead to truly audacious interventions.
overleaf, towards the end of the chapter, I return to these themes by
exploring examples where popular culture and literary registers offer
far more compelling representations of everyday life in slums.
one of the frustrating aspects of urban development is the fact
that it is relatively easy to identify the causal drivers of the multitude of problems that characterize most cities in the global south.
However, it does not follow that solutions to these problems are
straightforward to pinpoint and pursue. As I suggested at the outset,
this disjuncture compels one to pursue a transformation agenda that
is systemic and systematic – that is, invariably incremental – but
also radical in that it seeks over time to shift the underlying causal
factors that reproduce urban injustice. It is dificult to maintain this
ine balance because the rationalities and institutional intensities
of mainstream urban management can completely overwhelm and
swamp critical actors in the state and in civil society. This is where
insurgent practices come into the frame. Insurgent practices take on
various forms but essentially relect autonomous efforts on the part
of urban citizens in various kinds of associational conigurations to
carve our a space for their interests and desires despite regulatory
or symbolic prescriptions of the state. I now turn to the most useful
conceptual attempt to capture and theorize such insurgencies.
Insurgent urbanism: encroachment of the ordinary
The big controversy over the approach of the Millennium development Goals (MdGs) to the issue of shelter is of course the pathetic
target of lifting 100 million slum dwellers out of poverty by 2015.
everyday urbanism
113
What this target says is that if all the actors in the world who deal
with urban development put their heads together and prioritize the
eradication of slum living conditions, then 90 percent (900 million)
of slum dwellers worldwide will have to accept that they are not part
of this deal; their lives will not be touched by this extraordinary
global effort. Let us put the moral problems of this form of ultraconservative targeting to one side; let us also ignore the stacks of
academic reviews piling up predicting a massive failure to achieve
the MdG targets, given the trends since 2000 when the targets were
agreed upon. Instead, let us assume the target will be met. What
does it mean for the everyday reality of the world’s urban population,
largely conined to unhealthy, precarious and overcrowded conditions? basically, it means that people will continue to live in the
ways they live today: by their wits, relentlessly inventive and within
powerful networks of support and symbiotic dependence.
However, inside urban development policy discourses that seek
to spell out the solutions to problems, there is very little room for
a deep consideration or appreciation of the agency, skill, endurance
and effort that go into the survival and consolidation strategies of
the urban poor. The ‘livelihoods’ literature has stepped into this
breach and can offer great insights. However, it very easily slips
into a ‘toolbox’ discourse that helps urban planners or developers
to understand the livelihood strategies of the poor so as to better
connect them to micro-inance, or institutional support, and thereby
enlarge their ‘stocks of social capital’. There is a place for this form
of engagement with the survival practices of the poor, but it cannot
substitute for a serious engagement with the ‘quiet encroachment
practices’ of thousands, and sometimes millions, of individual actions
outside of modern institutions. In the previous chapter I quoted Asef
bayat at some length to relect his conceptualization of this idea of
rich, below-the-radar sets of small actions to gain a little piece of
pavement, or a few square foot of loor space, or illegally tapped
kilowatts from a government-owned power line, or enough invisibility
to duplicate copyrighted goods for sale at informal markets; all actions
carried out by the ‘necessity to survive and live a digniied life’.7 since
most slum dwellers and other marginal people in urban areas are
essentially left to fend for themselves without the prospect of state
114
city futures
support or decent work, by sheer dint of necessity people make do
and invent an endless series of permutations of informalized work,
service provision, occupation, places for bodily relief and passion.
Mostly these activities take on the form of modest, surreptitious
and atomized actions to carve out a little foothold to secure sustenance for just another day. From time to time they can spill over
into more collective expressions of demand, but according to bayat
the aim is usually to defend illegally gotten gains in the city. Conceptually, Asef bayat suggests, we need to understand two primary
aims that are embedded in these inevitable and incessant dynamics
of encroachment in contemporary cities in the south:
The irst [aim] is the redistribution of social goods and opportunities in the form of the (unlawful and direct) acquisition of collective
consumption (land, shelter, piped water, electricity, roads), public space
(street sidewalks, intersections, street parking places), opportunities
(favourable business conditions, locations, and labels), and other life
changes essential for survival and a minimal standard of living.
The other goal is attaining autonomy, both cultural and political,
from the regulations, institutions, and discipline imposed by the state.
The disenfranchised express a deep desire to live an informal life,
to run their own affairs without involving the authorities or other
modern formal institutions. This is not to suggest that tradition guides
their lives, but rather to insist that modern institutions, in one sense,
reproduce people’s traditional relations as solutions to the problems
that these institutions engender. In many informal communities in
Third World cities, people rely on their own local and traditional norms
during their daily activities, whether it be establishing contracts (e.g.
marriage), organizing their locality, or resolving local disputes. In a way,
they are compelled to exert control over their working lives, regulating
their time and coordinating their space … autonomy and integration in
the view of both the poor and the state are far from straightforward.
They are the subject of contradictory processes, constant redeinition,
and intense negotiation. Informality is not an essential preference of
the urban poor; it serves primarily as an alternative to the constraints
of formal structures.8
Clearly, for as long as the contemporary capitalist system persists,
exacting particular forms of territorial management – uneven and
highly exclusionary – it is likely that it will serve the interest of the
majority of the poor better to retain their autonomy and cannibalize
everyday urbanism
115
formal systems and resources where they can; and to bend parts of
the city to their will by defending and consolidating the micro-gains
they succeed in making by simply surviving the viciousness of the
city’s economic reproduction. signiicant for me is the sheer scale
and density of these practices across most of the south because of
the similarity in economic and governmental conditions, which leave
little room for the rights of the disenfranchised to be recognized and
realized. despite the obvious prevalence and scale of these actions,
it is telling that the bulk of urban scholarship, and of course policy
discourse, simply bypasses these dynamics and rather creates urban
spaces that correspond with the regulatory and developmental criteria
of formalized modern systems of urban management.
Tenacious insurgent activism:
Shack/Slum Dwellers International 9
If Asef bayat’s work draws attention to the logic of atomized encroachment on the formal city, the next example draws attention to a category
of urban actors who use their marginality as a source of active
mobilization to extract concessions and services from the state, but,
crucially, on their own terms. The most coherent, well-connected and
articulate of the various slum associations in the world is undoubtedly
shack/slum dwellers International (sdI). As a network they have
been incredibly effective and inluential in shaping shelter and tenure
policies of international development agencies over the past few years,
as discussed in Chapter 4. In this section, I want to home in on their
unique ideology and mobilization practice because it points to one way
of turning marginality and autonomy into an institutional expression
that can create an effective interface with the state without giving up
entirely the few sources of power available to the urban poor. Given
the great diversity of various afiliated federations of the sdI, I will
use the one I am most familiar with, the south African Homeless
People’s Federation (sAHPF), to explore this theme.
The institutional architecture of the sAHPF is deliberatively
designed to support an unambiguously people-led, people-centred
and people-controlled development strategy, termed in academic
literature as asset-based community development. This approach is
about fostering transformative, self-reliant and self-replicable social
116
city futures
development practices modelled around: asset mobilization; asset
mapping; community-based problem solving; and ‘progressive scaling’
up of activities as outside external institutions are called upon to
invest in community-devised and locally driven development initiatives. key practices or rituals to give effect to this strategy include:
enumeration and mapping, surveying, house modelling and savings
schemes establishment, exchange visits between settlements and internationally, precedent setting and claim-making.
In contrast to mainstream claim-making practices, the HPA’s
strategy in its engagement with the state is underpinned by the belief
that oficial programmes ‘need to be redesigned and redeveloped
by the poor’ so that they ‘work for them’, followed by negotiation
with the state to obtain support for the implementation of their
‘solution’.10 The solutions championed aim to strengthen long-term
capacity- and capability-building through three linked change processes: asset-building (mobilizing social capital through federating,
networking and exchanges, savings and loan activities); developing a
knowledge of community priorities and needs and how best to meet
them, and accumulating and mobilizing resources to test the eficacy
and sustainability of the solution (via enumeration, community planning and house design exercises, supported by exchange visits); and
engaging the state to support the solutions engineered by the poor,
without strangling the ‘life out of their organizations’.11
A key outcome of these processes of capacity–capability enhancement is for the poor to lead by example, wherein communities pioneer
and develop their own solution and demonstrate its practical viability – precedent-setting – before engaging the state in an effort to
transform oficial programmes. of signiicance in this approach is
not pitting the solution proposed by the poor against the state programme, or lobbying directly for policy change, but rather the seeking
of ‘shifts’ in the institutional arrangements which determine the way
policy translates into action. The ‘attendant shifts in the institutional
framework, if they are of some magnitude, will be bound to have a
direct impact on policy’.12 Joel bolnick, director of sdI, captured the
spirit of this form of engagement most eloquently: ‘don’t confront
authority head on. Instead of storming the citadel, iniltrate it.… Play
judo with the state – use its own weight to roll it over.’13
everyday urbanism
117
Clearly, the modalities of state engagement are extremely sophisticated. It involves straddling diverse spatial scales and territorial–
administrative jurisdictions; criss-crossing the political and oficial
divide; deal-making with progressive and conservative political parties;
and playing off one level of government against another (among
others). This strategic practice arises from and is reinforced by multiscalar organization-building interventions (local/regional/national/
international exchanges and afiliation to shack/slum dwellers International14 ) whose roots are anchored in communities.
The ‘federating’ of community-based organizations at city, provincial and national scales is the irst step. once federations are
active, negotiation with government oficials commences around
the priorities of the poor, and the solutions devised by them. signiicant in sAHPF’s multi-scalar practice are the contributions of
the international donor community. The lexibility of donor funding
facilitates innovation, which is needed to ensure effective utilization
of government funds.15 donor funding also creates the multinational
language and legitimacy for sAHPF interventions.
The superior track record of this unique community-based development approach is most visible in the sAHPF’s widely celebrated
housing delivery strategy. While the state was inalizing its supply
side, state-facilitated and private-sector-driven housing programme (in
a forum that excluded the homeless poor and their organizations),
the sAHPF used a combination of uTshani Fund loans (their own
loan inance facility, capitalized at that stage by european donors)
and savings from collectives of poor people to build homes that
were larger, cheaper and of better quality than those delivered via
the state–developer partnership route. In other words, in a context
such as south Africa, where there was a state-driven public housing
programme, the sAHPF could outperform the state in terms of
process and outcome with far fewer resources. This is a signiicant
achievement by any measure.
The sAHPF model became increasingly attractive to government.
Following the promotion of the model as sustainable at the Habitat
II Conference in 1996, global donors16 provided direct support for
the adoption of a housing approach based on self-help construction
through the formation of a People’s Housing Partnership Trust within
118
city futures
the department of Housing of the south African government in
1998. The purpose of the Trust was the ‘institutional capacitation
and empowerment at the provincial and local spheres of government
and among NGos to support the peoples’ process’.17
In south Africa, poor people are placed on a waiting list, and
when their turn comes they get the free transfer of a built house,
with serviced land, usually no more than 32 square metres. Under the
People’s Housing Process provision of the government, introduced
in May 1998, potential beneiciaries had to demonstrate participation
in a savings scheme in order to access the capital subsidy allocated
to the top structure of public housing. Considerable emphasis was
placed by government on community or beneiciary contribution to
the process of house construction through sweat equity. Thus the
oficial people’s housing process approach became ostensibly about
people building their own houses utilizing subsidized materials, with
government extending the necessary infrastructure.18 The sAHPF
and many progressive development practitioners claim the adoption
of people’s housing processes by the state as an important victory
for those committed to people-centred development.
Mainstreaming into government policy an alternative, initially
insurgent, survival practice is a noteworthy achievement. However,
as our research demonstrates, this can come at a cost in terms of the
effectiveness and radical edge of the movement. Today the sdI is a
profoundly inluential actor on the world stage of urban development
policymaking but remains wedded to a radical, oppositional political
ideology. For example, on their website they assert:
The sdI afiliates have come together to give a voice to the poor in
an arena of decision-making that has, in recent years, been conined
to global organizations that champion neoliberal theories of development. As a counterpoint to these agencies, social movements (such as
the women’s and environmental movements) have emerged. They see
themselves as opponents of centralized state power, backed by these
global agencies – the United Nations, the International Monetary Fund
and the World bank.19
The reason they are able to hold seemingly contradictory positions
– opposition and cooperation – is perceptively distilled by Mark
swilling:
everyday urbanism
BOX 6.1
119
Urban Think Tank: Caracas Case
A number of photographers, visual artists, architects and writers,
as well as social and cultural scientists, came together to research
the informal inluences on the contemporary development of
urban culture in Latin America, taking Caracas as an example.
The results of the interdisciplinary ield research provided the basis
for a fascinating publication, Informal City: Caracas Case, a work that
is of great relevance beyond Caracas and puts up for discussion a
new form of informal urbanism. A central argument by the lead
researchers/instigators/editors is the following:
The approach we take in this book to understanding the 21st-century
city offers an alternative to that of traditional planning, which has
attempted to shape the city over the past centuries and has been rooted
in european rationalism, notwithstanding resistance. Indeed, it has
long been an article of faith among architects and planners that the
Cartesian model is required in order to analyse the city, to the extent
that no deinition of the ‘informal city’ even exists.… The absence
of zoning codes, and well-established private property rights and the
existence of alternatively organized communities was seen as primitive
and problematic. [However, the] planned city can neither eliminate nor
subsume the informal qualities and practices of its inhabitants. The
informal city persists; its inherent strengths resist and defeat efforts
to impose order. The totally planned city is, therefore, a myth.… The
present-day city calls for a profound reorientiation in the manner in
which we study it; we believe in working at the intersections of the
individual and the collective, the real and the virtual in a multiplicity
of parallel engagements.
The book and accompanying exhibitions are wonderfully illustrated
with a melange of essays, photographs, diagrams, illustrative sampling, statistics and maps and were actively inserted into ongoing
public debates and public processes.
The signiicance of the approach used by the sdI associated initiatives
is that they have plaited together strands of developmental knowledge that are normally compartmentalized into separate types of
developmental practice: the key role of micro-inance in development;
grassroots community-organizing to build collective solidarities; technical innovations aimed at doing more with less; challenging existing
inequalities at the political level; pragmatic autonomism within civil
120
city futures
society; the speciicity of the city and in particular the socio-cultural
context of the urban poor as a ield of organizational practice; and
subordinating professional knowledge and roles to the organized chaos
of community leadership. Unsurprisingly, as with any kind of synthesis, it makes everyone who has not seen the synthesis unhappy. The
pragmatic autonomism will be criticized for being reformist because it
‘lets the state off the hook’; the emphasis on continuous challenge and
engagement will be criticized for being too political and confrontational
thus putting potential concessions at risk; micro-inance combined
with community organizing will be criticized by the micro-inance
purists for being irresponsible; and traditional rights-based community
organizers will see micro-inance as a waste of energy when the real
task should be to put pressure on states to inject more development
inance. Above all else, synthesis often makes the story too complex
to tell in short and simple enough ways for academics, government
oficials, the media, development specialists and most social activists
to understand. It works in communities because this complexity is an
everyday reality. 20
I will conclude this section on this note because it demonstrates
clearly the central point of this chapter: namely, in both the atomized
and organized survival practices of the poor, most of the lessons and
knowledge gained in engaging with the complexity of urban areas are
already decipherable, but the conventional assumptions and policy
models are not tuned in. box 6.1 describes a fascinating effort to
take the constitutive nature of urban informality as a starting point
for radically rethinking the city from the vantage point of Caracas.21
This vital work, which I do not have the space here to explore
more fully, provides an important example of one alternative way
to respond to the insurgent energies that invariably arise from the
cauldrons of informality across the south.
Popular culture and the negotiation of everyday violence
The literature is clear that urban violence is often endemic in many
cities of south. one of the more extreme examples is brazil, where
violence is indeed a dominant factor in everyday life, particularly in
the enclave neighbourhoods where the poor are concentrated – the
favelas. A consequence of this dominance is the normalization of
violence as routine in resolving conlict or relating to others. The
literature suggests that this is particularly common in post-conlict
everyday urbanism
121
societies such as Colombia, 22 Nicaragua, 23 south Africa, 24 Jamaica, 25
among many others. 26 drug traficking inds an easy setting in these
societies because it requires and produces violence. Almost all dimensions of the drug trade involve violence; for example, gang warfare
that lares to control markets and turf, attacks on addicts in waves
of social cleansing (especially in brazil), and the incessant quarrels
and gendered interpersonal violence in the home.27
structural violence, associated in particular with drug economies,
gave rise to particular spatial conigurations in favelas which constrict and direct the movement of ordinary people. Urban planner/
ethnographer Marcelo Lopez de sousa, in Culture Is Our Weapon,
provides an insightful picture of this spatiality:
favela-based retail drug traficking combines a strong hierarchy at the
scale of the favela, with a decentralised, network-based organisation
at the comandos scale. In each shanty town, this hierarchy comprises
(in descending order): the dono do morro (‘owner of the hill’), gerentes
(‘managers’, those who control the selling places), soldados (‘soldiers’,
security staff), vapores (‘vapours’, street sellers) and aviões (‘aeroplanes’,
go-between sellers). each drug traficking crew or quadrilha has its own
territory of one or more favelas, and while dealers who belong to the
same comando usually respect each other’s territories, bandits belonging
to rival comandos often try to take possession of enemy territories. This
results in turf wars over several days or even weeks, usually involving
several drug traficking crews belonging to the same comando in the
spirit of mutual help. The protection of business as well as other,
more symbolic aspects such as demonstrations of power and virility
… has contributed not only to an increasing use of violence among
criminal crews, but also to an increasing atmosphere of tyranny for
favela inhabitants. 28
The evocative accounts by former traficantes (drug trafickers) captures how a willingness and capacity for violence are key to moving
up the rungs of the drug gangs, in terms of both status and space.
The net effect of the violence is staggering: ‘between 1948 and 1999,
an estimated 13 000 people were killed in the Israeli–Palestinian
conlict. between 1979 and 2000, more than 48 000 died from irearm related injuries in the city of rio.’29 In other words, young
black kids in rio’s favelas grow up in a war zone, possibly with
worse psycho-social impacts because no one regards it as a time of
122
city futures
war.30 However, amidst this bleak outlook, dynamic counterpoints
have also emerged to respond to these trends, but crucially using a
popular-cultural hook.
Musical genres such as hip-hop and reggae, fused with indigenous
genres such as forró, frevo, samba, bossa nova, brazilian rock, among
others, have been central to the fermentation of a popular source
of critique and alternative practices to the violent gang cultures
that dominate everyday life in favelas. For example, racionais MCs,
the enormously popular hip-hop group from são Paulo, rap almost
exclusively about their position of marginality and the ways in which
the dominant, racist system reproduces that marginality.31 Another
equally inluential and critical voice is MV bill from rio de Janeiro,
who more clearly takes on the position of ‘organic intellectual’ from
the favela who aims to ‘speak truth to power’ about the double
standards of mainstream assumptions in brazilian society:
[W]hat you have to understand about this society is that questions of
violence and crime are not just about guns and drugs. In brazil, the
only people who go to prison are those who steal a little. Those who
steal a lot go free. Putting people in sub-human conditions in the
favelas? When I show it I’m criticised but that’s a form of violence. In
rio, there’s still a lot of colonial inluence. I heard a black girl at a
public school who suffered racism. she locked herself in a toilet and
tried to cut off her skin to make herself white. but when you try to
talk about racism, we’re told we’re neurotic. That’s a form of violence.
kids from the favelas always attend state schools but they have to work
for their families too. Therefore, favela kids never have good enough
education to get into public universities. They never have a chance.
Those places go to middle-class kids from private schools. That’s a
form of violence too. You know … I’m talking about blacks but the
same applies to Indians and whites who have nothing. People say hip
hop is all about violence but they don’t understand. rap in this country
is very anti-violence and does a lot of good. of course, it’s not the
only way to help people, but I know it’s helped me. some people want
to change hip hop to ‘I love this woman’ and all that stuff. but we’ve
heard that so many times in other music and, I ask you, do people really
have that much love?32
Afroreggae is another example of a hugely popular group that
uses music and other performative arts as an entry point into the
lives of traumatized youth and children in favelas. However, the
everyday urbanism
123
praxis of Afroreggae suggests that this is not uncomplicated, in
that they resort to emulating the disciplinary structures of the drug
gangs. Thus, apart from a broader politicized narrative of structural
exclusion and marginalization because of oficial complicity with
the proits of the drug trade, especially at the upper circuits of the
value chain, the leader of Afroreggae, Junior, knows that he must
mirror the discipline and hierarchies of the gang cultures. The point
is that he knows that his movement must offer an alternative home
and sense of belonging because that is what the gang offers in the
irst instance, apart from access to inancial resources which are not
available through participation in the formal labour market. In other
words, the solution is not simply a matter of restoring the sense of
self, pride and dignity of these young people and then they will
somehow, miraculously, manage to stay on the straight and narrow
of the alternative lifestyle the movement offers. Again, MV bill
captures this dynamic clearly when he argues:
They don’t have any opportunity of becoming something else; each one
is their own judge and can say what is right or wrong but crime nowadays in brazil has become just another choice; it breaks my heart to say
this but crime nowadays has tragically become a great choice for those
who are born with no prospects. I am not going to be hypocritical and
say the opposite because this is what I’ve seen, this is the truth and even
I have dificulties in saying to someone ‘Get out of the drug trafic’
because I don’t have anything better to offer. And it is not enough to
offer charity assistance, kind of small thing, because television shows
the good things in life and this is what everybody is after.33
In the same breath, MV bill also talks about his hip-hop organization, CUFA (Central Association of Favelas), which seeks to offer
alternatives to young people. What he resigns himself to here is the
larger structural factors at work that reproduce criminal economies.
He is not so naive to believe that their piecemeal intervention is a
solution on its own. Possibly this is why he has recently collaborated
with prominent brazilian anthropologist/criminologist Luis eduardo
soares to produce a book, Cabeça de Porco, and a documentary on urban
violence in nine brazilian cities. The book brings to light the scale
and convergence of urban violence in brazil, and in particular how
the perpetrators of the violence in the favelas are becoming younger
124
city futures
and more extreme. The book is meant as a wake-up call to the
brazilian establishment, and no doubt also a point of mobilization of
external resources to back initiatives such as CUFA and Afroreggae.
More importantly, this initiative underscores the fact that structural
interventions are required to deal with urban violence; interventions
that can dovetail with hip-hop-inspired grassroots programmes such
as those of MV bill and educational initiatives in juvenile prisons.34
soares is very clear about the kinds of reforms/transformations that
are required in response to the question ‘do you think that having
access to information, higher education and projects that increase
self-esteem could be a way out of violence?’
Without a doubt. I am convinced of that. In our book we do not forget
the importance of economic power, but we stress the importance of
inter-subjectivity, symbolism, affection, psychology and culture. Not
because that is more important, but because society has not paid them
proper attention. We have to offer youth at a minimum what the drug
trade offers: material resources, of course, but also recognition, a sense
of belonging and of value. In the end, there is a hunger more profound
than physical hunger: the hunger for affection and recognition, which
raise self-esteem … I think that repression should be the last resort.
before repression, there is a lot to be done in the way of prevention, such as reinsertion, education, and boosting self-worth. If we
want someone to change, we have to provide the foundation. No one
changes if he or she thinks that they are worth nothing. do we want
to exterminate poor youth or integrate them? Pardon and give a second
chance also means forgiving ourselves and giving ourselves a second
chance, as a society. Wouldn’t it be great for us to have the chance of
escaping from the horrible guilt of having abandoned thousands of
children to the fate of picking up a gun?35
soares intimates that there are two issues at stake. one, it is vital
not to lose sight of the humanity of poor black youth who grow
up amidst terror and, effectively, social abandonment. There is no
recuperating this class of (non)citizens for an inclusive urban polity
without acknowledging the fundamental need for an afirmation of
their personhood. Two, the scale of reform implicates the state. Poor
young people will remain confronted with truncated futures as long
as the criminal justice institutions of the state are not transformed to
embrace a philosophy that treats repression as a last resort. Clearly,
everyday urbanism
125
hip-hop projects in favelas are not in themselves able to address these
ambitious tasks. What they do offer is a vital entry point for young
people to exercise agency in larger and multilayered political and
cultural struggles for both recognition and reform. However, what
the voice and artistic practice of Afroreggae, MV bill, racionais
MCs, among others, suggest is that if poor black youth are to have a
meaningful voice it must be on their own terms, and this is precisely
what hip-hop registers potentially offer. This means a politics and
aesthetics of rage and militant critique of the thinly veiled double
standards of mainstream society. In this regard there are many dozens
of artists across the south who work in a hip-hop or popular-cultural
vein to make sense and get their instigations across, stoking the
desires and ambitions of marginalized youth. Furthermore, in the
complex aesthetic registers that hip-hop cultures instigate, young
people should be encouraged to explore their identities, aspirations
and contexts without too much censorship. Creative artistic expression
can potentially create a new political language and symbolic register
that is meaningful to young people and potentially impenetrable and
alienating to elites and middle classes. This is the point. For political
engagement to occur the powerful and privileged must be compelled
to acknowledge their different cultures and assumptions, which are
typically rendered invisible by virtue of being the social norm; only
then can they ‘make a difference’ as part of a larger cosmopolitan
politics. Finally, hip-hop registers offer poor young people a platform
for establishing various kinds of regional, national and international
networks of engagement and mutual support to foster a multi-scalar
agenda that brings together multiple local speciicities.
Public culture and the word: Sarai and Chimurenga
My inal example of the power of culturally driven and informed
responses to the complexity of urban change comes from India,
delhi in particular. Circa 1998, a small group of activists arrived
at a similar sense of unease about the sterility of academic debates
amidst a larger mainstream context of urban violence and strife. This
situation coincided interestingly with a countercurrent evidenced in ‘a
quiet rebirth of an independent arts and media scene’. Furthermore,
‘new ideas, modes of communication and forms of protest were
126
city futures
being tried out and tested in the streets.… The city itself, as a space
and as an idea, was becoming a focus for inquiry and relection,
and a provocation for a series of creative experiments.’36 It was in
this dynamic cauldron of change and renewal that the conceptual
foundation of a new initiative, called sarai, took shape. The discursive
sign sarai is drawn from the traditional connotation with places
where ‘travellers and caravans could ind shelter, sustenance and
companionship’.37 Consequently, the contemporary ‘sarai Initiative
interprets this sense of the word “sarai” to mean a very public
space, where different intellectual, creative and activist energies can
intersect in an open and dynamic manner so as to give rise to an
imaginative reconstitution of urban public culture, new/old media
practice, research and critical cultural intervention.’38 More formally,
sarai is a physical space and programme of the Centre for the study
of developing societies at the University of delhi. on their website,
they deine themselves as follows:
We are a coalition of researchers and practitioners with a commitment
towards developing a model of research-practice that is public and
creative, in which multiple voices express and render themselves in a
variety of forms. Through these practices that range from art practice
to publication, academic research to the organization of discursive
events, setting up of media labs and creative practices in locality labs in
disadvantaged neighbourhoods of the city, relecting upon the culture
of freedom, in speech and in software, we have sought to participate
in and cultivate a public domain that seeks to ind a new language
of engagement with the inequities, as also the possibilities, of the
contemporary world. over the last ive years, the sarai Programme has
matured into what could arguably be south Asia’s most prominent and
productive platform for research and relection on the transformation
of urban space and contemporary realities, especially with regard to the
interface between cities, information, society, technology and culture.
sarai has also been a robust platform committed to critical discourse,
freedom of expression and the exploration of the relationship between
human rights, civil liberties and the efforts to ensure the viability of a
democratic ethic with regard to media and information practices.39
The sarai initiative’s practice takes the form of rigorous and
innovative intellectual work that marks out vital new directions in
knowledge production, setting out from the city as it is, with all
everyday urbanism
127
its contradictions, without reverting to a teleological notion that
delhi is en route from informality to high-end services. Instead, it
is clear from a reading of the materials that come from this space
that the constitutive density of cultures and complexities cannot be
reduced to any coherent narrative, but are rather a series of layers
of urban reality that always exceed the medium and languages of
representation. sarai’s work makes it clear that the new knowledge
economy is as present and inluential in the slums of delhi as it is
formative in inancial centres such as London or New York. In its
various projects and outputs, sarai represents part of a glimmer of
an alternative register and sensibility in thinking about and through
the informal, emergent, makeshift and insurgent city that is the true
heart of urban life in the global south. It is an indispensable critique
and methodology for repositioning thinking and practice about the
futures of urban life and citizenship in our globalized era.
A similar, if more modest, cultural ferment has emerged in Africa
over the past few years. This is a cultural movement rooted in a
radical, underground, counter-mainstream positionality, but focused
on the real-life inventiveness of cultural activists across the African
continent. despite its radical positioning, the movement also makes
allowances for the vicissitudes of making everyday spaces through
deals in a messy world. I am referring to the ground-clearing publication Chimurenga, which is put out by an independent outit called
kalakuta Trust. According to their website,
Chimurenga, a pan African publication of writing, art and politics, has
been in print since March 2002. It was founded by Ntone edjabe. The
journal is published on the page three times/year, online monthly and
through themed performances called ‘Chimurenga sessions.’ The intellectual project has snaked from a Miltonian swamp of murky morality
and ‘paradigms lost’ if not into a Garden of eden, at least into a
more lucid landscape where intellect, integrity and humanity are valid
tools for growth. A lowering of organic schools of thought grown in
backyard gardens, tilled and fertilized by the fundamentals of humanity
preached and sometimes practised.40
As a result of this positioning and by dint of sheer determination by the nomadic editor, Chimurenga represents one of the most
important insurgent perspectives on public culture and critical politics
128
city futures
across the diverse spaces of the African continent. The reader can
gain the lavour of the energetically crazy and stimulating ambit of
the project by considering a few of the themes of past issues of the
print magazine: ‘Conversations in Luanda and other Graphic stories’
(an amazing special issue with graphic-novel type short stories from
across the south); ‘black Gays & Mugabes’ (critique and exposé of
homophobia in Africa); ‘The orphans of Fanon’; and, more recently,
‘Conversations with Poets Who refuse to speak’, ‘a heady mix of
words and images that give voice to silence’, according to the editorial
blurb.41 The point about Chimurenga, sarai and Urban Think Tank:
Caracas Case is that as we move into the future, the hundreds of
millions of youth who will remake the city in their own image will
ind different and new ways of expressing their unique urban experiences and outlooks; these are the still inaudible voices that urban
scholars and practitioners will have to learn to understand if they
have any hope of making a difference.
Conclusion
one frustration with a book of this nature is that it is biased towards
the formal discourses and representations of urban life that decisionmakers and policy activists use to deine the nature of problems in
order to arrive at decisions about how to address them. In the process
the dynamism and rich phenomenology of everyday life – which gives
cities their true identity and meaning – is taken out of the equation
in order to focus on the materiality of poverty and betterment.
However, the paradox is that as long as activists and decision-makers
fail to engage with the contradictory and elusive complexity of daily
life, especially in unregularized and underserviced areas, they are
unlikely to generate appropriate or effective policy responses. on the
other hand, constitutive complexity and diversity of particular streets,
neighbourhoods, zones, communities and districts in urban areas can
be so overwhelming that decision-making is neutralised, because the
decision-makers have not yet arrived at a ‘complete’ understanding
of everyday dynamics, or, in democratic terms, because not every
interest group has been consulted yet. This is not a paradox that can
easily be resolved. However, for me it boils down to a sensitivity to
the disjuncture between the assumptions policymakers are forced
everyday urbanism
129
to make about aggregate conditions and the lived realities they are
simplifying; it also boils down to a sensibility of openness to different
ways of seeing and responding to problems, because in the teeming
diversity of the city there will always be an angle or perspective or
experience that one has not considered. This reality should be enough
to keep any decision-maker or activist modest about their handle on
a given situation or problem.
This chapter has attempted to serve as a necessary diversion to
the overall rational policy discussion about the most effective policy
imaginaries and interventions available to us to understand and
address the challenges of urban development in our unequal global
era of interdependence. I now return to a macro-policy alternative to
the mainstream approaches to urban development reviewed in earlier
chapters, hopefully with an appreciation of the pluralism and openended dynamism of cities; of the limitations of overly prescriptive
or formulaic policy responses, but at the same time of the necessity
of intervention by strong and capable states.
7
Counterpoint:
alternative urban development
In the last two chapters I have explained the dynamic nature of
urban political life and the undercurrent of autonomy and sometimes
insurgency that animates most cities in the global south. The previous
chapter sought to counterbalance the tendency in the literature and
policy frameworks on developing-country cities by foregrounding
‘hidden’ dimensions of everyday survival and engagement to make
the city liveable for the majority of people who dwell and move
in its spaces. The purpose of this chapter is to return to the more
formalistic policy models and frameworks that inform the visions,
plans and decisions of urban development, for it is incumbent on
progressives to propose alternatives, not simply point endlessly to
the brutal workings of neoliberal power.
I come from the school of thought that believes one has to get
into the guts of urban institutions and decipher what the political
and discursive edge is of those institutions in terms of promoting
transformative interventions whilst holding on to the ‘constitutive
outside’ of those very organs of power and discipline. This kind
of positioning works on the basis of deep engagement with the
dynamic character of governmentality, sensitive to the imperative
of institutional expression, and hence the scope for subverting and
alternative urban development
131
extending the limits of formal politics. This positioning also accepts
that under certain circumstances the forces of conservatism may
be so strong that there is little point in working with and through
mainstream discourses; instead one should conine one’s activism
almost exclusively to a politics of opposition, resistance and militant
refusal. However, even in those cases, if a politics of opposition
eventually succeeds in shifting the terrain of decision-making and
power, a moment arrives where certain profound institutional and
formalization decisions need to be made about consolidating within
the practices of the state particular orientations and practices that
will systematically shift the weight of exploitation in the city off the
shoulders of the poor and abandoned.
This chapter presents a series of interlocking arguments about how
to think and act programmatically to bring more just and inclusive
systems into being in the routine functioning of the city. The starting
point is a brief ideological mapping of an alternative policy matrix
that can serve as a touchstone as activists challenge and incrementally
supplant the dominant discourses on urban development critiqued in
Chapters 3 and 4. This is followed by a succinct political economy
exposition of the underlying drivers of urban inequality, which is
meant to moderate overconident discourses about the prospects
and likelihood of full-scale urban transformations. Indeed, the brutal
workings of dominant powers in the world remain deeply entrenched
and creatively adaptive to foresee a full-scale urban revolution in our
generation. However, there are an ininite array of opportunities to
refuse, undermine, subvert, frustrate and erode that power, which
only begin to matter if one can effectively institutionalize such efforts.
such opportunities will be different and particular in each city and
town across the globe, but it is possible to weave together a general
tapestry of resistance which can serve as a vivid backdrop to local
struggles, always globally and regionally articulated. This chapter
presents such a tapestry, with a particular focus on two dominant
urban policy discourses, which are ripe for engagement, inversion
and redeployment to radical democratic purposes. Throughout, the
chapter operates on the basis of my perspective on the relational
dynamic of urban politics, expressed in Chapter 5.
132
city futures
Alternative urban development perspective
The holy grail of urban development is the achievement of integrated
sustainable human settlements whereby the needs of the present
generation are sustainably satisied without compromising the options
and resources of future generations. For example, the Habitat Agenda
asserts that the:
sustainability of human settlements entails their balanced geographical
distribution or other appropriate distribution in keeping with national
conditions, promotion of economic and social development, human
health and education, and the conservation of biological diversity and
the sustainable use of its components, and maintenance of cultural
diversity as well as air, water, forest, vegetation and soil qualities at
standards suficient to sustain human life and wellbeing for future
generations.1
This intergenerational deinition premissed on the idea of balancing
economic, ecological and social outcomes can be traced back to the
rio summit and its precursor, the bruntdland Commission.
An alternative deinition of the same issues come from the National
science Foundation Workgroup on Urban sustainability, who argue
for
a deinition of sustainability that focuses on sustainable lives and
livelihoods rather than the question of sustaining development. by
‘sustainable livelihoods’ we refer to processes of social and ecological
reproduction situated within diverse spatial contexts. We understand
processes of social and ecological reproduction to be non-linear,
indeterminate, contextually speciic, and attainable through multiple
pathways … Within the terms of this deinition, sustainability:
• entails necessarily lexible and ongoing processes rather than ixed
and certain outcomes;
• Transcends the conventional dualism of urban versus rural, local
versus global, and economy versus environment; and
• supports the possibility of diversity, difference, and local contingency rather than the imposition of global homogeneity.
Across the multiplicity of concrete situations, the sustainability of
local livelihood practices articulates with global-scale socioeconomic
and bio-chemical systems in complex, indeterminate, and poorly
understood ways. recent ecological and social theory proposes that
socio-ecological processes comprise non-linear dynamic systems that
do not tend to equilibrium. 2
alternative urban development
systemic drivers:
• Participatory
systems and
mechanisms
• Infrastructure
and technology
• building, design
and landscape
standards
• economic
processes and
value chains
• (In)equality
Fiscal policy:
tariffs, taxes and
land-use levies
enforcement
capacity
spatial
development
frameworks
Capable
democratic
local state
spatial
regulation: landuse guidelines
and zoning
enforcement
capacity
133
democratic system:
• Participatory
mechanisms
linked to policy,
budgetary and
spatial decisionmaking
• Vibrant
civil society
associational life
• Free speech and
independent media
• Autonomous action
Normative Framework: right-to-the-city,
pluralism, social justice and poverty reduction
Institutional dimensions
of sustainable urban development
FIGURE 7.1
This constructivist approach to sustainable urban development obviously resonates with the theoretical model I explored in Chapter 5.
Admittedly, this deinition is not the most accessible and easy to
understand, but in its focus on process rather than outcome, contingency as opposed to homogeneity, it opens a much more productive
line of enquiry about the dynamics and potential of sustainable urban
development. Practically, it means that sustainability is consistent
with robustness and lexibility in problem-solving within localities,
rather than management towards certain, preconceived outcomes. It
is often the common drive to predetermined outcomes that hems
in democratic contestation because certain urban features become
deined as ‘world class’ and become the de facto focus of local
politics, as was demonstrated in Chapter 4. In other words, this
deinitional approach entails a shift in thinking from achieving set
standards and single ‘solutions’ to empowerment for local problemsolving based on diverse knowledge. Consequently, the role of local
knowledge and practice is vital, which suggests that there is much to
learn from alternative ways of addressing sustainability in different
contexts. but local solutions, conscious of larger power structures
and systems of knowledge, need a vibrant political sphere and radical
democratic culture to emerge in all their richness. This implies that
134
city futures
‘sustainability is fundamentally a political rather than a technological
or design problem, in the sense that the greatest barrier to sustainability lies in the absence of institutional designs for deining and
implementing sustainable practices in local contexts.’3
The heart of an alternative urban development model is a clearer
institutional conceptualization of how to advance more sustainable
social and ecological reproduction dynamics within a highly exploitative capitalist economic system that relentlessly produces uneven
spatial outcomes that reinforce multiple lines of inequality. This
institutional model is best explained with the help of a diagramatic
representation (see Figure 7.1).
In this model it is assumed that the preconditions for more sustainable urban lives and livelihoods are: (i) an effective democratic local
state committed to a vibrant public sphere; (ii) an effective spatial
development framework that can give expression to the developmental
objectives of the state and citizens; (iii) a plural, dense and active
civil society that engages the state and business sectors around the
normative aspirations of the city; and (iv) a (nominal) normative
commitment to the right to the city, pluralism, social justice and
poverty reduction, which serve as parameters for public discourses
about the identity and futures of the city. of course, where these
conditions are underdeveloped or absent, the primary focus of an
alternative urban development approach is to bring these conditions
to life. In the remainder of this section I will explain the key normative anchors of an alternative urban development model: namely, a
rights-based approach and the importance of radical democracy as a
preferred model of democratic institutionalization; and what I refer
to as systemic drivers of urban sustainability, because these are the
practical sites of political struggle that will advance more sustainable
lives and livelihoods.
The right to the city
The literature on human rights distinguishes between irst-, secondand third-generation rights. First-generation rights typically include
civil and political rights; for example, the right to life and political
participation. second-generation rights include economic, social and
cultural rights. Third-generation rights are often termed solidarity
alternative urban development
135
rights, and include, inter alia, the right to peace or the right to a
clean environment.4 Progressives who adopt a rights-based framework
regard these different categories of rights as indivisible and mutually
reinforcing.
If one locates the rights-based normative framework in an urban
setting, it is clear that various basic services such as water, shelter,
waste management and access to energy are found in the realm of
the right to life as irst-generation rights. This is complemented by
political franchise, which in the urban context inds expression in
the focus on local democracy and various gradations of participatory
governance. These aspects have been the main focus of mainstream
urban policy. Clearly the demand for political representation at the
local or municipal level and the afirmation of the right to food, water
and shelter are crucial for individual and household advancement in
the city. but the preoccupation with these basic or irst-generation
human rights drives international support for transparency in local
government elections and for basic infrastructure provision, at the
expense of deining a more nuanced and demanding agenda of urban
transformation in which more complex rights can be addressed for
increasingly large numbers of people who live in the cities of the
south.5 The critical issue is to recognize that a holistic approach that
incorporates the full ambit of rights cannot stop with an individual
or household focus if translated into a programmatic agenda of the
state. In fact, addressing the full spectrum of rights transcends the
individualistic dangers of a narrow rights-based discourse and brings
to the fore the pivotal role of the state and multi-scalar actions to
address the complex interdependencies between different categories
of rights.
However, the ongoing focus on electoral and participatory democracy, as well as on protecting other individual rights (freedom from
discrimination, freedom of expression, etc.) within mainstream
urban development policy approaches, may marginalize new efforts
to advance second-generation socio-economic rights. These secondgeneration rights are achieved through the sustainable ongoing delivery of affordable urban services to households (not individuals) and
through viable service administration and inances, not just through
infrastructural investment. Hence the emphasis in Figure 7.1 on capable
136
city futures
democratic local states. How this ongoing service delivery is achieved
will vary greatly between urban and rural contexts. What is important
to consider, apart from the underemphasis of second-generation
socio-economic rights, is a further gap in political commitment and
action at the urban scale to provide third-generation rights such
as the right to a safe environment, to mobility or to public spaces.
These gaps persist despite the fact that many countries have adopted
a comprehensive rights approach in their formal constitutions and
legal frameworks. For example, the right to freedom of movement,
safety, environmental protection and economic opportunity are recognized in both the south African Constitution and the International
declaration on Human rights. What is signiicant, though, is that the
urban planning and enforcement mechanisms that protect or enable
these rights are poorly understood, and hence seldom in place. A
vital part of an alternative urban development agenda is to make this
lacuna in urban theory and policy visible, and to address it; hence
the emphasis in the framework diagram (Figure 7.1) on iscal and
spatial regulatory instruments at the urban scale. In other words, the
argument here is that if the full gamut of human rights are to be
exercised collectively, and at various geographical scales across the city
region (individual, house, property, neighbourhood, municipality and
city region), then they must be institutionalized through regulatory
systems. Third-generation rights form part of the public good and
of what I termed earlier public investment areas (Figure 4.1).
Thus, clearly, implementation of these second- and third-generation
rights rests on robust and capable sub-national state structures.
embryonic postcolonial local state structures, unfunded decentralization and privatization all militate against strong urban government
in the global south. Consequently, despite obvious wealth being
concentrated in large urban areas, the poor are trapped in secondclass strata of the city that might one day provide for universal
irst-generation rights, but will never facilitate full urban citizenship.6 For me, a rights-based normative anchoring of an alternative
urban agenda is helpful because it underscores the centrality of a
strong, effective, intentional and democratic local state, contrary to
the neoliberal agenda of the past twenty-ive years. Furthermore, it
brings to the fore in a useful way the importance of articulating,
alternative urban development
137
without sublimating, individual and collective imperatives, local and
regional scalar dynamics, and cultural, political, economic and spatial
imperatives of more just urban development futures. This agenda is
usefully and productively summarized under the sign ‘the right to
the city’. However, a fundamental part of my argument is that the
struggles for the right to the city and its incremental realization (and,
by extension, institutionalization) is only likely to arise in a context
of radical democracy, as explained in Chapter 5.7
Systemic drivers of sustainable urban development
The predominant focus on the mainstream urban development
approach to slums and strengthening associations of the poor can
lead to a lopsided approach that unwittingly (if one is to be generous)
creates a context in which the status quo can be reproduced indeinitely whilst the political rhetoric is bloated on feel-good references
to sustainability and poverty reduction. Thus, in this section I suggest
that the primary focus of an alternative urban development framework
must be on the large infrastructure, design and economic systems that
account for the routine reproduction of the built environment and the
inancial and symbolic economies it depends upon.
Participatory systems and mechanisms The now vast literature on participatory democracy makes it clear that in the absence of vibrant,
multiple and endowed participatory democratic avenues that can
impact on local government decision-making and prioritization, it is
unlikely that urban elites will introduce or inance policies that will
lead to redistributive or regulatory measures that allow for urban
resources to be distributed more equitably. Put differently, in most
cities in the global south, extreme levels of inequality and human
brutalization through widespread chronic poverty can be tolerated.
Unless the urban poor have democratic means by which their interests
can be represented and inserted into allocative processes, they will
simply be ignored, and urban accumulation policies with only shortterm proitability objectives will predominate. Thus, an important
and basic conditional urban driver is effective political voice through
formal participatory democratic systems. In this regard, the raft of
mechanisms and innovations proposed by the Good Governance
138
city futures
Campaign of UN–Habitat is informative even if politically underqualiied, as demonstrated in earlier chapters.
Infrastructure and technolog y The contemporary global economic system
is clearly anchored in city-regions across the world, with higher levels
of aggregation manifested in the traditional triad countries of the
North. However, a number of so-called global city-regions in the
south are increasingly important nodal points in this multi-scalar
space economy – for example, Mexico City, são Paulo, Lagos, dakar,
Johannesburg, singapore, shanghai, Mumbai, bangalore, and so on. It
is in these cities, with their very high concentrations of service economic sectors such as inance, insurance, real estate, tourism–leisure,
and so on, that the greatest volume of general value-added (GVA)
is generated inside national economies; this makes them particularly
important and sometimes powerful in national urban systems. The
new economic sectors that potentially embody very large volumes
of capital rely on a series of particular infrastructures which one can
cluster as ‘connectivity infrastructures’; these include telecommunications, cheap energy, transportation, and logistical hubs such as
ports, freeways and airports. Moreover, the new globalized skilled
managerial class that runs these companies that represent the upper
end of economic sectors are increasingly seen as demanding leisure
and residential infrastructures that can guarantee a hassle-free, insulated, safe, culturally ‘rich’ (i.e. the highbrow culture of museums,
galleries, opera houses, etc.) and insulated existence in cities invariably marked by great social divides. An important evangelist for the
lifestyle demands of this small segment of ‘world class’ cities has
been richard Florida, who promotes the importance of the creative
class.8 The point about all this is that most cities in the global south
fall into a trap whereby they come to deine their priorities in terms
of what they need to do to become ‘world class’ and competitive, as
these sorts of infrastructure investments invariably crowd out public
infrastructures that would beneit the majority of urban citizens and
affordable basic needs infrastructures for the urban poor. In Chapter
4, I presented a diagrammatic presentation of infrastructure prioritization that tends to respond only, or predominantly, to the needs of
the knowledge economy and business interests (see Figure 4.1).
alternative urban development
139
An alternative development approach must be able to put forward
a critical argument about urban infrastructure that leads to: (i) a
dematerialization of these systems (and the private-sector production
processes that feed off them); and (ii) a prioritizing of public-interest
and poverty-reducing investment over and above narrow growthsupporting ones. dematerialization refers to actions taken by industry
and the state ‘to develop industrial processes that are inherently
more benign and [lead to] production and consumption patterns
that reduce the low of matter and energy per unit of economic
activity’.9 of course, it is not possible to suggest that one can be
achieved at the expense of the other, but the alternative perspective
is about forcing a debate about the trade-off that has to be made,
and to link such a necessarily political engagement back to the normative standards of the city. This debate is becoming increasigly
easy to win as private-sector opinion leans increasingly in similar
directions.10 Figure 4.1 depicted the macro balancing-act that urban
actors must accomplish as routine decisions are made about what
infrastructure will be invested in, maintained and promoted. one can
surmise that a progressive coalition of urban actions and networks
will address critical economic performance-related infrastructure,
but in appropriate balance with adequate levels of investment in
public infrastructures and through technological modalities that are
increasingly environmentally benign and that improve the labourmarket absorptive capacity of the economy. This takes us on to the
next two areas of systemic focus.
Building, design and landscape standards Among the most potent capabilities of the (local) state is its regulatory power with regard to land
use, public space regulations, and building standards and norms,
which pertain to materials and architectural and heritage-related
norms. For example, in the formal economy, building plans typically
need to be approved by municipalities, and the criteria for approval
can be amended to promote new ways of building and improving the
energy and water eficiencies of the built environment. These change
drivers also, potentially, lend themselves to multi-class environmental
alliances that can build on a sustainable development platform. More
importantly, where the local state has a massive public investment
140
city futures
drive to provide low-income housing or support for in situ upgrading
of slums, it can use its own procurement muscle to enforce new
standards, which in turn can be used to leverage larger marketwide shifts in consumer and investor preferences. An important
example in this regard is, ironically, the neoconservative governor
of California state in the UsA, whose administration is aggressively
promoting solar-based energy solutions for the built environment
along with tough emissions-reduction standards for the state and
private sector to achieve a 30 per cent decrease in greenhouse gases
by 2016.11 It is fairly obvious that unless the inputs that go into the
construction of the built environment are progressively deined in
terms of ‘dematerialization’ criteria it is unlikely that the models of
city building will produce the necessary environmental eficiencies
to witness a visible reduction in greenhouse gas emissions.
Another closely related progressive imperative that sits at the
interface of building regulations, public space guidelines and infrastructural priorities is public transport. Given the insane growth in
automobile use in the emerging regions of the global south, especially
Asia, it is clear that unless a commitment to safe, widespread and
affordable public transport becomes the linchpin in alternative urban
development models, it is unlikely that the livelihood prospects of
the urban poor will be improved or better environmental outcomes
realized. The impressive ‘turnaround’ in dominant urban design and
development cultures of Curitiba and bogotá remain important reference points for progressives. These cities prove that public transport
is a popular, legitimate and achievable platform around which to
build broad-based coalitions. Moreover, once the legitimacy of a
commitment to public transport is secured politically and reinforced
by adequate budgetary allocations, then it becomes much easier to
push for more sustainable standards and technologies with regard to
energy, solid and liquid waste management and water consumption;
all profound systemic drivers of urban exclusion and unsustainable
processes.
Economic processes and value chains over the decades since the rio
earth summit in 1992 there have been profound normative shifts
in the domain of private capital. A number of voluntary regulatory
alternative urban development
141
frameworks now exist which extend from fair-trade practices to
respecting worker rights, and increasingly touch on the imperative of
internalizing environmental externalities into the pricing structures
of private companies. It seems as if the core argument of environmental economics about the externalization of environmental costs
is striking a chord among the ‘enlightened’ sector of global business
leadership as evidenced in the rhetoric spouted at the annual davos
corporate love-fest. It is of course easy to be totally sceptical about
the seriousness or depth of these shifts and to write them off as
window dressing or a cynical attempt to appeal to shifting consumer
sentiments in the North without changing the exploitative logic of
capitalist forms of accumulation. I think this is an error. It seems
that such an approach fails to appreciate the institutional logic of
private irms and how certain shifts in norms and predispositions can
instigate profound structural effects that extend beyond the control
of any one company.
It is obviously beyond the scope of this book to explore these
issues in any depth, except to suggest that there is a lot of scope
for principled partnerships and coalitions with enlightened corporate
interests that want to position themselves in ethical and environmentally sustainable terms, to the extent that they can improve the
working conditions of their employees, with knock-on effects for
their suppliers and clients. The point is that once this political agenda
begins to internalize environmental costs and inluence the entire
value chain, the consequences can be far-reaching and potentially
systemic. Given the disproportionate power that business needs and
interests exercise over urban development priorities in the minds of
public-sector leaders and managers, it is vital that activists striving for
an alternative urban path exploit the new opportunities for regulation
and redistribution that this area allows for.
(In)equality even though inequality is endemic to capitalist modes
of accumulation, it is evident that the level of inequality a particular
society is willing to contemplate and tolerate differs greatly, not only
between the North and south but also among countries that fall
into these two categories. In an urban context, iscal instruments,
redistribution formulas and land-use guidelines can greatly shape the
142
city futures
nature and extent of inequality. one of the most important dimensions of an alternative urban development agenda is to address social
and economic inequalities directly by irst and foremost adopting
progressive taxation systems and then enforcing them with minimal
room for corruption. This implies vigilant civil society oversight and
mature political leadership.
Fiscal instruments are particularly important in ensuring that
urban services are priced on the assumption that the fundamental
human rights of all urban citizens make them eligible for free basic
services that are essential – drinking water, cleansing, sanitation,
shelter from the elements, affordable energy and safety. In contexts
with widespread poverty it is imperative that municipal tariff systems
are based on a stepped formula whereby the unemployed and poor
have free access to a minimum quantum of water and energy, and
consumers who can afford to pay for services cross-subsidize the
usage of the poor along with the general iscus. south Africa has
made important strides in this regard but has a long way to go to
make it adequate for the needs of the poor.12 The other dimension
that perpetuates unequal access to urban resources and opportunities
is land markets. It is widely acknowledged that the current form of
globally embedded economic development in cities produces greater
spatial segregation and social balkanization. Land-use instruments
can go a long way to counteract and ameliorate these effects if local
states are politically compelled to arrest and reverse urban segregation
and fragmentation. For example, the magisterial review of urban
planning instruments by robert riddell offers encyclopaedic details
on how to achieve more integrated, equitable and sustainable land-use
outcomes.13 so the issue is not an absence of precedent or policy
tools but rather an unwillingness on the part of urban governments
to deploy these instruments, which in turn can be traced back to
insuficient democratic pressure on states to make such recalcitrance
very expensive.
The point of this section is to demonstrate that it is possible
to think in very practical terms about the primary pressure that
can be targeted to shift the underlying drivers of urban systems.
However, this approach does presuppose a democratic system of
urban governance, opportunities for radical and progressive groups
alternative urban development
143
to engage with decision-making and planning processes, and an open
public sphere that allows for alternative approaches to be tabled and
advanced. It also assumes that guiding instruments in the form of
spatial development frameworks inform more precise regulatory tools
in the domains of urban inancial policy and land-use management.
These conditions are clearly not in place in many cities in the global
south, which does preclude the possibility of progressives pursuing
these lines of radical incrementalism. In those places it makes more
sense to opt for advocacy and militant direct action that can lead
to the institutionalization of participatory democratic systems. It
is becoming very dificult for nation-states with global integration
ambitions to eschew formal democracy even if they remain demagogic
at heart.
Political economy of urban transformation
At the heart of the crises of urban development described in Chapter
2 is a contemporary dynamic whereby urban spaces are increasingly
marked by deeper lines of spatial fragmentation, social and economic
segregation, and of course inequality. To capture the systemic nature
of these factors, which is left underdiscussed and undertheorized in
mainstream policy discourses of the World bank, Cities Alliances
and UN–Habitat, it is important to explore in a slightly theoretical
vein how these contemporary features of urban life come to be. This
section summarizes understanding in contemporary urban studies of
segregation, fragmentation and inequality, and the causes of their
(re)production.
In general terms, urban segregation can be seen as an outcome
of urban inequality in capitalist cities, which is reinforced by urban
management and planning ideas that valorize the ordered fragmentation of urban space. Iris Marion Young provides a useful working
deinition of segregation and its general causes:
[s]egregation consists in an enforced separation of groups that conines
members of some groups to speciic areas, or excludes members of a
group from speciic spaces, institutions, or activities, or regulates the
movements of members of segregated groups … group based residential
segregation is common in modern democracies with self-consciously
differentiated groups. Where it exists, it is the product of class and
144
city futures
income differentials combined with a variety of discriminatory actions
and policies of individuals, private institutions, and government.14
This coincides with the perspective of savage et al., which regards
segregation as the spatial expression of inequality.15 Inequality can
be mapped in terms of differential access to economic resources
(wages, land and knowledge) and collective consumption goods and
services (i.e. education, health service provision, town planning and
transport), social standing (i.e. status) and political power.16 Capitalism
(in all its variants) is fundamentally an economic, social and political
system that produces and exploits inequalities in society. In this light,
it is clear that inequality is always multidimensional and the various
elements tend to operate in a mutually reinforcing manner, linked to
(but not fully determined by) the political-economic reproduction of
society. It is this character of inequality that makes it a particularly
intractable problem. Furthermore, it is impossible to understand the
reproduction of inequality outside of an appreciation of how group
identities and subjectivities are reproduced in the city, in speciic
neighbourhoods or enclaves.
Initially, in classical functionalist and structural (Weberian and
Marxist) approaches to urban studies, identities were seen in static
and deterministic ways. In other words, it was assumed that economic
and political forces (e.g. racism) determined the subject position of
people – for example, as working class or black working class. These
ascriptions of identity, linked to people’s relation to the means of production, were seen as adequate to explain subjectivity. Furthermore,
‘[s]ocial divisions were thus predominantly seen as deriving from
economic forces and organized around class.’17 This approach was
uprooted with the introduction of the notion of ‘difference’ by feminist, psychoanalytical, postcolonial and poststructural theorizations
in social theory more generally, and urban studies more speciically,
during the 1980s.18 As a result, there was ‘a move away from thinking
about identity and subjectivity as static, essential categories, to seeing
them as shifting, decentred and multiply located’.19 In addition to
regarding identity as multiple and hyphenated, it is also necessary to
recognize that ‘identities are also “hybrid”, that is, overdetermined,
and structured by the unconscious desires in a relation of alterity
to the other and the self’, as explained in Chapter 5. 20 For this
alternative urban development
145
reason, it is impossible to tease out speciic dimensions of identity
– for example, gender, race or nationality – in pure forms. on the
contrary, the various dimensions of hybrid identities are mutually
constitutive and shaped by various spatialized experiences – locality
(home, street, neighbourhood, city), nation and transnational territories. 21 Lastly, identities are also luid, always under construction
and fundamentally open-ended. The multiple spatialities in the city
provide the raw material for the incessant work of making identity
in particular places. 22 This theoretical position makes it impossible to
read off from a person’s residence (e.g. in a ghetto or gated community) or job description (e.g. in a factory, ofice or as a home-worker)
their political and economic interests. Also, it makes it impossible
to assume the ‘cultural character’ of a neighbourhood, based on the
class proile of the inhabitants.
such a nuanced conceptual approach to identity and subjectivity
invariably complicates understanding the reproduction of segregation
and inequality, because there is always a margin of complicity in the
functioning of regimes of difference; for power works through difference to reproduce inequality. With the intensiication of awareness
of, and attention to, multiplying differences in postmodern societies,
urban inequalities – manifested in various forms of segregation – are
intensifying.
Cities, therefore, are becoming places where far from encountering
difference, people actively contrive to avoid it. different social classes,
increasingly, are forced to follow different trajectories through space,
they inhabit different zones for work and leisure, and rarely, if ever, do
they unexpectedly encounter the ‘other’. The ideal urban environments
are places of control rather than disorder. This city of difference is
not a place where diversity is celebrated on the ground. It is a place
of watchfulness and suspicion – of enclaves of homogeneity, perhaps
even community – a place where mingling with strangers is to be
avoided. 23
Many forces and factors contribute to urban fragmentation and
divisions: the operation and functioning of land and housing markets;
planning aimed at social control and modernist functionalism;
consumer preferences of particularly the middle classes, who seek
safety and exclusivity; symbolic and psychic attachments to particular
146
city futures
places; the physical form of the city and how it actively prevents
certain categories of people (e.g. those with disabilities, or women
or children) moving around or accessing services and goods. 24 It is
vital to relate these more structural factors to questions of identity
and power. ‘different marginalities, such as race, gender, or sexuality, or other forms of exclusion, interrelate to concentrate sites of
power disadvantage and are not simply a question of special needs
or lifestyle but are embedded in power relations, whether these be
symbolic or real.’25
In other words, whilst accepting the validity of a difference perspective, which foregrounds the complexity of subjectivity and the
relationship between place and identity construction, it is also possible
to be clear that unequal power relations operate through spatial
differentiation to concentrate a lack of access to bases of power.
Where these perspectives often fall short, however, is in relation to
the appropriate role of public policy in addressing power disadvantage,
including that reproduced through the segregation and fragmentation
of urban space, leaving deepening inequality in its wake.
Unravelling political opportunity
driving an urban transformation agenda is much like detective work.
due to the historical depth of urban dynamics, the impact of multiple
spatialities that coexist and jostle in the city, and the complex socialities that arise from every shifting term of identity and community,
iguring out the most effective routes to a transformative agenda
requires painstaking attention to detail with a heightened sense of
the political. In Chapter 1 I introduced the idea of the city as a
political terrain with various domains of political action. However,
to understand the dynamics of each of these domains (and their
interfaces), following Patsy Healey, it is useful to pay particular
attention to three dimensions of power dynamics. 26
The irst dimension is speciic episodes that unfold as a drama
that can be read in terms of plot-lines, competing actors and pointed
towards particular outcomes with differential consequences for the
different actors implicated. In an increasingly globalized world the
‘big’ episodes that structure attention and a sense of political unfolding – that is, the city’s storyline – are typically large-scale investments
alternative urban development
147
in freeways, ports, wireless meshes, signature buildings or museums,
international sporting events and so forth. These episodes provide a
set of clues about where power and inluence coagulate in the city
– that is, the identity of the actors and the nature of the strategies
deployed to secure their interest. At the same time, the episodes that
fall outside of public and media attention are equally informative
because they point to the moments that pass by unnoticed, and often
these decisions are even more revealing about the nature of power
relations in the city.
second, interests in the city are channelled and aggregated through
various networks and coalitions that often span the social domains
– the state, private sector and civil society – that analysts too easily
separate out. The discourses mobilized by these interest-based networks and coalitions provide important clues about how political
priorities are framed as a problem statement, which ineluctably leads
to particular kinds of solutions. Thus, in many cities today, centrist
and right-wing coalitions would present the need to become world
class and globally competitive as the primary motivation for everything that gets done in a city. More importantly, these rationalizations
would become unquestionable common sense, skewing the bias of
democratic and corporatist deliberation forums in the direction of
policy recipes that adopt the same assumptions. If progressives are
to succeed in advancing the agenda mapped out above, it is vital
that they remain vigilant about these tendencies and hold explicit
and clear views about how particular policy biases are mobilized
and sustained in the city.
Third, Healey reminds us that urban politics are embedded in
particular governance cultures where a number of deeply engrained
values and informal norms underpin the relationships and behaviour
of urban actors. This point is particularly germane if one accepts my
argument that urban politics are always deeply relational, shifting/
adaptive and subject to discursively shaped norms in the public
sphere regarding what is appropriate at a given moment. It is only
with an intimate knowledge of urban political actors, institutions
and dominant norms that epistemic communities will be able to
successfully advance alternative agendas that reach down to the
systemic level of the city. on this note, let me clarify what I mean
148
city futures
by epistemic communities, painted here as pivotal change agents in
the city yet to come.
Driving urban transformation:
epistemic communities/strategic networks
Given the complexity of building an effective politics that can simultaneously impact on the systemic drivers of the city and deepen
democratic institutions, it is appropriate to deine my conception of
the change drivers that are most likely to inhabit interstitial spaces
between the various domains of urban politics. 27
Ideas matter. Ideas are indispensable for interpreting what is wrong
in our cities, how it can be ixed, and what is better than what we are
settling for at the moment. Ideas can ignite creative energy, resistance
and movements for change. Ideas can also ix the future, creating
the conviction that we are trapped by the powers of geography, time
and capital lows. Much of the impasse in urban development stems
from the incorrect belief that we are circumscribed by very narrow
parameters for manoeuvre at this particular juncture in history. This
storyline is unconvincing because much can be done to break away
from the mainstream tropes of urban development critiqued in earlier
chapters. In the earlier parts of this chapter I have not been proposing any particular recipe for urban development (not that recipes
don’t have their place), but have sought to persuade the reader that
endogenous ideas can be generated through focused processes of debate
and engagement about dealing with the nerve endings of inequality, environmental degradation, and economic and social exclusion.
speciically, my suggestion is that unless more coherent ‘epistemic
communities’ emerge in our cities, we are unlikely to generate the
kinds of ideas and creativity that will point the way out of our
condition of urban crisis.
The notion of ‘epistemic community’ is derived from the idea that
knowledge-generating collectives can be assembled or networked to
enable a vigorous exchange of perspectives within a broader shared
commitment to ind practicable ‘solutions’ to intractable social and
economic problems. This conception builds, on the one hand, on
ideas about the roles of ‘organic intellectuals’ in society as formulated
by Antonio Gramsci, and redeployed by Cornell West, edward said
alternative urban development
149
and stuart Hall.28 on the other hand, it draws on the Aristotelian idea
of phronesis, as advanced by planning theorists bent Flyvbjerg, Jean
Hillier and Michael Gunder. Phronesis essentially refers to the skill
and reason of practical judgement ‘in the moment of action’. 29 It is
an intellectual virtue that strives to realize good and effective action
in complex and unfolding circumstances. In Gunder’s approach, it
is particularly attuned to unequal power relations and to inding the
most pragmatic and strategic path forward to effect urban policy
actions that can produce greater equity and social justice.
by making the link between organic intellectuals and the practice
of phronesis, one can argue that the purpose of the epistemic community is fundamentally to challenge conventional orthodoxy (the
mainstream) about what is possible and not possible in terms of
transformative urban development agendas. expounding on said’s
understanding, Ashcroft and Alhuwalia remind us that ‘[o]rganic
intellectuals … are those who are actively involved in society, striving to change it rather than maintain traditions. Unlike traditional
intellectuals who “remain in place”, organic intellectuals “are always
on the move”’,30 in search of workable alternatives that can become
hegemonic. Cornell West develops this idea by casting organic intellectuals as catalysts who stay ‘attuned to what the mainstream has to
offer – its paradigms, viewpoints and methods – yet maintains a
grounding in afirming and enabling subcultures of criticism’.31 This
is a vital aspect of an epistemic community’s role – understanding
the rationalities and governmental technologies of control whilst
recognizing its inherent limits and potential for critical subversion
to serve more insurgent interests of the excluded and discriminated
in the city. one aspect of fulilling this role is to engage with the
totality of urban development policies as encapsulated in municipal
development plans or city development strategies and the institutions these planning frameworks are embedded in. Another aspect
is to identify the most strategic leverage points to push mainstream
development agendas beyond their own limits towards a more redistributive, inclusive and integrated footing, which grafts on to the
systemic drivers explored above (Figure 7.1).
There will undoubtedly be the danger that an epistemic community loses its sense of what constitutes creative alternatives that can
150
city futures
resonate with present crises, for what is cutting-edge and innovative
is profoundly contextual, subjective and generational.32 It is therefore
crucial that an epistemic community remains attuned to its own
potential for new orthodoxies and builds into its functioning and
identity, the mechanisms for critique, renewal and even termination,
if the need arises.33 An implication of this approach is that such an
epistemic community (of organic intellectuals) cannot remain (or
even arise?) within the state or in highly institutionalized civil society
organizations. It must inhabit a space in the border zones between
the state, civil society, the grassroots, academia and the business
sector. It must be open to multiple perspectives and practice the
art of interpretation and translation in order to bring new meanings and understandings to life. It must keep an ear irmly to the
ground in order to know and feel the various pulses of the city and
its changing moods.34
Fundamentally, an epistemic community is, to my mind, about
opening up vital debates and enlarging the public sphere through
the projection of iconic ideas, rooted in sound analysis, about viable
alternative ways of city building. However, the progressive ideas that
emanate from an epistemic community should be embedded in a
political framework of strategic action across the various domains of
urban politics discussed in Chapter 5. In this way urban development
policy counterpoints are placed within a relational chain of actors
and agendas that are continuously analysed and calibrated to deal
with concrete problems, challenges and hegemonic discourses. In
this respect, the biggest challenge is to engage in an informed and
intelligent way with economic processes and actors, given the constitutive function of economic well-being in realizing a host of social
and environmental objectives. differently put, along with exploring
and foregrounding the cultural complexity of the city there is a need
to adopt a political economy lens in identifying strategic actions to
address urban inequality and fragmentation. This is easier wished for
than achieved, especially during the current moment when neoliberal
economic ideas remain hegemonic and entrenched, particularly among
government leaders and powerful private-sector interests.35 However,
if progressives and the various epistemic communities in which they
embed themselves focus on the institutionalized points of decision-
alternative urban development
151
making in urban governance processes, they can achieve progress.
In light of this I now turn to the inal aspect of institutionalizing
an alternative urban development approach in the heart of the city’s
multiple and overlapping planning systems.
Strategic entry points
In order to justify my focus on urban planning systems as the primary
institutional entry point for advancing an alternative urban agenda, I
need to make an explicit argument to link my conception of relational
radical democratic politics (mapped in Chapter 5) with the drivers
of the systemic change perspective, detailed above. This clariication
will be followed by a presentation of a typology of overlapping urban
planning systems. With regard to the former imperative, the most
economical way of drawing the conceptual linkages is to summarize
my assumptions as a series of interrelated propositions about the
preconditions required for transformative politics to take root in
the city.
Connecting the dots
First, effective and adaptive democratic public institutions (local
state) must exist. second, democratic local states will only remain
committed or interested in transformative urban policy if there is a
growing autonomous civil society sector capable of mobilizing around
its (diverse) interests in relation to the state and other power interests
in the society. Third, cities require enabling or supportive regulatory
environments in order for civil society actors and local state bodies
to engage effectively. In the absence of these there can be a fundamental disconnect between the disparate actors, essentially serving
the interests of a narrow and probably shrinking elite. Fourth, if an
enabling/open environment for local state–civil society exists there
is a need for a shared understanding of the issues that are critical
for the city’s sustainable enhancement or betterment. My proposal
is that the systemic drivers discussed earlier serve as fruitful entry
points in identiing such critical issues. Fifth, it is vital to structure
democratic deliberation on these critical issues of consequence, and
embed it in larger symbolic politics that shape the public discourses
and the shifting lines of hegemony. Issues of consequence refer, inter
152
city futures
alia, to aspects of the underlying drivers of equitable access to urban
opportunities, such as suitable and affordable land for the urban poor,
quality education, employment and affordable public transport. sixth,
transformative politics require an explicit articulation of local-level
struggles around household and neighbourhood reproductive issues
and the city-wide issues of consequence that arise from the systemic
drivers of urban reproduction. Lastly, planning systems (not exclusively or necessarily) offer a unique opportunity to facilitate local and
city-wide articulations because, ideally, planning matrices consider and
address long-term structural factors, their spatialities and potential
social-cultural embedding in order to achieve traction. building on
these propositions, I will now explore the speciic potentialities of
planning, having irst presented a typology of planning.
A working typology of planning
In the interest of space I use a diagramatic tool to summarize the
various types of planning, each with different reaches and impacts
on the city (see Figure 7.2). I will now briely describe each form
of urban planning.
strategic plan
regional development plan
business
improvement
district plans
la 21
Local
community
plans
Transport planning
FIGURE 7.2
Antipoverty
Health planning
Local
community
plans
Housing planning
sectoral planning
Urban design imperatives
Master plan
Led
business
improvement
district plans
overlapping dimensions of urban planning
alternative urban development
153
Master planning This is the most conventional form of city-wide planning. Typically it is meant to provide a rationale for urban land use and
serve as the basis for more detailed zoning systems and codes. The
scope and reach of master planning varies from country to country.
For example, in brazil master planning remains a vital instrument to
deine land use in progressive terms. The statute of the City, promulgated in 2001, is a potential instrument for redistribution through
land-use reforms which deine social uses that advantage the poor as
more important than economic uses that favour the elite.36 However,
in most countries master planning is largely ignored and only serves
to inform land-use provisions at very general levels. Nonetheless, it
is important to bear in mind that despite the limited effectiveness of
master plans to ensure equitable and sustainable land-use patterns in
the city, they remain an important starting point for regulatory systems
and land-use provisions that structure urban space.
Sectoral planning The major functional areas of urban development
can be captured here – transport, education, (primary) health, energy
provision, water, waste management and sanitation. These services
tend to consume the bulk of the day-to-day focus and resources
of municipalities. Also, planning in these areas tends to reinforce
the departmental silos that continue to characterize most municipal
governments. These plans, via departmental champions, also tend to
structure the budget of the municipality: each sectoral plan with its
respective capital and operating expenditure splits, which makes it
dificult to reorient and reposition the underlying drivers of municipal
priorities and actions. It is common for sectoral planning to be
closely tied to basic-needs-oriented development approaches, policy
preferences that tend to be, at best, ameliorative even if important.
Multi-sectoral planning during the late 1980s and 1990s the importance
of more integrated development approaches came to the fore. A forerunner in this regard was the environmental perspective encapsulated
for municipalities in Local Agenda 21 strategies, which arose out of
the UNCed summit in rio de Janeiro in 1992. since then there has
been a proliferation of cross/inter-sectoral policy perspectives that
are applicable at city level. For example, local economic development
154
city futures
policy frameworks seek to tie together the impact the municipality
has on the regional economy it is embedded in as an economic actor
in its own right (with a substantial asset base and various forward
and backward linkages in the economy) and as a structuring force of
various types of markets and their eficiency and equitability. other
multi-sectoral development approaches include: social development,
HIV/AIds prevention and mitigation, poverty reduction frameworks, and, more recently, climate change adaptation and mitigation
strategies. These strategic imperatives lead to a different kind of
planning that seeks to bring various development imperatives, scales
and temporalities together, with a strong emphasis on institutional
design implications that either retard or facilitate cross-departmental
functioning. It is probably fair to say that multi-sectoral policy frameworks and planning have become commonly accepted, but their
actual implementation and embedding in municipal governments
remain very limited.
Area-based planning Another dimension of multi-sectorality has been
the rise of area-based approaches to effective poverty reduction or
(economic) urban renewal. Much of the urban poverty literature suggests that it is vital for municipalities to recognize the importance of
tailoring multidimensional responses to particular local communities/
neighbourhoods, because of the great variety of livelihood strategies
that poor communities adopt. This implies an institutional form
geared to respond to local speciicities in the form of multidisciplinary
teams that conduct multidimensional programmes in response to
various dimensions of urban poverty, such as health, economic exclusion, access to basic services, transport access, appropriate information
about labour market opportunities, and so on. such area-based interventions usually also require area-based planning and budgeting, which
allow for a practical mechanism to pursue multi-sectoral development
strategies. The other increasingly common dimension of area-based
approaches is the dramatic rise of urban renewal programmes tied to
business-improvement districts. In this instance area-based planning
allows private-sector interests to pool their resources and achieve
higher levels of public services, especially security and cleansing, for
the business district within which they operate.37
alternative urban development
155
This dimension of planning raises important questions about the
potential to connect spatial planning at the neighbourhood scale
with larger territorial scales of the city and the broader region it
is embedded in. I believe it is the articulation of local, city, and
regional scales that can give planning a powerful role in animating
a more precise urban and strategic urban politics because it sharpens the questions about the drivers of urban growth, inequality,
fragmentation, unsustainability and social divisions. At this point
it is appropriate to bring in the role and function of master plans,
regional development strategies and strategic planning.
Regional development planning This achieved greater recognition and
favour after the worst impact of the reagan/Thatcher years of
anti-planning and the abandonment in particular of comprehensive
and master plans. regional development strategies and plans arose
as a response to the infrastructure coordination imperatives that
accompanied the spatial effects of increasingly globalized production and value chains, which in turn made network infrastructures
and mobility systems crucial to city-based economic competition.38
Given that the labour-market catchment areas and various economic
circuits are stretched across local municipal boundaries, it became
increasingly accepted in europe and the Uk that regional planning
is an indispensable tool to foster the rationale for inter-agency and
intergovernmental coordination, especially after the radical institutional restructuring that accompanied the neoliberal managerialism
that reigned supreme in most urban areas across the world during
the 1980s and early 1990s.39
Strategic planning The other direction that macro-planning took after
the height of the neoliberal onslaught against planning was towards
a focus on strategic planning. I discussed this at some length in
Chapter 4.
signiicantly, as one looks across various contexts, it is apparent
that all of these diverse forms of planning are couched in participatory discourses that place a lot of emphasis on the processes of
conducting and implementing the plans, which in itself represents a
range of new frontiers for democratic politics that go signiicantly
156
city futures
further than traditional forms of claim-making to simply register the
demands of the urban poor and marginalized. However, if progressive civil society interests merely focus on exploiting the processual
potential of the different forms of planning and lose sight of the
importance of relating these different parts of the overall urban
planning system, then urban politics will remain limited; hence my
focus on the role of planning as an entry point to move forward a
highly strategic politics trained on the drivers of the urban system.
Planning systems as an entry point for
transformative urban development politics
Fundamentally, urban politics is about distributive justice. In other
words, it is about how public resources are deployed to ensure the
effective reproduction of the urban system whilst all citizens are
afforded an opportunity to exercise and realize their rights, especially
socio-economic rights to housing, health, culture, safety and digniied
employment. Commonly urban governance and management systems
are not geared to facilitate meaningful agonistic engagements between
interest groups and citizens to understand why resource allocation
happens in particular ways and why only sectional interests are served
by municipal policies and programmes. Instead, one could argue that
the uncritical promotion of participatory governance and planning
has been so focused on the politics of consensus and its concomitant
processes that they have masked the deep-rooted causal drivers of
urban inequality and social-ethnic balkanization.
As I have argued throughout this book, an important precondition
for a more radical urban politics is the promotion of dissensus: that
is, focused disagreement on how best to allocate public resources
across space (different neighbourhoods and quarters of the city) and
time (how to stagger and sequence public investment into various
categories of infrastructure and services). These fall into the realm
of what was earlier referred to as critical issues of consequence. In
keeping with radical democratic theory, explored in Chapter 5, the
point of dissensus is more to ensure that conlict is not suppressed,
but of course at a certain point diverse and divergent actors need also
to agree on how to act at a given moment or around particular interventions, even if all differences between them are not resolved.
alternative urban development
157
keeping this framework in mind, I will now tease out the speciic
links between planning and democratic decision-making. In the irst
instance it is clear that planning offers a vital framework and series
of moments to explore and deine normative horizons to anchor
political discourses and debate. Master planning, strategic plans and
regional development plans all tend to start with a set of normative
principles such as sustainability, integration, social justice, and so
forth, in relation to some conception of territoriality. of course,
the devil lies in the detail of interpretation, but it is incontrovertible
that such principles do offer important spaces for radical interests to
offer their perspectives on how to address the various problems of
the city. It therefore becomes vital that social movements and other
interest groups of the urban poor link their everyday struggles and
demands to these larger normative frameworks and give concrete
expression to the deeper systemic changes that will advance their
immediate cause. In this way, social movements can build an alternative set of registers and discourses about how normative principles
and horizons such as ‘integration’ or ‘sustainability’ or ‘endogenous
development’ link to everyday, incremental improvements, expressed
in sectoral and community-level plans. In fact, if the formal processes
to conduct local-level planning do not exist or are done in a narrow
technocratic fashion, grassroots movements can even construct their
own, autonomous plans, which become their reference points for
engaging in contestation and negotiation about resource allocation
decisions.40
Following this line of argument, I think it is clear that theorists
of urban politics undervalue the potential of community-level spatial
planning methodologies to cohere and focus grassroots activism and
economies of social care. Given that grassroots politics in poor communities are plagued by inter- and intra-organizational conlicts and
schisms which often render local activism ineffective and essentially
turned on itself, local patronage-based political practices further
exacerbate these tendencies. What community-level spatial planning
tools offer is a language and framework for diverse local actors to
negotiate, within a spatial register, how their respective agendas and
issues relate to one another. Furthermore, it becomes possible also
to see what the sequential relationship between various issues may
158
city futures
be. For example, the link between campaigns for access to water
and campaigns for improved health services in the same community
can be framed as one struggle in a situation where home-based care
for HIV/AIds sufferers places pressure on water usage in poor
households.
Typically, neighbourhood spatial planning processes attempt to
develop a localized vision and argument for what the community
needs to ind its fullest expression of cultures, resources and (diverse)
aspirations. It then proceeds to identify what exists, its quality, eficacy
and relevance, and what is absent, for the community to realize its
full potential. Local spatial planning processes do work from various
assumptions about the basic elements of a viable, vibrant and sustainable community and use such assumptions to structure and direct
discussions. For example, there is usually a desire for
diversity of use – housing, business, shopping, social, cultural and
health facilities, offering easy accessibility, opportunity and choice for
all; … a pedestrian-dominated public realm to facilitate a healthy social
life and provide an attractive, safe and human-scaled environment; a
green-space network that provides accessible open space, with effective
water, energy, wildlife and climate management; aesthetic identity that
is rooted in the collective identity of the region, relecting characteristics valued in the community.41
of course, in contexts of abject poverty where slum living and high
levels of informality are the norm, it may be too much to expect
such expansive development agendas or perspectives to emerge.
Nonetheless, even demands for the ‘right to housing’ and its consequences require one to pay attention to the larger spatial system
that expressing the right should be embedded in, which in turn will
only expand the remit of political claims and citizenship. such local
city-wide articulations are crucial for a more strategic, ambitious and
territorially connected urban politics under the banner of ‘the right to
the city’. I would therefore suggest that a crucial focus of democratic
practice should be spatially framed arguments for what the right
to the city means in practice. In this regard it may be an error to
dismiss or understate the potential value of various representation
tools, such as plans, drawings, illustrations and the like, to capture
and express local, co-determined visions. For example, many of
alternative urban development
159
the urbanism frameworks I have seen in brazil that underpin favela
upgrading programmes in salvador, rio de Janeiro and são Paulo
embody much of what I have in mind here. My question is, to what
extend are social movements using these registers to spatialise their
claims and so confront the deeper drivers of urban inequality and
social–ethnic balkanization?
There is, furthermore, a lot of scope to redirect the resources
stored in the large sectoral departments of municipalities to the
needs and interests of poor neighbourhoods if, through local strategic
spatial planning frameworks, community organizations target their
lobbying more precisely. Again, with the spread of participatory
discourses across the whole gamut of urban development, all sectoral
planning models now accept the importance of community engagement and inluence over both systems and technologies of delivery
and long-term objectives of these services. There is thus a lot of
scope to inluence the big sector plans – for example, transport,
health, education, energy – even if these sector departments are not
open to cross-sectoral coordination. What community-level spatial
planning brings to the fore is the unavoidability of cross-sectoral
coordination because the everyday economic and reproductive functions of neighbourhoods underscore the fundamental interconnection
between various inputs such as economic services, health care, public
parks, education, transport and so forth. Furthermore, a fundamental
shift towards more environmentally sustainable urban infrastructures
starts with community-level experiments which establish technological viability and provide the reference points for larger processes of
behavioural change.
Planning reform can come from either the top or the bottom but
is most likely to involve both dimensions. What is obvious is that
the tools and registers of various types of planning are thick with
potential to be mobilized for democratic engagement on questions
of urban transformation. Planning potentially renders the underlying
drivers of urban life more visible, and therefore subject to discourses
of change to achieve more fundamental reform of our cities. However,
as the disappointing history of urban planning reminds us, there is
nothing intrinsic to planning that produces better urban outcomes.
such outcomes have to emerge out of skilful articulation of urban
160
city futures
struggles that draws on planning for its potential uses, as intimated
earlier, but always located within a much broader repertoire of strategy
and tactics.
Conclusion
radical urbanists ind themselves in a paradoxical moment. on the
one hand, almost all of the central normative positions about social
justice, sustainability, democratic participation, and so forth, have
been accepted by the mainstream. on the other hand, whilst this door
is open, the imperatives of hard-nosed (neoliberal) models of urban
management and citizenship in a cut-throat globalized economy mean
that urban conditions, particularly economic and social inequalities,
are getting worse. My argument in this chapter has tried to transcend
this paradox. I deined the normative framework, anchored in the
symbolically rich discourse of the right to the city, and linked that to
concrete pressure points that can alter at a systemic level the logic of
urban processes. In this, the suggestion was that progressives need
to go much further with alternative policy proposals about how
speciically – that is, in technological, iscal, spatial and institutional
terms – these systemic drivers can be redeined in order to make
alternative urban futures material realities. However, they are unlikely
to succeed with this task if they fail to appreciate the constitutive
nature of political power and interests in the city; an insight that
forces the calibration of alternative policy agendas with street-smart
political strategies. In the next chapter I concretize this argument
even further by homing in on urban poverty.
8
Making a start towards
alternative city futures
You must understand that this is a place of high intention. This is a
city where they mend torn sails, or souls; hammer hearts back into
place; make ine adjustments in the eye; replace the mind’s printed
circuits. Where they roll the projector lens slowly till all the blurred,
shapeless forms snap into focus. but it is also an insupportable
mean, petty place, just as the upswept dark corners of our hearts
are mean and petty, with hard grey loors, bare walls, windows that
will not open … some light must always shine behind our lives; but
here it is very dificult for that light to get through.1
Irrespective of how dificult and brutal contemporary cities may
seem, there remains a great deal that we can imagine and do to alter
dramatically their future prospects. Progressives have access to a vast
reservoir of ideas, policies, strategies, sensibilities and experiences to
apply to the important challenge of letting the light pierce through
the darkness of dominant trends with regard to urban development
across the global south. In this inal chapter I will pull together the
overall argument of the book and home in on what progressives
can do to tackle urban poverty, in particular, and, more generally,
to bring lasting transformative change into the dominant reproduction of cities. Hopefully, by the end, it will be clear that we cannot
escape the rebus character of the contemporary city. Nevertheless we
can certainly make enough momentary sense of it to ind the more
162
city futures
opportune pressure points across our city systems to advance more
sustainable livelihoods and lives. This is an intellectual and political
imperative that haunts us, for we are all, in millions of tiny ways,
the cities we desire or dread.
Redux: the core argument
The last three chapters have made it abundantly clear that it is a
formidable challenge to combine the sensibilities of radical incrementalism and recursive empowerment. It became clear that one requires
a ine-grained institutional and political analysis of the local state
(within its intergovernmental context), civil society formations and
diverse business sectors. Unravelling the tendencies and practices of
actors within these broad categories ineluctably leads to a complicated picture which is rendered decidedly complex once practices are
deined in relation to larger political-economic, environmental and
cultural systems; all of which display more intense rates of change
and reconiguration as globalizing dynamics become increasingly a
driver of urban interactions and decisions. Nonetheless, amidst this
complexity and ever-changing scenario, I suggested that progressives
who want to bring more just and inclusive cities into the world need
to focus their attention on the systemic drivers of urban development: the political system of decision-making and resource allocation;
infrastructure; technological standards and systems; building, design
and landscape architectural standards that frame the form of urban
development; the production systems and infrastructural implications of economic activity in the city-region; and iscal, service and
income-based measures to tackle urban inequality as enshrined in
law, policy and regulations of public agencies.
The drivers can be redeined and respeciied towards more just
purposes if democratic institutions work, especially if there is a
capable state and an explicit rights-based policy mandate. However,
contrary to the good urban governance policy model of UN–Habitat,
I argued that it is not enough to have democratic systems and a
formal commitment to human rights. What is required is vigorous
democratic contestation, which may involve momentary consensus on
policy priorities, but may not, especially if policy forums of deliberation constrict participation and simply reinforce elite perspectives
alternative city futures
163
on urban development. Consequently, throughout, there has been
a careful argument for vibrant politics that understand different
domains of political practice that can be mobilized and articulated
in various ways depending on the political opportunity structure of
the city, which in turn lows from the dominant discursive formations that frame what is subject to democratic scrutiny and what
is not. If that space is very narrow and technocratic, it is then
incumbent upon progressives to opt for a militant politics of refusal
and symbolic contestation to bring the city to the brink of crisis or
political deadlock as a lever to shift the terms and focus of political
discourse. Where there is suficient democratic space, it is incumbent
upon progressives to offer alternative proposals on how the drivers
of urban change can be thought of and constructed in order to have
more just and inclusive outcomes. Furthermore, if such a political
space exists, progressives need to target the various domains of
the planning system where primary allocative decisions are taken,
which are later on codiied in budgets and infrastructure investment
decisions. This approach rests on a deep appreciation of the political
and of the inevitability of institutionalization when it comes to the
governance and transformation of cities, especially where there are
large swells of poverty and exclusion of various kinds.
Considering the general situation of rising poverty and inequality
in most cities in the global south, despite a concomitant rise in formal
rhetoric about economic inclusion and greater democratization, it is
appropriate to use this last chapter to focus more concretely on the
question of urban poverty. Thereafter I conclude the chapter and
book with a stylized model of how progressive epistemic communities and the movements they are embedded in can systematically
bring transformative change to life amidst the perplexing brutality,
violence, inventiveness, pleasure and productivity of everyday life in
contemporary cities.
Multidimensional urban poverty reduction agenda
In light of the humanitarian crises that characterize the growth of
contemporary cities, as evidenced in the incomprehensible scale of
one billion people being forced to eke out an existence in slum conditions, it is obvious that urban poverty must be the primary frontier
164
city futures
in the struggle for more just city futures. debates in academic and
policy communities over the past two decades have converged on the
idea that poverty is much more than merely insuficient income and
goes to the heart of what full citizenship may mean in a globalizing
world. Thus, in broad brush strokes, urban poverty can be deined
in the following terms.
Poverty exists when an individual’s or a household’s access to income,
jobs and/or infrastructure is inadequate or suficiently unequal to prohibit full access to opportunities in society. The condition of poverty
is caused by a combination of social, economic, spatial, environmental
and political factors. due to the multiplicity of causal factors and
their spatial dynamics, individuals and households may move in and
out of poverty depending on stages in life-cycle and shifting political economy patterns. Poverty is therefore much more than a lack of
adequate income. 2
building on this deinitional framing, there is broad agreement that
urban poverty can only be reduced and potentially eradicated if a
variety of interventions are pursued in tandem, which include, in particular, the coalescing of political power advocating for the interests of
the poor. At the risk of oversimplifying a vast and continuing debate,
I want to propose a typology of poverty reduction actions (box 8.1):
1. Facilitating access to good-quality employment and economic
opportunities.
2. Increasing the physical asset base of the poor – land, housing,
equipment for economic enterprise.
3. Facilitating access to basic services for the poor, including water
and sanitation, solid waste management, affordable and safe energy,
transport, education, health and shelter.
4. strengthening the community’s management of its own initiatives
and external programmes and ability to self-organize. (The most
important plank of anti-poverty interventions for Csos is to
facilitate the autonomy and empowerment of poor households
and organizations of the poor – community management.)
5. enhancing democratic participation by the poor in public decisionmaking to ensure effective monitoring and inluence over public
resource allocations and service delivery.
alternative city futures
165
6. ensuring the poor’s access to legal entitlements and security.
7. ensuring access to safety nets to strengthen ability to manage
shocks and stresses.
There is a coherence between these seven platforms: activities in 1
and 2 relate to economic dimensions of poverty, whereas activities in
3 and 4 relate to material dimensions and 4–7 relate to political–social
dimensions of poverty. box 8.1 spells out a typology in terms of each
of the seven platforms of action.
It is important to recognize that these interventions must be
located within a larger model of change that draws explicit links
between the micro- and macro-drivers of economic, political and
social life. In other words, it is not adequate to focus simply on local
or urban policies that address each of the seven areas of poverty
reduction work without addressing the articulation between local
forces and global dynamics.3 Thus, local interventions must explicitly
contribute to national, regional and global transformation agendas
that seek to redistribute decision-making power over questions such
as trade rules, environmental standards, labour standards, and so
forth. Put differently, urban policy is always, also, national and global
policy. However, for now I want to focus on the micro-aspects of
poverty reduction in order to paint a more dynamic picture of what
is required within poor communities and their cities to advance a
poverty reduction agenda. This is inluenced by the fact that I have
also devoted the earlier chapters to the dynamics and function of
macro urban institutions, particularly the local state as it functions
at the scale of the city and its adjoining regions.
BOX 8.1
Typology of poverty reduction domains4
1. Facilitating access to good-quality employment and economic
opportunities (income poverty).
• ensuring macroeconomic policies – monetary, iscal and
exchange-rate policies – prioritize the needs of the poor.
• ensuring these economic policies prioritize and promote the
interests of the poor and informal sector: private investment
policies; micro-inance policies; competition policies; labour
166
city futures
market policies; trade policy, especially in the pro-poor sector;
inancial-sector development programmes; pricing policies.
• expansion of quality education, especially skills development
initiatives.
• Labour-based approaches to public works and/or community
contracting for infrastructure and service provision and
management (e.g. municipal–community partnerships).
• enabling policy framework to support and promote the
informal sector (e.g. appropriate regulatory framework, land,
infrastructure, access to inance and markets).
2. Increasing the physical asset base of the poor: land, housing,
equipment for economic enterprise (asset poverty).
• ensuring that sectoral and cross-sectoral/integrated development frameworks and plans facilitate an increase in the asset
base of the poor. sectoral policies would include those pertaining to land, housing and enterprise development.
• Investment in public spaces of collective consumption to
ensure the presence of beauty and greenery in poor communities, which can encourage new forms of sociality and trade and
induce collective pride.
3. Facilitating access to basic services for the poor: water and
sanitation, solid waste management, affordable and safe energy,
transport, education, health and shelter (capability poverty).
Education
• eradicating illiteracy through outreach activities and national
campaigns.
• ensuring full access to pre-primary and primary schooling
through adequate budgetary allocations, quality monitoring of
schools, targeted subsidies to ensure full enrolment, devising
practical initiatives to reduce gender discrimination.
• enhancing parental involvement and management of schools
and suficient accountability.
Health
• Full access to primary health-care facilities for the poor.
• ensuring parental education and enrolment.
• Providing access to safe water and sanitation.
• Promoting breastfeeding and access to health services, including immunization.
alternative city futures
167
• HIV/AIds programmes.
• Communication strategies to ensure awareness among the
poor about health and safety rights and facilities.
• Nutrition programmes (feeding and parental education).
Water and sanitation
• National policy to ensure the poor have access to a minimum
lifeline service to guarantee basic daily domestic levels.
• Community-based infrastructure and maintenance initiatives
to keep costs minimal for the poor but ensure full access.
• basic lifeline for survivalist economic initiatives of homebased enterprises.
4. strengthening ‘community management’ or organization of own
initiatives and external programmes and ability to self-organize.
Vibrant community organizations provide an indispensable platform for collective actions to exercise rights, manage conlict in
democratic ways and provide a learning laboratory on democratic
citizenship – all of which can increase stocks of social capital.
Community management is facilitated through initiatives that:
• strengthen community management capability.
• support democratic processes internally and externally.
• Focus on organizational development, training and capacitybuilding.
• Focus on leadership development, especially among women
and youth.
• Provide access to useful information in appropriate formats.
• support collective action aimed at increasing access to opportunities and entitlements; and transforming the policy framework that shapes the opportunity structures of the poor.
5. enhancing democratic participation by the poor in public
decision-making to ensure effective monitoring and inluence
over public resource allocations and service delivery.
• Proactive support measures to enable poor households and
representative organizations to participate in formal participatory mechanisms, especially at local government level.
• ensuring good governance practices – transparency and
accountability – meet the needs of the poor.
• A strong and effective local government system that can
ensure the provision of an integrated package of basic services
to the poor, tailored to neighbourhood dynamics.
168
city futures
• Improved budget management and transparency, with disaggregated information about expenditure targeting the
poor.
• Information and public dialogue tailored to needs of the
poor.
• Targeted anti-corruption and anti-abuse efforts in the public
service that interface with the poor.
• Actions to expose and address gender discrimination.
6. ensuring the poor’s access to legal entitlements and security.
• Fair judicial system that meets the needs of the poor.
• Providing squatters and landless communities with tenure to
reduce the risk of eviction and increase the value of assets, and
so raise the prospect of accessing credit.
• ensuring access to relevant information about human rights,
socio-economic rights and the right to information and quality
service from public-sector oficials.
• Access to information about legal instruments to ensure
employment protection and workplace safety and security,
especially for domestic workers and other vulnerable
categories.
• Protection against violence and insecurity at household and
community levels.
• opportunity and facilities to exercise political democratic
rights and responsibilities via adequate arrangements for elections, political representation and accountability.
7. ensuring access to safety nets to strengthen ability to manage
shocks and stresses.
• Access to risk-management mechanisms, e.g. micro-credit and
safety-net programmes (e.g. public works).
• Access to emergency curative care.
• Actions to reduce domestic, gender and community violence
(e.g. community policing).
• Measures to mitigate environment disaster risks (e.g. better
designed infrastructure).
• spending on and targeting of safety-net programmes, including nutrition, disability, old-age pensions and child support
grants and ensuring access to private maintenance grants.
• emergency credit facilities for the poor in times of disaster or
rapid economic decline.
alternative city futures
169
Micro anti-poverty actions
Anti-poverty action at a micro scale involves a wide spectrum of
development work, as box 8.1 intimates. Alan Fowler5 has usefully
summarized both micro- and macro-interventions that are essential
to shift the development landscape to a degree that poverty will be
eradicated; an end-state he typiies as ‘socially just and sustainable
economies with accountable, inclusive systems of government’. The
micro-tasks involve a range of interventions and services to achieve
three broad outcomes:
• empowerment of poor communities and individuals;
• strengthening of local institutions;
• sustained improvements in the physical well-being of poor and
abandoned citizens.
This list clearly coincides with the seven anti-poverty planks of
action summarized in box 8.1. The important dynamic to understand is that the irst and last outcomes depend on the second – the
strengthening of local institutions. This goes back to what we know
from the participatory development literature: unless development
processes are owned and driven by the so-called beneiciaries, they
are unlikely to succeed over the long term. In different terms, the
primary task of local development work is to foster strong, democratic, transparent and responsive organizations that enable poor
citizens to pool their energies and mobilize for better access to
development opportunities and greater inluence in the larger public
sphere of the city.
However, decades of experience and learning across the south
have taught us that people do not participate in collective organizations unless they speak to immediate needs, fulil identity-based
aspirations and serve a political function. Choices to participate
or not are heavily inluenced by perceptions about the nature of
‘political space’ to organize and act autonomously from the state and
political movements linked to the state. Furthermore, democratic
organizations of the poor are very hard to build and sustain, because
they are often hijacked by ‘local elites’, who act as gatekeepers and
spokespersons for the local community. For these and many other
reasons (that extend beyond the scope of this chapter and book),
170
city futures
intermediary service organizations (NGos) play an important role in
encouraging and supporting the formation of democratic movements
and mutual-help organizations in poor communities. However, the
entry point to foster collective action and solidarity tends to be a
speciic problem/issue, typically rooted in a sectoral development
focus – for example, health, access to credit, access to land, and
so on. Numerous sectorally deined examples are listed in box 8.1,
which should help to visualize this point.
The recent debate on sectoral, or fragmented, versus integrated development has highlighted the problems of sectoral-based
approaches to development and poverty reduction.6 The singular
lesson that emerges from these debates is that local-level interventions
need to address concrete needs or wants, but the processes of addressing needs must also unlock a wider set of developmental dynamics
that can visibly contribute to the strengthening of local institutions
and empowerment of communities and individuals. Furthermore, in
urban contexts dominated by the lack of work or access to productive
opportunities, this is often the primary trigger to unlock developmental processes in poor communities. experience and research,
furthermore, suggest that fostering savings that are collectively held
is often the most effective way of stimulating access to productive
assets and employment opportunities. There is a more expanded
argument behind this assertion that I can only touch on supericially
here. For now, the diagrammatic summary in Figure 8.1 will have
to sufice to illustrate the key points. (I link these community-level
imperatives to the typology presented above.)
Figure 8.1 makes it clear that the biggest asset a poor community
has is its stock of social capital that allows it to carry out collective
actions on the basis of solidarity. social capital is best enhanced
through collective actions that address the physical well-being of the
participating people (and households) in one form or another. The
experience of achievement that comes from positive collective action
provides a useful foundation to promote political agency aimed at
powerful local actors and the government, depending on the issues at
hand. The example of shack/slum dwellers International, discussed
in Chapter 6, captures this dynamic forcefully. The central point to
take away from this discussion is that effective anti-poverty action
alternative city futures
171
(Access to cash transfers, equipment,
land, credit and employment)
Increase the
economic base of
poor households
Increase stocks
of social capital
through participation
in development
organizations
Grow savings
of poor
households
Microactions
Increase political
leverage of
poor citizens
through their
organizations
Increase access
to (basic) social
services required
by poor households
Macroactions
(Access to health, education, water
and sanitation, transport, etc.)
FIGURE 8.1
developmental linkages at the micro scale7
at a local neighbourhood scale must combine a degree of sectoral
specialization with an awareness of fostering integrated development.
Institutionally, this implies that service providers (NGos), agencies of
the state and local associations need to work in a more coordinated
manner. Local interventions also require a sharp understanding of
how the speciic action will link up with contiguous processes at
the meso and macro scales. In other words, how do the experiences of local development processes with all their frustrations and
achievements directly inform advocacy and lobbying processes at
national and international scales? This is the intersection point where
the micro informs the macro, and where the macro can, potentially,
enable local action to empower poor households, citizens and their
organizational formations.
Tipping points of urban transformation
Just and sustainable city futures need not simply be a utopian aspiration. Champions of the unequivocal ‘right to the city’ for all have a
large and rich canvas with which to work, as I have been at pains to
illustrate throughout this book. In fact, we have never before been in
a position where the nominal discourses of mainstream institutions
172
city futures
are so close to our agenda for justice, equality, inclusivity, sustainability and cultural fulilment. The problem is that progressives tend to
fall into one of two kinds of trap: either they assign everything to the
realm of dominating power, manifested in tendencies by governments
and development agencies to use progressive-sounding discourses
to simply camoulage new forms of rule and oppression; or they
uncritically buy into the familiarity of left-sounding discourses and
assume that a neat consensus-driven politics will bring redistributive
politics and outcomes into the world. What I have been proposing
throughout is that the history and spatiality of cities throughout the
global south are too dense, speciic and redolent with contradictions
to lend themselves to such easy readings, no matter how compellingly one marshals the evidence. It is therefore imperative to take
the uniqueness and ordinariness of all cities very seriously and think
through a prism of radical democracy to identify the unique interventions required to advance radical incrementalism and recursive
empowerment, both of which have a deep institutionalism to them.8
In this concluding section I want to think through the procedural
aspects of this agenda.
My starting point is a commitment to radical democracy that inds
expression in vibrant political contestation across the ive domains of
urban politics: formal representative systems; corporatist deliberation
forums; sites of direct action by autonomous civil society actors;
practice-oriented interventions aimed at enhancing and expanding the
livelihoods of the poor and marginalized; and, very importantly, the
symbolic domain where competing discourses clash and morph into
new imaginaries about the city. The articulation of these domains tells
us something about the quality of urban democracy and the room for
manoeuvre for progressive agendas. I have proposed further that the
city is an ideal breeding ground for various epistemic communities
that seek to work at the untidy seams of mainstream urban politics in
order to identify vulnerable points, so as always to push boundaries
and institutionalize ever more just and inclusive policies that ind
expression in the regulatory systems of urban governments, especially
their budgets and land-use provisions. This is the arena of radical
incrementalism signalled in the opening chapter and expounded in
the previous chapter.
alternative city futures
173
However, radical incrementalism has little prospect if civil society
organizations that represent and champion the diverse interests of
the poor are weak, unorganized and ineffectual with regard to formal
centres of political and economic power. It is therefore important to
stress that my understanding of a dynamic urban democracy rests on
the idea that civil society organizations among the poor exist and
are autonomous from the overbearing inluence of dominant political
parties and vested economic interests.9 Furthermore, it is important
that such civil society organizations consciously deepen their own
relexivity and critical practice, because their ideological and political
integrity is directly linked to their internal democratic practices and
cultures.10 Patriarchal and authoritarian organizations of the poor will
remain limited in how far they can advance transformative agendas
for the city as a whole, and will often remain vulnerable to co-option
by elites. Typically, these organizations also need to be reasonably
adept at generating resources to fund their activities, which again
signals something about their capacity to embed themselves in local
needs and be seen as relevant by ordinary citizens. Lastly, if these
organizations are to be effective they obviously need to be visible
in the public sphere. often organizations representing the interests
of the poor render themselves invisible and insigniicant because
they restrict the ambit of their work to the immediate issues in a
particular locality without drawing practical links to the larger citywide dynamics that cause or reinforce local problems, or they do not
invest in symbolic expressions of their work.
so, let us assume a context where there are numerous progressive networks and epistemic communities focused on driving and
deepening systemic urban change across a plurality of fronts within
a democratic framework which holds the potential to be pushed in
a radical democratic direction. In this setting, I would argue that
the irst task of progressive coalitions is to identify the top four
to six ‘tough issues’ that many actors in the city agree represent
the most formidable obstacles to resilient and sustainable urban
futures. This could be the prevalence of HIV/AIds, which is rendered insurmountable because of the pervasiveness of poverty, poor
education infrastructure, food insecurity, limited social capital and
a persistent resistance among the urban elite to allocate suficient
174
city futures
resources for greater income equality, higher levels of access to
basic services and increased expenditure on primary health-care
infrastructures and personnel. or it could be the pervasive presence
of extremely violent, patriarchal and, paradoxically, welfare-oriented
drug-based gangs that constitute the dominant form of governmentality over territories in the city where, predominantly, the poor live.
Whatever the tough or stubborn problems may be, addressing them
will require considerable resources, a multidimensional response, an
intergenerational agenda and large-scale mobilization of the affected
communities themselves.
once these issues are strategically identiied as the most pressing
and intractable, they can then be used as a focus to shift the ways
in which these problems are conventionally deined and dealt with.
This implies a capacity to isolate and expose the primary tenets of
mainstream discourses (of the state, business sector and particular
civil society organizations) and their effects in terms of resource
allocation, likely impact on the problems, and legitimacy in the public
domain. once discourses are deconstructed and revealed for what
they actually mean and produce as a societal response, it becomes
possible to provide alternative perspectives on the underlying reasons
for the disjuncture between the ostensible objectives of the set of
policies promoted by such discourses and the probable outcomes. The
critical literature on the future prospects of curbing and reversing
slum formation is a sobering reminder of just how wide the gap is
between dominant discourses and the material impacts of associated
policies.
This kind of critical deconstructive work is only the beginning,
though, and must lead to serious and rigorous exploration of viable
alternatives that may not be able to remedy the chronic weaknesses
of mainstream policy solutions but can at least offer some stepping
stones to more effective alternative interventions. However, this
does imply that progressive coalitions and networks must be suficiently schooled in the technical and institutional dimensions of
mainstream policy approaches so as to identify fairly precise interventions to reposition the energies and resources of the state. Too
often, radical scholars and activists are brilliant at critiquing why
mainstream approaches fail despite having formally good intentions,
alternative city futures
175
but can seldom suggest alternative approaches rooted in the messy
and intractable sticky ground that arises from highly asymmetrical
capitalist production and social reproduction systems. It is against
this imperative that I offered in Chapter 7 the coordinates of a an
alternative urban development schematic, because it is around the
systemic drivers of the urban system that progressives need to do
more spadework to demonstrate how, in particular contexts, the urban
can be remodelled, resourced and reorganized along more inclusive,
as opposed to exclusionary, lines. both literature and practice are
clearly on the rise across the global south, but more theorization
and experimental application are required in order to point the way
to large-scale systemic change.
once alternatives are more precisely delineated to the extent that
they can become the raw material for progressive coalition politics, it
will be important to take stock of the organizational and institutional
capabilities within the (local) state and civil society organizations
linked to the urban poor. This task is twofold. First, care must be
taken not to overload or overburden the local state with too many
imperatives and policies so that it ends up terminally incapacitated
because the urban transformation agenda is simply too large and
complex to implement in practice. In other words, it is vital that
there is a it between the transformation agenda and the institutional capacity of the state to execute (new) dominant policies and
programmes. For example, many scholars of local governance and
urban development in south Africa have come to the conclusion that
the urban transformation agenda has suffered under the weight of
an overgrown and overambitious reform agenda which has produced
perverse outcomes, such as the exacerbation of urban sprawl, racial
segregation and inequality.11 similar suggestions are beginning to
surface in the brazilian urban literature as well.12
second, the task is about understanding whether there is a suficient
critical mass of leaders and activists across the institutional entities
to carry forward a complex, critical politics; one that must eschew
the temptation of narrow like-minded coalitions, as envisaged in the
Cds approach of the Cities Alliance, in favour of a more dynamic
matrix of conlicting tensions that produce a higher quality of argument, engagement and practical experiment with more ambitious
176
city futures
interventions that act on the nerve endings of urban inequality.
The point is that once the appropriate interventions are clariied, it
is important to deine and strengthen the institutional vehicles and
mechanisms to ensure consistent implementation. Urban transformation will not become a material reality without the mundane, almost
boring, routine actions of stable institutions that deliver appropriate
and quality services at the right scale and in an appropriate sequence
to a highly stratiied and adaptive citizenry. Getting this aspect
of alternative urban development right is as important as iguring
out more just and sustainable urban infrastructure solutions or new
economic sectors that can generate meaningful employment.
Finally, discovering the unique alchemy of a radical, alternative
urban political agenda is about holding on to a strong cultural sensitivity for the numerous and ever-changing rhythms of the city, which
never cease to bring fresh and surprising novelty into its very heart.
Moreover, a cultural acuity is vital to iguring out what constitutes
the most strategic or inely balanced tipping points in the city likely
to take it on to a qualitatively different plain in terms of the possibility of transformative change. In my mind, these tipping points
come into focus when progressives triangulate: (i) understandings of
the main ‘tough issues’ in the city; (ii) where in space these issues
intersect most acutely or visibly to become a focal point for intervention; (iii) where institutional desire and capability reside in the
state and civil society; and (iv) imaginative (symbolic) responses arise
directly from uniquely local idioms, practices and traditions, which
can be remoulded to construct a locally recognizable campaign for
transformation. I have expanded in much greater depth elsewhere
on how this can work in cities marked by high levels of inequality
and diversity, which I shall not repeat here.13
echoing the sensibility of James sallis at the opening of this
chapter, it seems to me that the scope for grounded, radical but
necessarily incremental urban transformation is vast; but our ability
to exploit that scope depends on our willingness to step beyond a
narrow, reactive, interminably critical posture, to one where we take
responsibility for letting the light shine through the darkness that
engulfs our cities.
Notes
Chapter 1
1. Calvino 1997:44.
2. The term ‘global south’ refers to countries that do not have fully industrialized economies, largely non-oeCd countries with the exception
potentially of Mexico, korea and Turkey. In postcolonial theoretical
terms it denotes countries that have experienced some form of colonial
domination (directly or indirectly) in their modern history, which have
left indelible scars on their economic, cultural and political landscapes.
3. davis 2005: 202.
4. A quintessential expression of this mode of policy conidence can be
found in Jack 2006.
5. Cornwall and brock 2005.
6. see: bayat 1997, 2000; benjamin 2004; de boeck and Plissart 2004; roy
2005; roy and Alsayyed 2004; simone 2004; Watson 2007.
7. simone 2004: 11.
8. An important body of work that picks up on a research approach itting
for such readings can be found in Flyvbjerg 2001, 2004.
9. roe 1993: 93. Technically, roe distinguishes between the following dimensions of complexity: ‘the number of components in a system, the degree
of differentiation in components, and the degree of interdependence
between components … The most important characteristic of complexity
in demchack’s words, is “that complexity produces surprise”’ (93–4).
10. byrne 2001: 11.
11. Here I have in mind the approach taken in sharp et al. 2000, and the
erudite intervention by Amin and Thrift (2005). An interesting attempt
178
12.
13.
14.
15.
16.
17.
18.
19.
20.
city futures
to question the totalizing tendencies of some Foucauldian interpretations
of power can be explored in barnett 2005.
see Moore 1994: 123.
For a useful account of what the ‘good city’ may mean in the contemporary era, see Amin 2006.
Hall 1996: 244.
These ideas are persuasively developed in the various writings of Arjun
Appadurai (2002, 2004) whose work seeks to capture the indeterminate
dynamics of processes of identity formation and agency in some of the
harshest urban contexts in the world.
david Harvey (2006) convincingly maps out the reasons for the virtual
impossibility of economic alternatives emerging. Adrian Atkinson (2004,
2005) develops this proposition more extensively in recent essays.
Lingis (1994, 2004).
I have explored these themes in greater detail in Pieterse 2004.
I will return to this framework in Chapter 5, but see also Pieterse 2005.
There is obviously a lot more to be said about the richness of this framework and the wealth of issues that it will generate if applied systematically
to a particular development issue or if one wants to track the governance culture of a municipality over a period of time. We leave it to the
interested reader to read the original texts and explore the analytical
possibilities (see Healey 2004, 2007).
Chapter 2
1.
2.
3.
4.
5.
6.
7.
8.
9.
10.
11.
12.
13.
14.
15.
satterthwaite 2007.
Graham and Marvin 2001.
UNFPA 2007.
UNFPA 2007: 7–8. It is important to heed david satterthwaite’s (2007)
caution that urban projections that go too far into the future, e.g. 2030,
must be treated with great circumspection because the underlying data
sets for many developing countries remain extremely problematic.
Throughout this book I will assume that this warning is understood
and appreciated.
satterthwaite 2007: 1.
Lee 2007: 7.
satterthwaite 2007: 29–30.
United Nations 2006.
satterthwaite 2007: 29.
Wright 2002: 72–3.
McMichael 2000.
UNdP 2005.
McMichael 2000.
sutcliffe 2001.
The global city thesis suggests that cities are positioned in highly
notes
16.
17.
18.
19.
20.
21.
22.
23.
24.
25.
26.
27.
28.
29.
30.
31.
32.
33.
34.
35.
36.
179
differentiated points in a broader global hierarchy of cities. This ‘hierarchy’ holds determining implications for the capacity of the city to engage
with and survive the new economic processes that rode on the wave
technological advances that made extended trade and exchange lows
possible. For instance, the top tier in the hierarchy would be dominated
by London, Tokyo and New York; the second level will hold cities of
regional importance, e.g. Amsterdam, Frankfurt and Los Angeles; the
third tier would relect signiicant internationally recognized capitals such
as Madrid and sydney; the fourth level would relect cities of national
importance and some international functions, e.g. Milan and osaka.
In other words, in terms of the logic of the global economy, this is a
hierarchy based on the level of strategic importance for international
capital. see sassen 1994.
For a useful review, see UN–Habitat 2001: ch. 2.
Graham 2000: 183–4.
Graham 2000: 183–4.
Graham 2000: 185.
Graham 2000: 186.
For an insightful elaboration with examples of this point, see Graham
and Marvin 2002: ch. 3.
The data for Table 2.3 come from swilling 2006. The summarized descriptions provided by the knowledge-management company that developed
the instrument deserve a discussion in their own right. It may interest
the reader that Mark swilling uses these data to calculate and demonstrate the differential contribution of wealthy and poor residents to the
extraordinarily large ecological footprint of Cape Town.
The motor vehicle industry is the world’s largest manufacturing business.
In 2002 it was estimated that there were 600 million vehicles in the world
and approximately 53 million were sold annually. It is anticipated that
66 per cent of sales growth over the next decade will come from the
Asia-Paciic region, mainly China and India. see Gabel and bruner 2003:
36–7.
Graham and Marvin 2001: 117.
This history is usefully set out in zetter 2004.
Ya and Weliwita 2007: 4–5.
Tannerfeldt and Ljung 2006: 54.
Moreno and Warah 2006.
UN–Habitat 2006: 190.
Moreno and Warah 2006.
see Clarke 2006; de souza 2005; standing 2004.
Neuwirth 2005.
Lee 2007: 16 (see this reference for original source).
Tibaijuka 2005: 18–19.
Moreno and Warah 2006.
Tibaijuka 2005: 19.
180
city futures
Chapter 3
1.
2.
3.
4.
5.
6.
7.
8.
9.
10.
11.
12.
13.
14.
15.
16.
17.
18.
19.
20.
21.
22.
23.
24.
25.
26.
UN–Habitat 2004a: 14.
UN–Habitat 2004a: 21–2.
UN–Habitat 2004a: 25.
UN–Habitat 2004a: 64–5.
Press release, ‘United Nations expert on Adequate Housing Concludes
Visit to south Africa’, www.ohchr.org; accessed 28 November 2007.
UN–Habitat 2004a: 32.
UN–Habitat 2004a: 33–4.
de soto 2000. I will return to de soto’s inluence later on in the
chapter.
UN–Habitat 2004a: 32.
Lee 2007.
UN–Habitat 2004a: 39; see also UN–Habitat 2004b for a range of examples that can be linked to each of these tenure forms.
Fernandez 2002: 5–8.
de soto 2005.
smolka and Larangeira 2007.
smolka and Laraggeira 2007.
Fernandez 2002: 7.
Fernandez 2002: 7.
UN–Habitat 2004a: esp. 35.
UN–Habitat 2004a: 36. Also see a recent piece by one of the leading
policy minds in UN–Habitat on the importance of the rental route in
relation to the massive market failure, evidenced most clearly in the sheer
absence of inancing instruments tailored to the realities of the urban
poor: You 2007.
UN–Habitat 2004a: 37.
south Africa is an interesting example of likely private-sector behaviour
because the inancial services sector is matured, there is a willingness on
the part of the state to underwrite such transactions, and the banks are
compelled by an industry charter to develop products for the lower ends
of the market. Nevertheless, up until now the dominant trend is market
avoidance.
UN–Habitat 2004a: 41.
For a fascinating and counter-intuitive exploration of these issues and
their implications for economic development, see benjamin 2004.
riddell 2004.
A particularly instructive case is the dramatic progress bogota has made
in just over a decade to expand dramatically access for the urban poor
(and non-poor) to crucial public infrastructures such as transport, cycle
lanes, parks and, most impressively, well-designed and well-stocked
libraries that are interlaced with the transport and public space systems
(see e.g. Cabbalero 2003; Wright and Montezuma 2004).
It is crucial to recognize that the task force did not simply accept target
notes
27.
28.
29.
30.
31.
32.
181
11 because it was regarded as too limited and instead introduced the
following formulation: ‘by 2020, improving substantially the lives of at
least 100 million slum dwellers, while providing adequate alternatives
to new slum formation.’ This is highly signiicant because the growth
of slums is projected to be well above 100 million people. so, in effect
the document seeks to make a much more substantial intervention than
what the original target established. see: UN Millennium Project 2005:
3. However, here I am not delving into the overarching argument of the
document, which is very strong, but rather focus on the approach to civil
society participation.
In particular, see UN–Habitat 2004a: 60 para. 2.
My perspective is informed by a study Firoz khan and I conducted of
the growth and institutional dynamics of the south African Homeless
People’s Federation. see khan and Pieterse 2006.
UN–Habitat 2004a: 58.
UN–Habitat 2003: xxvii.
swilling 2006. The list of proposals that follow are all adapted from this
same source.
swilling 2006: 48.
Chapter 4
1.
2.
3.
4.
5.
6.
7.
8.
9.
10.
11.
12.
13.
14.
15.
A useful review of these trends can be found in Manor 1999.
Habitat 1996.
UN–Habitat 2002: 15.
UN–Habitat 2002: 15.
UN–Habitat 2002: 16.
see the review of Manor 2004.
For more explicit elaborations of this phenomenon, see Cornwall 2004;
Miraftab 2004, etc. For a more nuanced articulation of this argument,
see Williams 2004.
UN–Habitat 2002: 11.
Mumtaz and Wegelin 2001: 126.
Pieterse 2000.
dialogical is derived from dialogue, which in turn can mean discussion, exchange of ideas, low of information, and so forth. Theoretically,
dialogical draws on the work of Jürgen Habermas on communicative
action to democratize the public sphere (see Healey 1997 for a creative
adaptation of Habermas’s theories to urban politics and planning; and
Flyvbjerg 1998 for a systematic critique).
borja and Castells 1997: 154.
Cities Alliance website: www.citiesalliance.org; accessed 26 october
2007.
see World bank 2000: 64.
Cities Alliance 2001: 1.
182
city futures
16. Cities Alliance 2001: 1.
17. Cities Alliance 2006. This document systematizes the lessons from practical
experiences in undertaking Cdss and responding to new development
priorities such as climate change and associated environmental risks.
18. Cities Alliance 2006: 42.
19. Cities Alliance 2006: 3. each of these themes is further subdivided in
sub-themes which are also of great importance.
20. I am assuming here that most local governments in cities of the global
south are democratically elected. obviously my analysis does not apply
in the same way where this is still not the case.
21. Cities Alliance 2006: 42.
22. borja and Castells 1997: 154, 155.
23. Healey 1997: 284.
24. Healey 2000: 526.
25. Landry 2000.
26. Cities Alliance 2006: 4.
27. Graham and Marvin 2001.
28. UN–Habitat 2001.
29. UN–Habitat 2001: 26.
30. UN–Habitat 2001: 30.
31. Cities Alliance 2006: 33.
32. This igure is an adaptation of a model developed by stephen boshoff,
the former chief city planner of the City of Cape Town municipality.
Chapter 5
1. okri 1997: 32.
2. simons 1995: 3.
3. In urban studies the actor-network approach of Ash Amin and Nigel
Thrift (2002) stands out along with the post-Marxist formulation of
kian Tajbakhsh (2001). In development studies, Norman Long (2001)
has gone a long way in formulating a sophisticated framework to capture
the dynamic interplay between structure and agency and the space for
political action beyond the restrictions of economic-deterministic epistemologies. These are consistent with scholarship in postcolonial cultural
studies (Ahluwalia 2001; Ashcroft 2001).
4. see Amin and Thrift 2002: ch 6.
5. Two scholars who are particularly insightful on this point are de sousa
santos 1995; Unger 1998.
6. For example, see Gabardi 2001; Mouffe 2000; squires 2002.
7. see Flood 1999.
8. Healey 2000: 918.
9. In other words, it is related to, but more narrow than, the Foucauldian
conception, whereby ‘Government is any more or less calculated and
rational activity, undertaken by a multiplicity of authorities and agencies,
employing a variety of techniques and forms of knowledge, that seeks to
notes
10.
11.
12.
13.
14.
15.
16.
17.
18.
19.
20.
21.
22.
23.
24.
25.
26.
27.
28.
29.
30.
31.
183
shape conduct by working through our desires, aspirations, interests and
beliefs, for deinite but shifting ends and with a diverse set of relatively
unpredictable consequences, effects and outcomes’ (dean 1999: 11).
Gabardi 2001: 82.
Healey 2000: 919.
The rich and insightful work of doreen Massey 1999 is particularly
illuminating on this point.
Tajbakhsh 2001: 6.
Cleaver 2001: 44.
Cleaver 2001: 44.
Flyvbjerg 2001: ch. 8; Gabardi 2001: ch. 4.
Goetz and Lister 2001; Heller 2001.
In an earlier study I provide a full discussion on the gamut of participatory governance policies and tools with due regard for contextual speciicity and dangers associated with this relatively recent trend: Pieterse
2000. Also see borja and Castells 1997: 193–200; Goetz and Gaventa 2001;
Manor 2004.
see barkin 1997; Mossberger and stoker 2001.
see UN–Habitat’s own experience and research in this regard: Lüdeking
and Williams 1999.
borja and Castells 1997.
see shubane 1995.
For example, see bond 2000.
There is a rich literature on this which provides useful guidelines for
thinking through the complex relational politics; see especially edmunds
and Wollenberg 2001; Hillier 2002.
There are obviously many instances where (relatively) privileged and
conservative groups also embark on direct action to get their political
grievances across. by focusing on disadvantaged groups I am merely signalling an analytical preference to highlight the actions of this category
of social actors but not to create an impression that other groups do not
engage in this political arena.
Alvarez et al. 1998; orbach 1996.
scott 1997: 323.
This is surveyed in Pieterse 2001.
Appadurai 2004: 69.
evans 2002.
This is not to denigrate the important and complex work of effective
institutional change in large public-sector organizations. studies on
‘synergy’ between the state and civil society organizations demonstrate
just how crucial it is to pursue organizational transformation to enhance
the developmental capability of government departments, especially
where they act in concert with civil society organizations (see evans
1996; Tendler 1997; Abers 2000). Nevertheless, drawing on participant
observations, I am also certain that much of what passes as change-
184
32.
33.
34.
35.
36.
37.
38.
39.
40.
41.
42.
43.
44.
city futures
management quickly becomes ritualized practices of adaptation with little
interest in fulilling the developmental mandate of the government.
barnard and Armstrong 1998.
see bauman and Mitlin 2002.
Goverde et al. 2000: 14.
Gabardi 2001: 89.
robinson 2002.
see Graham and Marvin 2001.
The theoretical basis of such an approach is elaborated in: eade and Mele
2002; Massey 1999; robinson 2002; and Tajbakhsh 2001. strategic actions
that low from such an approach are deftly argued in Amin 2002; Amin
and Thrift 2002; Graham and Marvin 2001: Postscript; and sorkin 2001.
bayat 1997, 2000; scott 1997.
bayat 2000: 24–5.
barker 2000: 151.
Gabardi 2001: 109.
Amin and Thrift 2002: ch. 6; Mouffe 2000.
Holston 1998.
Chapter 6
1. Cities Alliance 2006: 17.
2. Healey 2000a.
3. Coates (2003: 17) explains that ecstacity is ‘an imaginary place that foregrounds the sensual side of all cities. To help construct it, I have taken
fragments from seven cities around the world, and woven them into one
multi-coloured urban fabric. Its patterns shift according to the overlap
of cultures. It both reconigures what we already know and stimulates
new responses.’
4. For example, see eade and Mele 2002; Tajbakhsh 2001.
5. rakodi and Lloyd-Jones 2002.
6. Coates 2003: 43.
7. bayat 1997: 8.
8. bayat 1997: 10–11.
9. This section draws on a previously published chapter: khan and Pieterse
2006.
10. People’s dialogue 1996: 21.
11. People’s dialogue 1996: 21; 2000.
12. People’s dialogue 1996: 21.
13. J. bolnick, interview, 7 April 2004, Cape Town.
14. shack/slum dwellers International (sdI), a global network of poor
people’s organizations from eleven countries of the south, comprises
federations of community organizations that are linked to NGos and
groupings of professionals who support federation initiatives. Unlike
other transnational citizen networks, the locus of power lies in communities themselves rather than in intermediary NGos at national and
notes
15.
16.
17.
18.
19.
20.
21.
22.
23.
24.
25.
26.
27.
28.
29.
30.
31.
185
international levels. This is partly because the sdI and its counterparts
were not set up to inluence global policymaking or lobby international
inancial institutions (though these roles are increasing). rather, their
aim is to promote practical solidarity, mutual support and the exchange
of information about strategies and concrete alternatives among their
members (edwards 2001).
development Works 2003.
The United Nation’s Commission for Human settlements (UNCHs) and
the United Nations development Programme (UNdP) – co-convenors
of the Habitat II Conference – and the United states Agency for International development.
Huchzermeyer 2001: 322.
Huchzermeyer 2001: 323.
see www.sdinet.org/documents/doc16.htm, accessed 19 November 2007.
Personal correspondence with the Mark swilling based on assessment of
sdI he carried out in east Africa 2006.
The sources for the textbox are brillembourg and klumpner 2005: 19;
and www.u-tt.com, accessed 30 July 2007.
Ferrándiz 2004.
rodgers 2004.
standing 2004.
Clarke 2006.
Winton 2004.
see de sousa 2005; Winton 2004; zaluar 2006.
de sousa 2005: 6–7.
Neate and Platt 2006: 102.
research by various scholars indicates that during the past two decades,
in tandem with intensifying globalization processes, the scale, complexity
and reach of drug economies (and markets) have exploded, leaving a devastating legacy of crime and violence in their wake (Castells 1997; Naím
2006). during this same period economic contraction and restructuring
(to more service-based sectors, which require higher skill levels) has
tended to worsen income inequalities in most cities, leaving the most
marginalized in even more precarious situations with little hope of incorporation into the formal labour market (UNdP 1998). As a consequence
of these forces, many black youths, especially men, are enrolled in one
form or another into gangs that manage and drive, in particular the drug
trade in poor neighbourhoods. Poor neighbourhoods fulil particular
functions in an extensive and often globalized value chain of production,
reinement, manufacturing, warehousing, distribution and consumption
in local, national and global markets. Around these activities, drug-based
gangs exercise near total control of the territories where they are located,
often in collusion with elements in the security forces (de souza 2005).
For a fascinating reading of the signiicance of this group, see Caldeira
2004.
186
city futures
32. MV bill quoted in Neate 2003: 191–2. MV bill (Alexandre barreto) is a
hip-hop artist from one of the most violent regions of the city of rio de
Janeiro, the favela of Cidade de deus (City of God).
33. From an interview in Leros Magazine, June 2005, www.leros.co.uk; accessed
21 october 2006.
34. Pardue 2004.
35. Interview with Luis soares, www.dreamscanbe.org/controlPanel/
materia/view/433; accessed 21 october 2006.
36. sarai Collective, ‘sarai: The New Media Initiative’ http://subsol.c3.hu/
subsol_2/contributors0/saraitext.html; accessed 8 November 2007.
37. Ibid.
38. Ibid.
39. www.sarai.net/about-us/introducing-sarai/overview; accessed 8 November 2007.
40. www.chimurenga.co.za/html; accessed 8 November 2007.
41. This crude summary of the important work of Chimurenga cannot substitute for exploring this initiative irst hand by visiting their website and
buying their wares.
Chapter 7
1.
2.
3.
4.
5.
6.
7.
8.
9.
10.
11.
12.
13.
Habitat 1996: para. 29.
NsFWUs 2000: 7.
NsFWUs 2000: 8.
Human rights, www.reference.com/browse/wiki/Human_rights;
accessed 5 November 2007.
There is another layer to the issue of a comprehensive approach to rights,
which is the importance of adopting a multicultural lens to view the question of rights and their localization in particular regions and countries.
This argument has been fruitfully expounded by bouventura de sousa
santos (1999).
This section draws on, and is more fully developed in, another publication: Parnell and Pieterse 2007.
see Friedmann 2002: ch. 4, for a similar kind of argument but through
the lens of ‘insurgent citizenship’.
Florida 2005.
robinson and Tinker 1998: 25.
For example, a leading business magazine, Strateg y and Business, carried
an article in which the following case was made: ‘The quality of infrastructure and land-use planning “hard wires” the environmental impact
of a given region. The more consciously we can build infrastructure that
doesn’t harm, or that even helps restore, the natural environment, the
more likely it is that those cities will endure’ (Finn and rahl 2007: 50).
see Walsh 2007; doerr 2006.
Parnell 2007.
riddel 2004: 258–60.
notes
14.
15.
16.
17.
18.
19.
20.
21.
22.
23.
24.
25.
26.
27.
28.
29.
30.
31.
32.
33.
34.
35.
36.
37.
38.
39.
40.
41.
187
Young 2000: 206, 207.
savage et al. 2003.
see stevenson 2003; Tajbakhsh 2001.
bridge and Watson 2000: 253.
eade and Mele 2002.
stevenson 2003: 40.
Tajbakhsh 2001: 28.
smith 2001.
Clifford 2000; Massey 1999.
stevenson 2003: 47.
bridge and Watson 2000: 257–9; Marcuse 2000.
bridge and Watson 2000: 257.
The points in this section draw on Healey’s subtle and insightful framework on the dimensions of governance (see Table 1.1).
This section draws on an argument elaborated more fully elsewhere:
Pieterse 2006.
For an elaboration, see barker 2000.
Gunder 2003: 253.
Ashcroft and Alhuwalia 1999: 135; the closing words are from edward
said.
Cornell West, quoted in Ashcroft 2001: 49.
I am indebted to Ahmedi Vawda for the reminder that what is considered
‘radical’ and ‘establishment’ is profoundly generational. Youth always
carries within itself very particular ideas about what is radical and cuttingedge, as changing fashions in popular culture and politics remind us.
I believe that a number of epistemic communities need to coexist and
will do in practice. However, for the sake of the argument in the book,
I hereon refer to epistemic community in the singular because I am
invoking one that I can identify with.
I am fully aware that a number of objections to the notion of an epistemic
community or organic intellectuals can be raised but refer the reader to
another source where I have dealt with those: Pieterse 2006.
brenner and Theodore 2002.
see Fernandes 2007; Ministry of Cities 2005.
This avenue of area-based planning has attracted a lot of scholarly criticism; see for example Miraftab 2007.
see Appadurai 2002; swilling 2006, on such counter-governmentalities in
the practices of shack/slum dwellers International.
scott et al. 2002.
Healey 2007.
barton et al. 2003: 1.
Chapter 8
1. sallis 2000: 13–14.
2. see: Parnell and Pieterse 1999: 7.
188
city futures
3. The general structural causes of poverty at a global scale are clearly and
aptly summarized by Christian Aid: ‘Poverty is caused by unequal power
relations within and amongst countries. structural causes of poverty
ensure an adverse redistribution from the poor to the rich: the debt service
burden, unfair terms of trade and trade rules that favour rich companies
based in the North, and the lack of resources for investment. Market
incentives ensure that the beneits of technology and globalization accrue
to the rich. Present systems of governance are ill-equipped to address
these causes; there are no accountability systems to regulate transnational
corporations and only imperfect accountability for the IMF, the World
bank and the WTo. Amongst attempted solutions, economic growth has
enjoyed the greatest support. but even “pro-poor” growth has failed to
overcome poverty, because it does not challenge the unequal distribution
of resources. In fact, macroeconomic reform and iscal stringency have
required governments to withdraw resources from poor people’ (quoted
in Christie and Warburton 2001: 114).
4. see Pieterse 2001 for the sources that inform this typology.
5. Fowler 1997.
6. For a fuller review of these debates, see Pieterse 2001.
7. Pieterse and van donk 2002.
8. Part of the problem of the left has been its ambivalence towards institutions, if not downrights dismissal of them because the codiication that
accompanies institutionalization tends to encrust new lines of inclusion/
exclusion. This is not the place to explore this theme in any great depth
but I do think that the fear of contamination that invariably accompanies
institutionalization is an important part of why progressives are often so
short on implementable alternatives with regard to urban policy.
9. Total autonomy or independence is, of course, highly unlikely and improbable, especially since former anti-colonial movements are often today part
of the ruling elite in democracies of the south. As a consequence, these
movements/parties remain hugely inluential in shaping the dynamics
within civil society.
10. The organizational sensibility I have in mind here is analogous to the
critical praxis that arises from Freierean critical pedagogy, which in turn
can be extended to the politics of decolonizing interiority of Frantz
Fanon and steve biko. The evocative theorizations of organizational
development scholar Alan kaplan (2000) come to mind.
11. see van donk et al. 2008; Harrison et al. 2003.
12. For example, see Fernandes 2007.
13. Pieterse 2006.
References
Abers, r. (2000) Inventing Local Democracy: Grassroots Politics in Brazil, boulder
Co and London: Lynne rienner.
Ahluwalia, P. (2001) Politics and Post-Colonial Theory: African Inflections, London:
routledge.
Alvarez, s., dagnino, e., and escobar, A. (1998) ‘Introduction: The Cultural
and the Political in Latin American social Movements’, in s. Alvarez, e.
dagnino and A. escobar (eds), Cultures of Politics, Politics of Cultures: Revisioning Latin American Social Movements, boulder Co and oxford: Westview
Press.
Amin, A. (2002) ‘ethnicity and the Multicultural City’, Environment and Planning
34(6): 959–80.
Amin, A. (2006) ‘The Good City’, Urban Studies 43(5/6): 1009–23.
Amin, A., and Thrift, N. (2002) Cities: Reimagining the Urban, Cambridge: Polity
Press.
Amin, A., and Thrift, N. (2005) ‘What is Left? only the Future’, Antipode
37(2): 220–38.
Andersson, G. (1999) ‘Partnerships between Cbos, NGos and Government
in south Africa: Insights derived from experience’, Pretoria: UsAId
south Africa.
Appadurai, A. (2002) ‘deep democracy: Urban Governmentality and the
Horizon of Politics’, Public Culture 14(1): 21–47.
Appadurai, A. (2004) ‘The Capacity to Aspire: Culture and the Terms of
recognition’, in V. rao and M. Walton (eds), Culture and Public Action,
stanford CA: stanford University Press.
Ashcroft, b. (2001) Post-Colonial Transformations, London: routledge.
190
city futures
Ashcroft, b., and Ahulwalia, P. (1999) Edward Said: The Paradox of Identity,
London: routledge.
Atkinson, A. (2004) ‘Urbanization in a Neoliberal World – exploring escape
routes’, City 8(1): 89–108.
Atkinson, A. (2005) ‘Urban development: reviving and Activating Utopian
strategies’, City 9(3): 279–95.
barker, C. (2000) Cultural Studies: Theory and Practice, London: sage.
barkin, d. (1997) ‘Will Higher Productivity Improve Living standards?’, in
r. burgess, M. Carmona and T. kolstee (eds), The Challenge of Sustainable
Cities: Neoliberalism and Urban Strategies in Developing Countries, London: zed
books.
barnard, A., and Armstrong, G. (1998) ‘Learning and Policy Integration’,
in J. schnurr and s. Holtz (eds), The Cornerstone of Development: Integrating
Environmental, Social and Economic Policies. boca raton: Lewis Publishers
and IdrC.
barnett, C. (2005) ‘Consolations of Neoliberalism’, Geoforum 36(1): 7–12.
barton, H., Grant, M., and Guise, r. (2003) Shaping Neighbourhoods: A Guide for
Health, Sustainability and Vitality, London and New York: spon Press.
bauman, T., and Mitlin, d. (2002) ‘The south African Homeless Federation:
Investing in the Poor’, paper presented at rural and Urban development
conference, rietvleidam: History Workshop and National Land
Committee.
bayat, A. (1997) Street Politics: Poor People’s Movements in Iran, New York: Columbia
University Press.
bayat, A. (2000) ‘social Movements, Activism and social development in
the Middle east’ Civil Society and Social Movements Programme Paper, Geneva:
UNrIsd.
benjamin, s. (2004) ‘Urban Land Transformation for Pro-poor economies’,
Geoforum 35(2): 177–87.
bond, P. (2000) Elite Transition: From Apartheid to Neoliberalism in South Africa,
London and Pietermaritzburg: Pluto and University of Natal Press.
borja, J., and Castells, M. (1997) Local and Global: The Management of Cities in the
Information Age, London: earthscan.
brenner, N., and Theodore, N. (2002) ‘Cities and the Geographies of “Actually
existing Neoliberalism”’, Antipode 34(3): 349–79.
bridge, G., and Watson, s. (2000) ‘City differences’, in G. bridge and s.
Watson (eds), A Companion to the City, oxford: blackwell.
brillembourg, A., and klumpner, H. (2005) ‘Introduction’, in A. brilembourg,
k. Feireiss and H. klumpner (eds), Informal City: Caracas Case, London:
Prestel.
byrne, d. (2001) Understanding the Urban, New York: Palgrave.
Cabbalero, M.C. (2003) Biblored: Colombia’s Innovative Library Network. Washington dC: Council on Library and Information resources.
Caldeira, T.P.r. (2004) ‘Hip-Hop, Periphery, and spatial segregation in são
references
191
Paulo’, paper presented at the symposium ‘Urban Traumas: The City and
disasters’, Center of Contemporary Culture of barcelona, 7–11 July.
Calvino, I. (1997) Invisible Cities, London: Vintage.
Castells, M. (1997) The Power of Identity, vol. II of The Information Age: Economy,
Society, and Culture, oxford: blackwell.
Christie, I., and Warburton, d. (2001) From Here to Sustainability: Politics in the
Real World, London: earthscan.
Cities Alliance (2001) ‘City development strategies: The Cities Alliance
Perspective’, draft for discussion, Washington dC: Cities Alliance, www.
citiesalliance.org; accessed 23 october 2007.
Cities Alliance (2006) Guide to City Development Strategies: Improving Urban Performance. Washington dC: Cities Alliance.
Clarke, C. (2006) ‘Politics, Violence and drugs in kingston, Jamaica’, Bulletin
of Latin American Research 25(3): 420–40.
Cleaver, F. (2001) ‘Institutions, Agency and the Limitations of Participatory
Approaches to development’, in b. Cooke and U. kothari (eds), Participation: The New Tyranny? London: zed books.
Clifford, J. (2000) ‘Taking Identity Politics seriously: “The Contradictory
stony Ground…”’, in P. Gilroy, L. Grossberg and A. Mcrobbie (eds),
Without Guarantees: In Honour of Stuart Hall. London: Verso.
Coates, N. (2003) Guide to Ecstacity, London: Laurence king.
Cornwall, A. (2004) ‘spaces for Transformation? relections on Issues of
Power and difference in Participation in development’, in s. Hickey and
G. Mohan (eds), Participation: From Tyranny to Transformation. Exploring New
Approaches to Participation in Development, London: zed books.
Cornwall, A., and brock, k. (2005) ‘What do buzzwords do for development
Policy? A Critical Look at “Participation”, “empowerment” and “Poverty
reduction”’, Third World Quarterly 26(7): 1043–60.
davis, M. (2005) Planet of Slums, London: Verso.
de boeck, P., and Plissart, M. (2004) Kinshasa: Tales of the Invisible City, brussels:
Ludion.
de soto, H. (2000) The Mystery of Capital, New York: basic books.
de soto, H. (2005) ‘The Challenge of Connecting Informal and Formal Property systems: some relections based on the Case of Tanzania’, Lima:
Instituto Libertad y democracia.
de sousa santos, b. (1995) Towards a New Common Sense: Law, Science and Politics
in the Pragmatic Transition, London: routledge.
de sousa santos, b. (1999) ‘Towards a Multicultural Conception of Human
rights’, in M. Featherstone and s. Lash (eds), Spaces of Culture: City – Nation
– World, London: sage.
de souza, M.L. (2005) ‘Urban Planning in an Age of Fear: The Case of rio de
Janeiro’, International Development Planning Review 27(1): 1–19.
dean, M. (1999) Governmentality: Power and Rule in Modern Society, London:
sage.
192
city futures
desai, A. (2000) The Poors of Chatsworth: Race, Class and Social Movements in
Post-Apartheid South Africa, durban: Madiba.
development Works (2003) ‘Cities Alliance Project on a Pro-Poor slum
Upgrading Framework for south Africa for submission to the Cities
Alliance/United Nations Centre for Human settlements’, report for
People’s dialogue, Johannesburg.
doerr, J. (2006) ‘California’s Global-Warming solution’, Time, 3 september,
www.time.com/time/magazine/article/0,9171,1531324,00.html; accessed 30
November 2007.
duiker, s. (2000) Thirteen Cents, Cape Town: david Philip.
eade, J., and Mele, C. (2002) ‘Introduction: Understanding the City’, in J. eade
and C. Mele (eds), Understanding the City: Contemporary and Future Perspectives,
oxford: blackwell.
edmunds, d., and Wollenberg, e. (2001) ‘A strategic Approach to Multistakeholder Negotiations’, Development and Change 32(2): 231–53.
edwards, M. (2001) ‘Global Civil society and Community exchanges: A different Form of Movement’, Environment and Urbanisation 13(2): 145–9.
evans, P. (1996) ‘Introduction: development strategies across the Public–
Private divide’, World Development 24(6): 1033–37.
evans, P. (2002) ‘Introduction: Looking for Agents of Urban Liveability in
a Globalized Political economy’, in P. evans (ed.), Livable Cities? Urban
Struggles for Livelihood and Sustainability, berkeley: University of California
Press.
Fernandez, e. (2002) ‘The Inluence of de soto’s The Mystery of Capital’, Land
Lines, January: 5–8.
Fernandez, e. (2007) ‘Land Governance and Popular Participation in Urban
Management. Possibilities and Limitations of socio-spatial and Political
Inclusion in brazil’, paper presented at Western Cape Integrated development Planning Annual Conference, Cape Town, May.
Ferrándiz, F. (2004) ‘The body as Wound: Possession, Malandros and everyday
Violence in Venezuela’, Critique of Anthropolog y 24(2): 107–33.
Finn, M., and rahl, G. (2007) ‘The environment: Let’s Get It right’, Strateg y
& Business 47: 46.
Flood, r.L. (1999) Rethinking the Fifth Discipline: Learning within the Unknowable,
London and New York: routledge.
Florida, r. (2005) Cities and the Creative Class, New York and London:
routledge.
Flyvbjerg, b. (1998) ‘empowering Civil society: Habermas, Foucault and the
Question of Conlict’, in M. douglas and J. Friedmann (eds), Cities for
Citizens: Planning and the Rise of Civil Society in a Global Age, Chichester:
John Wiley.
Flyvbjerg, b. (2001) Making Social Science Matter: Why Social Inquiry Fails and How
it Can Count Again, London: sage.
Flyvbjerg, b. (2004) ‘Phronetic Planning research: Theoretical and Methodological relections’, Planning Theory and Practice 5(3): 283–306.
references
193
Fowler, A. (1997) Striking a Balance: A Guide to Enhancing the Effectiveness of Nongovernmental Organisations in International Development, London: earthscan.
Friedmann, J. (2002) The Prospect of Cities, Minneapolis and London: University
of Minnesota Press.
Fung, A., and Wright, e.o. (2001) ‘deepening democracy: Innovations in
empowered Participatory Governance’, Politics and Society 29(1): 5–41.
Gabardi, W. (2001) Negotiating Postmodernism, Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press.
Gabel, M., and bruner, H. (2003) Global Inc. An Atlas of the Multinational Corporation, New York: New Press.
Goetz, A., and Gaventa, J. (2001) ‘From Consultation to Inluence: bringing
Citizen Voice and Client Focus into service delivery’, IDS Working Paper
no. 138, brighton: Institute for development studies.
Goetz, A.M., and Lister, s. (2001) ‘The Politics of Civil society engagement
with the state: A Comparative Analysis of south Africa and Uganda’,
brighton: Institute of development studies.
Goverde, H., Cerny, P.G., Haugaard, M., and Lentner, H. (2000) ‘General
Introduction: Power in Contemporary Politics’, in H. Goverde, P.G. Cerny,
M. Haugaard and H. Lentner (eds), Power in Contemporary Politics: Theories,
Practices, Globalizations, London: sage.
Graham, s. (2000) ‘Constructing Premium Network spaces: relections on
Infrastructure Networks and Contemporary Urban development’, International Journal of Urban and Regional Research 24(1): 183–4.
Graham, s., and Marvin, s. (2001) Splintering Urbanism: Networked Infrastructures, Technological Mobilities and the Urban Condition, London and New York:
routledge.
Gunder, M. (2003) ‘Passionate Planning for the other’s desire: An Agonistic response to the dark side of Planning’, Progress in Planning 60(3):
235–319.
Habitat (United Nations Centre for Human settlements) (1996) The Habitat
Agenda, Nairobi: Habitat.
Hall, s. (1996) ‘When Was “The Post-Colonial”? Thinking at the Limit’, in I.
Chambers and L. Curti (eds), The Postcolonial Question: Common Skies, Divided
Horizons, London: routledge.
Harrison, P., Huchzermeyer, M., and Mayekiso, M. (eds) (2003) Confronting
Fragmentation: Housing and Urban Development in a Democratising Society, Cape
Town: UCT Press.
Harvey, d. (2006) Space of Global Capitalism: Towards a Theory of Uneven Geographical Development, London: Verso.
Healey, P. (1997) Collaborative Planning: Shaping Places in Fragmented Societies,
London: Macmillan.
Healey, P. (2000a) ‘Planning in relational space and Time: responding to
New Urban realities’, in G. bridge and s. Watson (eds), A Companion to
the City, oxford: blackwell.
Healey, P. (2000b) ‘Planning Theory and Urban and regional dynamics:
194
city futures
A Comment on Yiftachel and Huxley’, International Journal of Urban and
Regional Research 24(4): 917–21.
Healey, P. (2002) ‘on Creating the “City” as a Collective resource’, Urban
Studies 39(10): 1777–92.
Healey, P. (2004) ‘Creativity and Urban Governance’, Policy Studies 25(2):
87–102.
Healey, P. (2007) Urban Complexity and Spatial Strategies: Towards a Relational
Planning for Our Times, London: routledge.
Heller, P. (2001) ‘Moving the state: The Politics of democratic decentralization in kerala, south Africa, and Porto Alegre’, Politics and Society 29(1):
131–63.
Hillier, J. (2002) ‘direct Action and Agonism in democratic Planning Processes’, in P. Allmendinger and M. Twedwr-Jones (eds), Planning Futures:
New Directions for Planning Theory, London: routledge.
Holston, J. (1998) ‘spaces of Insurgent Citizenship’, in L. sandercock (ed.),
Making the Invisible Visible: A Multicultural Planning History, berkeley: University of California Press.
Huchzermeyer, M. (2001) ‘Housing for the Poor: Negotiated Housing Policy
in south Africa’, Habitat International 25: 303–31.
Jack, M. (2006) ‘Urbanisation, sustainable Growth and Poverty reduction in
Asia’, IDS Bulletin 37(3): 101–14.
kaplan, A. (2002) Development Practitioners and Social Process: Artists of the Invisible,
London: Pluto.
khan, F., and Pieterse, e. (2006) ‘The Homeless People’s Alliance: Purposive
Creation and Ambiguated realities’, in r. ballard, A. Habib and I. Valodia
(eds), Voices of Protest: Social Movements in Post-Apartheid South Africa, Pietermaritzburg: University of kwazulu–Natal Press.
Landry, C. (2000) The Creative City: A Toolkit for Urban Innovators, London:
Comedia and earthscan.
Lee, k.N. (2007) ‘An Urbanizing World’, in L. starke (ed.), State of the World
2007: Our Urban Future, New York and London: W.W. Norton.
Lingis, A. (1994) Abuses, berkeley: University of California Press.
Lingis, A. (2004) Dangerous Emotions, berkeley: University of California
Press.
Long, N. (2001) Development Sociolog y: Actor Perspectives, London: routledge.
Lüdeking, G., and Williams, C. (1999) ‘Poverty, Participation and Government
enablement. A summary of Findings, Lessons Learned and recommendations of Habitat/Iss evaluation research (1996–1998)’, Nairobi: Habitat.
Manor, J. (1999) The Political Economic of Democratic Decentralization, Washington
dC: World bank.
Manor, J. (2004) ‘democratisation with Inclusion: Political reforms and
People’s empowerment at the Grassroots’, Journal of Human Development
5(1): 5–29.
Marcuse, P. (2000) ‘Cities in Quarters’, in G. bridge and s. Watson (eds), A
Companion to the City, oxford: blackwell.
references
195
Massey, d. (1999) ‘Cities in the World’, in d. Massey, J. Allen and s. Pile (eds),
City Worlds, New York: routledge.
McMichael, P. (2000) Development and Social Change: A Global Perspective, Thousand oaks CA: Pine Forge Press.
Ministry of Cities (2005) Land Regularization, brasilia: Ministry of Cities.
Miraftab, F. (2004) ‘Making Neo-liberal Governance: The disempowering
Work of empowerment’, International Planning Studies 9(4): 239–59.
Miraftab, F. (2007) ‘Governing Post Apartheid spatiality: Implementing City
Improvement districts in Cape Town’, Antipode 39(4): 602–26.
Moore, d. (1994) ‘optics of engagement: Power, Positionality and African
studies’, Transition 63: 121–7.
Moreno, e.L., and Warah, r. (2006) ‘Urban and slum Trends in the 21st
Century’, UN Chronicle Online Edition 2, www.un.org/Pubs/chronicle/2006/
issue2/0206p24.htm; accessed 19 November 2007.
Mossberger, k., and stoker, G. (2001) ‘The evolution of Urban regime Theory:
The Challenge of Conceptualisation’, Urban Affairs Review 36(6): 810–35.
Mouffe, C. (2000) The Democratic Paradox, London and New York: Verso.
Mumtaz, b., and Wegelin, e. (2001) Guiding Cities: The UNDP/UNCHS/World
Bank Urban Management Programme, Nairobi: UN–Habitat.
Naím, M. (2006) Illicit: How Smugglers, Traffickers, and Copycats are Hijacking the
Global Economy, London: Heinemann.
Neate, P. (2003) Where You’re At: Notes from the Frontline of a Hip Hop Planet,
London: bloomsbury.
Neate, P., and Platt, d. (2006) Culture is Our Weapon: Afroreggae in the Favelas of
Rio, London: Latin American bureau.
Nederveen Pieterse, J. (2001) ‘Participatory democracy reconceived’, Futures
33(5): 407–22.
Neuwirth, r. (2005) Shadow Cities: A Billion Squatters, A New Urban World, New
York: routledge.
NsFWUs (National science Foundation Workshop on Urban sustainability)
(2000) ‘Towards a Comprehensive Geographical Perspective on Urban
sustainability. Final report of the 1998 National science Foundation
Workshop on Urban sustainability’, rutgers University, New Jersey.
okri, b. (1997) A Way of Being Free, London: Phoenix House.
orbach, s. (1996) ‘Couching Anxieties’, in s. dunant and r. Porter (eds), The
Age of Anxiety, London: Virago.
Pardue, d. (2004) ‘“Writing in the Margins”: brazilian Hip-Hop as an educational Project’, Anthropolog y and Education Quarterly 34(4): 411–32.
Parnell, s. (2007) ‘Urban Governance in the south: The Politics of rights and
development’, in k. Cox, M. Louw and J. robinson (eds), A Handbook of
Political Geography, London: sage.
Parnell, s., and Pieterse, e. (1999) ‘Municipal Poverty reduction Framework:
Technical reports on Municipal Poverty reduction Frameworks for the
Cape Metropolitan Area’, Cape Town: Isandla Institute.
Parnell, s., and Pieterse, e. (2007) realising the “right to the City”:
196
city futures
Institutional Imperatives for Tackling Urban Poverty’, paper presented to
Living on the Margins Conference, Centre for Chronic Poverty, Plaas and
Isandla Institute, Cape Town.
People’s dialogue (1996) ‘What Are Those bastards Up To Now? A review
of the Interactions between the south African Homeless People’s Federation/People dialogue Alliance and the south African Government of
National Unity’, www.dialogue.org.za/pd/bastards.htm.
People’s dialogue (2000) ‘The Age of Cities and organisations of the Urban
Poor’, unpublished mimeo (available from authors).
Pieterse, e. (2000) Participatory Urban Governance: Practical Approaches, Regional
Trends and UMP Experiences 25, Nairobi: Urban Management Programme.
Pieterse, e. (2001) ‘In Praise of Transgression: Notes on Institutional synergy
and Poverty reduction’, Development Update 3(4): 39–69.
Pieterse, e. (2004) ‘sketches of development Praxis against a Horizon of
Complexity’, in e. Pieterse and F. Meintjies (eds), Voices of the Transition:
The Politics, Poetics and Practices of Development in South Africa. Johannesburg:
Heinemann.
Pieterse, e. (2005) ‘Transgressing the Limits of Possibility: Working Notes on
a relational Model of Urban Politics’, in A. simone and A. Abouhani (eds),
Urban Processes and Change in Africa, London: zed books.
Pieterse, e. (2006) ‘building with ruins and dreams: exploratory Thoughts
on realising Integrated Urban development through Crises’, Urban Studies
43(2): 285–304.
Pieterse, e., and van donk, M. (2002) ‘Capacity building for Poverty reduction’, Dark Roast Occasional Paper 8, Cape Town: Isandla Institute.
rakodi, C., and Lloyd-Jones, T. (eds) (2002) Urban Livelihoods: A People-Centred
Approach to Reducing Poverty, London: earthscan.
riddell, r. (2004) Sustainable Urban Planning: Tipping the Balance, oxford:
blackwell.
robinson, J. (2002) ‘Global and World Cities: A View from off the Map’,
International Journal of Urban and Regional Research 26(3): 531–54.
robinson, J., and Tinker, J. (1998) ‘reconciling ecological, economic, and
social Imperatives’, in J. schnurr and s. Holtz (eds), The Cornerstone of
Development: Integrating Environmental, Social, and Economic Policies, ottawa and
boca raton: IdrC and Lewis Publishers.
rodgers, d. (2004) ‘“disembedding” The City: Crime, Insecurity and the
spatial organization of Managua, Nicaragua’, Environment and Urbanization
16(2): 113–23.
roe, e. (1993) ‘Against Power: For the Politics of Complexity’, Transition 62:
90–104.
roy, A. (2005) ‘Urban Informality: Towards an epistemology of Planning’,
Journal of the American Planning Association 71(2): 147–58.
roy, A., and Alsayyad, N. (eds) (2004) Urban Informality: Transnational Perspectives
from the Middle East, Latin America and South Asia, Lanham Md: Lexington
books.
references
197
sallis, J. (2000) Gently into the Land of Meateaters, seattle: black Heron Press.
sandercock, L. (1998) ‘The death of Modernist Planning: radical Praxis for a
Postmodern Age’, in M. douglas and J. Friedmann (eds), Cities for Citizens:
Planning and the Rise of Civil Society in a Global Age, Chichester: John Wiley.
sassen, s. (1994) Cities in a World Economy, London: Pine Forge Press.
satterthwaite, d. (2007) ‘The Transition to a Predominantly Urban World
and Its Underpinnings’, Human settlements discussion Paper, London:
International Institute for environment and development.
savage, M., Warde, A., and Ward, k. (2003) Urban Sociolog y, Capitalism and
Modernity, London: Palgrave Macmillan.
scott, J.C. (1997) ‘The Infrapolitics of subordinate Groups’, in M. rahnema
and V. bawtree (eds), The Post-Development Reader, London: zed books.
sharp, J., et al. (2000) ‘entanglements of Power: Geographies of domination/
resistance’, in J. sharp, P. routledge, C. Philo and r. Paddison (eds), Entanglements of Power: Geographies of Domination/Resistance, London: routledge.
shubane, k. (1995) ‘revisiting south African Conceptions of Civil society’, in
r. Humpries and M. reitzes (eds), Civil Society after Apartheid, Johannesburg:
CPs and Fes.
simone, A. (2004) For the City Yet to Come: Changing African Life in Four Cities,
durham NC and London: duke University Press.
simons, J. (1995) Foucault and the Political, London and New York: routledge.
smith, M.P. (2001) Transnational Urbanism: Locating Globalization, oxford:
blackwell.
smolka, M., and Larangeira, A. (2007) ‘Informality and Poverty in Latin
American Urban Policies’, unpublished paper.
sorkin, M. (2001) Some Assembly Required, Minneapolis: University of Minnesota
Press.
soudien, C. (2003) ‘routes to Adulthood: becoming a Young Adult in the
New south Africa’, IDS Bulletin 34(1): 63–71.
squires, J. (2002) ‘democracy as Flawed Hegemon’, Economy and Society 31(1):
132–51.
standing, A. (2004) ‘out of the Mainstream: Critical relections on organised
Crime in the Western Cape’, in b. dixon and e. van der spuy (eds), Justice
Gained? Crime and Crime Control in South Africa’s Transition, Cape Town:
UCT Press.
stevenson, d. (2003) Cities and Urban Cultures, Maidenhead: open University
Press.
sutcliffe, b. (2001) 100 Ways of Seeing an Unequal World, London: zed books.
swilling, M. (2006) ‘sustainability and Infrastructure Planning in south Africa:
A Cape Town Case study’, Environment and Urbanization 18(1): 23–50.
swilling, M., and russell, b. (2002) The Size and Scope of the Non-profit Sector in
South Africa, durban/Johannesburg: Center for Civil society/Graduate
school of Public and development Management.
Tajbakhsh, k. (2001) The Promise of the City: Space, Identity, and Politics in Contemporary Social Thought, berkeley: University of California Press.
198
city futures
Tannerfeldt, G., and Ljung, P. (2006) More Urban Less Poor: An Introduction to
Urban Development and Management, London: earthscan.
Tendler, J. (1997) Good Government in the Tropics, baltimore and London: Johns
Hopkins University Press.
Tibaijuka, A. (2005) ‘Poverty and the Urban Agenda’, inFocus, August: 18–19,
brasilia: UNdP International Poverty Centre.
UN Millennium Project (2005) A Home in the City, UN Millennium Task Force
report on Improving the Lives of slums dwellers, London: earthscan.
UNdP (United Nations development Programme) (1998) Human Development
Report 1998: Consumption for Human Development, New York: UNdP.
UNdP (United Nations development Programme) (2005) Human Development
Report 2005: International Cooperation at a Crossroads: Aid, Trade and Security in
an Unequal World, New York: UNdP.
UNFPA (United Nations Population Fund) (2007) State of the World Population
2007, New York: UNFPA.
Unger, r.M. (1998) Democracy Realised: The Progressive Alternative, London:
Verso.
UN–Habitat (1996) Istanbul Declaration, Nairobi: United Nations Council for
Human settlements.
UN–Habitat (United Nations Human settlements Programme) (2001) Cities
in a Globalizing World: Global Report on Human Settlements 2001, London:
earthscan.
UN–Habitat (United Nations Human settlement Programme) (2002) ‘Global
Campaign on Urban Governance. Concept Paper’, Nairobi: UN–Habitat.
UN–Habitat (United Nations Human settlements Programme) (2003) The Challenge of Slums: Global Report on Human Settlements 2003, London: earthscan.
UN–Habitat (United Nations Human settlements Programme) (2004a) Global
Campaign for Secure Tenure: A Tool for Advocating the Provision of Adequate Shelter
for the Urban Poor, concept paper, 2nd edn, Nairobi: UN–Habitat.
UN–Habitat (United Nations Human settlements Programme) (2004b) Land
for All, Nairobi: UN–Habitat.
UN–Habitat (United Nations Human settlements Programme) (2006) State of
the World’s Cities 2006/7: The Millennium Development Goals and Urban Sustainability. London: earthscan.
United Nations (2006) World Urbanization Prospects: The 2005 Revision, Fact sheet
2: Urban Population in Major Urban Areas, department of economic and
social Affairs, Population division.
van donk, M., swilling, M., Pieterse, e., and Parnell, s. (eds) (2008) Consolidating Developmental Local Government: Lessons from the South Africa Experience,
Cape Town: UCT Press.
Walsh, b. (2007) ‘California’s Christmas List: Clean Air’, Time, 8 November,
www.time.com/time/printout/0,8816,1682116,00.html; accessed 30 November 2007.
Watson, V. (2006) ‘deep difference: diversity, Planning and ethics’, Planning
Theory 5(1): 31–50.
references
199
Watson, V. (2007) ‘revisiting the role of Urban Planning’, concept paper prepared for UN–Habitat for the 2009 Global report on Human settlements,
Cape Town: school of Architecture, Planning and Geomatics, University
of Cape Town.
Williams, G. (2004) ‘evaluating Participatory development: Tyranny, Power
and (re)politicisation’, Third World Quarterly 25(3): 557–78.
Winton, A. (2004) ‘Urban Violence: A Guide to the Literature’, Environment
and Urbanization 16(2): 165–84.
World bank (2000) Cities in Transition, Washington dC: World bank.
Wright, L., and Montezuma, r. (2004) ‘reclaiming Public space: The economic, environmental, and social Impacts of bogotá’s Transformation’,
bogota: Human City Foundation.
Wright, r. (2002) ‘Transnational Corporations and the Global division of
Labour’, in r.J. Johnston, P.J. Taylor and M.J. Watts (eds), Geographies of
Global Change: Remapping the World, oxford: blackwell.
Ya, Y., and Weliwita, A. (2007) ‘The Urban Informal economy – New Policy
Approaches’, Habitat Debate, June: 4–5.
You, N. (2007) ‘sustainable for Whom? The Urban Millennium and Challenges
for redeining the Global development Planning Agenda’, City 11(2):
214–20.
Young, I.M. (2000) ‘A Critique of Integration as the remedy for segregation’,
in d. bell and A. Haddour (eds), City Visions, London: Longman.
zaluar, (2006) ‘brazilian drug Worlds and the Fate of democracy’, Interventions
7(3): 338–41.
zetter, r. (2004) ‘Market enablement and the Urban sector’, in r. zetter and
M. Hamza (eds), Market Economy and Urban Change: Impacts on the Developing
World, London: earthscan.
Index
accountability, elected politicians, 91, 94
Accra, Ghana, 34
adaptive strategies, 42
Africa: cultural ferment, 127; rural
populations, 20; sub-saharan, 22, 30;
urban population growth, 19
African National Congress, 93
Afroreggae, brazilian music group,
122–5
agenda setting, capacity, 88
agriculture, GdP decline, 20
AIds pandemic, vulnerable children,
54
Alhuwalia, P., 149
alliances, multi-class environmental,
139; opportunities for, 99
alternative approaches, precise
delineation need, 175
anthropology and sociology, urban, 110
Appadurai, Arjun, 98, 103
Argentina, neoliberalism impact, 64
Ashcroft, b., 149
Asia: car use, 140; inancial crisis,
development policy impact, 41;
NIC’s world export share, 22; rural
populations, 20; urban population
growth, 19
aspirations, ‘cultural map of’, 98
autonomy, civil society actors, 94;
pragmatic autonomism, 119–20
balance of forces, 12
balkanization, urban socio-ethnic, 26,
156
bangalore, 138
barcelona, renewal, 70
bayat, Asef, 103, 109, 113–15
berlin Wall, fall of, 64
biko, steve, 96
bogotá, public transport, 59, 140
bolnick, Joel, 116
boosterism projects, 83
borja, Jorge, 70, 76, 92–3
boycotts, local south African, 93
brazil: musical genres, 122; positive
slum examples, 53; social cleansing,
123; urban literature, 175; urban
violence, 120
brundtland Commission, 132
‘business climate’, fetishized, 37, 78
byrne, david, 4
California, UsA, 140
capacity–capability enhancement, 116
Cape Town, 27; criminal gangs, 33
Caracas, 120; Informal City: Caracas Case,
119; slums, 109
cars, 140
Castells, Manuel, 70, 76, 92–3
Central Asssociation of Favelas, 123
centralization, tendency to, 64
index
Centre for the study of developing
societies, University of delhi, 126
Chile, positive slum examples, 53
Chimurenga, 127–8
China, 22
Circa 1998 group, delhi, 125
Cities Alliance, 14, 36, 54, 62, 70–71, 73,
76, 80–81, 83, 93, 143, 175; approach
of, 72; consensus model assumption,
75, 77–8
city(ies): competitiveness imperatives,
23–4, 79, 80; creative, 9; cultural
sensitivity to, 176; discursive
terrains, 81; identity, 101, 103;
inclusive ideal, 66; medium-sized
prevalence, 38; rebus character, 5,
161; regions, 138; slums as
constituents of, 111; structural
informality, 30; ‘world class’
imperatives, 102, 133, 138, 147
City Consultation processes, UMP, 69
City development strategy approach,
World bank (Cds) 70–75, 78–80,
175; methodology proposed, 81;
policy discourse, 102
City of God, 9
civil society organizations, 134, 164;
autonomy need, 94, 173; visibility
need, 173
claim-making practices, 116
Cleaver, Frances, 88
Coates, Nigel, 109–11
Colombia: bogotá, 59, 140; positive
slum examples, 53; urban violence,
121
communicative planning approach, 1,
77–8
community relations, romanticized,
88
complexity, 88; daily life, 128; the poor,
7; theory, 4
conservatism, forces of, 131
consumerism, infrastructural, 25, 27
co-option, inancial dependency caused,
100
‘Cosmopolis’, 87
‘creative class’, 138
credit, access to, 49
criminal economics, 123
criminal gangs: drugs, 174; informal
power, 33
crisis, points of, 88
CUFA, brazilian initiative, 123,124
culture, 101; participatory democratic,
201
69; local resources, 98; perspective
of, 111
Culture is Our Weapon, 121
Curitiba, public transport, 59, 140
dakar, 138
davis, Mike, 2, 6, 104; Planet of Slums, 1,
9
davos annual conference, 141
de soto, Hernando, 45; ahistoricism of,
50; The Mystery of Capital, 40, 48–9
decentralization, unfunded, 136
delhi; Circa 1998 group, 125; sarai
Initiative, 126–7
deliberation, systems of, 105
‘dematerialization’, 139–40
democracy: experience of
organizational, 99; participatory, 36,
69, 137; radical, 15, 84, 86, 105, 134,
156, 172; space of, 163; underdeveloped local, 64; values, 98
development, urban: discourses, 113;
issues complexity, 4; literature, 97;
mainstream depoliticized, 14, 36;
multi-sectoral approaches, 154;
participatory discourses, 62; politics
of, 11; rights-based approach, 66–7;
sectoral-based approaches, 170;
studies impasse, 2; see also
sustainability
‘difference’, notion of, 144
direct action, non-violent, 95
discourse(s): legitimizing, 102;
mainstream deconstructed, 174;
mainstream nominal, 171;
participatory plans, 159; power of,
101; questioning of, 103; rightsbased, 55; urban development, 113
discursive formations, 12
division of labour, international, 21
drug traficking, 121
ecstacity, 109–11
education, 166; investment in, 22; unreal
assumption of base size, 102
elite(s), 8, 78, 95, 137; enclaves, 9; in
nominal democracies, 67; interests
prioritized, 73; local gatekeeping
role, 169; pacts among, 91;
perspectives on planning, 162;
privileged needs of, 79; serviced,
151; unregulated actions, 68; vested
interests, 93, 104
empowerment: notion of, 8; recursive,
202
city futures
4, 7, 13, 162, 172
‘encroachment of the ordinary’, 103–4,
109
energy, renewable alternatives, 59
environmental politics: degradation,
148; economics, 141; health, 73
epistemic community(ies), 148–50,
172–3
europe, regional planning, 155
everyday, the, phenomenology of, 14
exclusion, zones of informal, 18
exploitation, conditions of, 2
export-processing zones, 22
Fanon, Frantz, 96
favelas, 120–21, 123; Afroreggae, 122;
hip-hop projects, 125 rio de Janeiro,
9
federations, 117; slum dwellers, 54
Fernandez, edesio, 49–50
inancial services sector, city
competition for, 35
Flyvbjerg, bent, 149
Foucault, Michel, 101; concept of
power, 90; ‘governmentality’
concept, 86
Fowler, Alan, 169
freehold title argument, 45, 48; dangers
of, 50
Freire, Paulo, 96
fundamentalist right-wing groups, 96
Gandhi, Mahatma, 96
gang warfare, 121
gated communities, rise of, 7, 27
gender, equity, 43
Global Campaign for secure shelter,
UN–Habitat, 40
Global Campaign for secure Tenure
(GCsT), 42, 44–5, 51–6; ‘key
messages’, 43; advocacy tool, 50;
sustainability approach, 58
Global Campaign on Urban
Governance (GCUG), 14, 61, 65, 70,
91
globalization: framing conditions, 2;
‘hyperglobalist’ domination, 79–80;
property markets impact, 52; spatial
dynamics, 17; subcontracting
production, 21; technological shifts,
19
governance, urban, 66; campaign for
good, see GCUG; culture of, 12–13;
deinition, 87; democratic
conception, 63; dialogical, 77; local
participatory, 91; mainstream
concepts, 62
‘governmentality’, 86; colonial, 25
Graham, stephen, 9, 17, 24–5
Gramsci, Antonio, 148
greenield development, engineered
demand for, 28
Guggenheim Museum, bilbao, 83
Guide to City Development Strategies, 72
Gunder, Michael, 94, 149
Habermas, Jürgen, 105
Habitat Agenda, 1996, 14, 42, 44, 132;
context, 65; declaration, 32, 63
Hall, stuart, 7, 149
Harare, illegal slum evictions, 40
Healey, Patsy, 12, 77, 146–7
Hillier, Jean, 94, 149
hip-hop, brazil, 122, 125
Holston, James, 107
Homeless People’s Federation, see
sAHPF
human rights, 162
‘hybrid’ identities, 144–5
ideas, power of, 148
identity(ies): agency, 85; non-essentialist
conception, 87–8; static ascriptions,
144
inclusion, rhetoric of, 163
India, neoliberalism impact, 64; delhi,
125–7
Indonesia, 22
industrialization, export-oriented, 22
inequality, 8, 24, 34, 106, 131, 134, 141,
148, 156; reproduction of, 145;
segregation reinforcement, 143–4
informal settlements sector:
legalization, 49; support for, 166
informalization, 3
information and knowledge
management, 20
infrastructure: business priority bias,
79, 81–3, 91, 102, 138–9, 147; as
public goods, 24; car culture
supportive, 29; community-based,
167; community-level experiments,
159; ‘connectivity’, 138; discourses,
60; globally connected enclaves, 38;
inclusion/exclusion marker, 25;
labour-intensive provision goal, 58;
private-sector cherry-picking, 30;
proit maximization, 26; regional
index
203
approach need, 53; ‘unbundling’, 26
institutions: arrangements shift aim,
116; capability of, 51; institutionalization, 163; local, 169; need for
stable, 176; representative, 86
insurgent practices, 112
integrated policies, need for, 36
International declaration on Human
rights, 136
Istanbul, Habitat II conference 1996, 32,
39, 62–3, 65, 117
40–41, 54; slum targets, 112–13
Millennium Project, UN, 62
Millennium summit 2000, UN, 8, 41
‘mood shapers’, people, 72
Moore, david, 5
Mouffe, Chantal, 106
multiparty democracy, discourse, 64
‘multiplexity’, 77
Mumbai, 138; slum dwellers’
associations, 98
MV bill, rio de Janeiro, 122–5
Jack, Malcolm, 2
Jamaica, urban violence, 121
Johannesburg, 138
National science Foundation,
Workgroup on Urban sustainability,
132
neighbourhoods: ‘cultural character’,
145; gatekeeping, 7
neoliberalism, 155; global order, 79;
hegemonic, 150; institutional theory,
29; orthodoxy, 41
‘network infrastructures’, 8, 24; public
investments, 9; ‘splintered’, 17
Neuwirth, robert, 104
New York, 127
NGos (non-government
organizations), 51, 170
Nicaragua, urban violence, 121
Nike, worldwide production system,
21–2
nutrition, urban agriculture, 60
kalakuta Trust, 127
kingston, criminal gangs, 33
korea, 22
Lagos, 9, 138
land: ownership regularization
unintended consequences, 44; use,
143, 153
legal framework, secure tenure
necessity, 51
Lingis, Alphonso, 9
livelihood approaches, 10
Local Agenda 21, 10, 153
local economic development strategies,
10
local–global relationship, 171
local government: capability
assessment, 175; Cds view of, 81;
checks and balances, 76;
contradictory imperatives, 17;
democratic quality, 134, 151
London, 127
Lopez de sousa, Marcelo, 121
Malcolm X, 96
managerialism: discourse of, 6; global
managerial class, 138; neoliberal, 155
Manila, 9
marginalization, possibilities of, 3
market forces, compulsory reforms for,
29
Marvin, simon, 9, 17, 24–5
master planning, brazil, 153
Mexico City, 138
micro-inance, 119; access to credit, 49;
see also savings
‘militant refusal’, 6
Millennium development Goals, 8,
okri, ben, 106; Dangerous Love, 9
opportunity, unjust structures, 3
‘organic intellectuals’, 148–50
Pan-Africanist Congress, 93
participatory processes, 68; budgeting,
66; Cds forum idea, 74;
development literature, 169;
potential harm to, 76; stakeholderbased, 77
patronage relationship, slum areas, 33
People’s Housing Partnership Trust,
south Africa, 117–18
Peru, titling programmes, 49
planning, urban: area-based, 154;
community-level spatial, 157–8;
erosion of comprehensive, 25–6;
layers of, 153; processual potential,
156; strategic, 93
policy-prescriptive studies, apolitical, 2
politics: consensus-based, 69–70;
contestation-based, 37; elected
politicians, 92; horizon mediation,
204
city futures
105; human-rights based, 85;
militant, 163; neo-corporatist
mechanisms, 11; parties, 91;
patronage-based, 51, 157;
representative, 11, 90;
representation, 135; rhetoric, 137;
‘space’ for/of 169; symbolic, 100, 103
poor, the urban: agency of, 7; asset
base, 166; inventiveness, 15;
representation of, 68; spatial
segregation, 17; survival strategies,
113
Porto Alegre, public transport, 59
possibility, horizons of, 87
postcolonial experiments, 64
poverty, 163; anti- programmes, 98;
anti- action, 16; asset-based, 57;
realistic deinition, 164; reduction
policy objectives, 65, 73, 79, 165, 170;
urbanization of, 35–6
power: circuits of, 5; discursive, 101,
105; dynamics, 3–6; local dynamics,
12; unequal relations, 84, 146, 149
proactive strategy, notion of, 73
production: lexible specialization, 21;
general value-added, 138; high valueadded, 20
proit maximization, infrastructure
market, 26
pro-poor, nominal policies, 68
‘public opinion’, 105
public spaces, investment in, 166
public transport, 59, 140
‘quiet encroachment practices’, 113
racionas MCs, brazil, 122, 125
radical democracy, 15, 84, 86, 105, 134
radical incrementalism, 4, 6, 13, 143, 162,
172–3
‘rational consensus’, process, 74
rational deliberative model, 105
reagan, ronald, 155
recursive political empowerment, 4, 7,
13, 162, 172
regional development planning, 155
regulatory powers: building, 139–40;
environments, 151; new
opportunities for, 141; spatial
development, 143
representation: politics, 11, 90; tools,
158
resistance, tapestry of, 131
riddell, robert, 52, 142
right to adequate housing proposal, Us
opposition to, 39
‘right to the city’, 158, 171
rights: irst-generation, 135; literature of,
134; second-generation, 135–6; thirdgeneration, 136
rio de Janeiro, 122; criminal gangs, 33;
earth summit 1992, 41, 132, 140, 153;
favelas, 9, 159; irearms deaths, 121
robinson, Jenny, 102
roe, emery, 4–5
rule of law, 86
safety nets, 168
said, edward, 148–9
sallis, James, 176
salvador, brazil, 159
sandercock, Leonie, 87
sanitation services, 10
são Paulo, 138; rap music, 122
sarai initiative, delhi, 126–8
sassen, saskia, 23
satterthwaite, david, 16
savage, M., 144
savings, 170; and loan activities, 116;
-based model exclusion potential,
56; schemes, 118
scott, J.C., 97, 103
segregation, inequality consequence,
143–4
self-esteem, 124
service sectors, 23, 138; knowledgeintensive, 17
services: sectoral, 10, 153; user-pays
model, 26
sewage, reuse of treated, 59–60
shack/slum dwellers International
(sdI), 8, 56, 62, 109, 115–19, 170
shanghai, 138
shelter for all campaign, 14
simone, AbdouMaliq, 3
singapore, 138
skills development, 166
slum areas, 30; city constituent, 111;
discursive boundaries, 56; dweller
organizations, 51, 54; eradication
eviction rationale, 40; global
distribution, 31; global growth, 104;
heterogenous, 32; heterogenous
dwellers, 57; informal governance,
33–4; knowledge economy presence,
127; mainstream policy models, 35;
Manila, 9; Mumbai, 98; negotiated
resettlement goal, 43; possible
index
beneits, 57; re-representation, 109;
strategic arteries, 53
soares, Luis eduardo, 123–4
social capital: community, 170;
literature, 88
social change, welfarist model, 100
social control, 145
social movements: autonomous plans,
157; democratic culture need, 97;
mobilization, 11, 55
solar-based energy, California state
promotion, 140
south Africa, 57, 85; Constitution, 136;
department of Housing, 99, 118;
diplomatic strength, 39; legal
institutions, 67; local government
scholars, 175; private property
rights, 44; public housing, 117;
services tariff system, 142 ; social
protests, 96; stakeholder forums, 93;
UN housing policy review, 43; urban
violence, 121; see also sAHPF
south African Homeless People’s
Federation (sAHPF), 56, 99, 118;
claim-making practices, 115–16;
donor funding, 117
spatiality, appreciation need, 87;
regulatory development tools, 143;
uneven outcomes, 134
stakeholder forums, 69, 72, 93, 94; Cds
composition of, 75–6; multi-, 92, 96,
100
State of Human Settlements 2003 report, 58
state, the: capability of, 162; neoliberal
ideology, 29; welfare, 24
statute of the City, brazil, 153
stiglitz, Joseph, 41
‘strategic articulation’, 11
strategic planning, 155; legitimacy need,
93
structural adjustment policies, impact,
51
subcomandante Marcos, 96
suburban enclaves, 29
survival strategies, urban poor, 113
sustainability, urban, 58, 132, 134, 137,
139, 171; constructivist approach,
133; environmental, 53, 60
swilling, Mark, 58, 118
synectics, 77
Taiwan, 22
Tajbakhsh, kian, 87
Tanzania, titling programmes, 49
205
targeting, geodemographic techniques
27
tariff systems, stepped formulae, 142
tax: local government base, 73; -paying
class size, 52; progressive systems,
142
tenure, housing: group-based forms, 50;
pro-poor policies, 37; regularization,
52; security/insecurity, 36, 39–44, 51,
168; strategic approach need, 53;
systems, 46–8; titling programmes,
49; women’s participation, 54
Thatcher, Margaret, 155
‘tipping points’, idea of, 15, 176
tourism, city competition for, 35
‘trade-offs’, public resources, 17; glib
notions of, 80–81, 83
transgression: ethic of, 106; idea of, 85
transnational corporations (TNCs),
coordinating function, 23
transparency, 135; governments, 66
UN (United Nations): Commissioner
for Human rights, 43; development
Programme, 70; Millennium Task
Force report, A Home in the City,
54–5; slum dwellers data, 31; State of
the World Population 2007, 18;
urbanization statistics, 16
UN–Habitat, 14, 31, 34–6, 54, 70–71,
76–7, 79, 143; advocacy role, 65;
‘Advocacy Tool’, 40; Agenda, 94;
‘good urban governance campaign’,
37, 62, 86, 91, 138, 162; Governance
Concept Paper, 69; policy
prescriptions, 61; ‘residential tenure’
priority, 45; restructuring of, 41;
rights discourse, 43; ‘shelter for all’
campaign, 36; The Challenge of the
slums report, 55; 2004 report, 39
United kingdom, regional planning, 155
urban imaginaries, unarticulated, 11
Urban Management Programme
(UMP), 69
urban studies: mainstream scholarship,
115; structural, 144; theory, 85
Urban Think Tank–Project Caracas
Case, 128
urban violence, 120, 124, 174
urbanism, splintering, 27
urbanization, second wave, 16, 25, 37;
speed of population growth, 18–19
UsA (United states of America), 21,
39
206
city futures
Ussr (Union of soviet socialist
republics), dissoultion of, 64
uTshani Fund, 117
victimhood, 2
Vietnam, 22
visibility need, civil society
organizations, 173
water, unequal costs, 34
West, Cornell, 148–9
women, 66; inheritance rights, 67
work categories, profound change in, 38
World bank, 14, 41, 143; Cds, see City
development strategy; economic
growth agenda, 63
Young, Iris Marion, 143
zero waste policy, 59