Price Regulation of Airport Services
Price Regulation of Airport Services
Price Regulation of Airport Services
$LUSRUW6HUYLFHV ,QTXLU\5HSRUW
5HSRUW1R
-DQXDU\
Commonwealth of Australia 2002
This work is subject to copyright. Apart from any use as permitted under the
Copyright Act 1968, the work may be reproduced in whole or in part for study or
training purposes, subject to the inclusion of an acknowledgment of the source.
Reproduction for commercial use or sale requires prior written permission from Info
Products. Requests and inquiries concerning reproduction and rights should be
addressed to the Manager, Legislative Services, Info Products, Department of
Finance and Administration, GPO Box 1920, Canberra, ACT, 2601.
Publications Inquiries:
Media and Publications
Productivity Commission
Locked Bag 2 Collins Street East
Melbourne VIC 8003
Tel: (03) 9653 2244
Fax: (03) 9653 2303
Email: maps@pc.gov.au
General Inquiries:
Tel: (03) 9653 2100 or (02) 6240 3200
23 January 2002
Dear Treasurer
In accordance with Section 11 of the Productivity Commission Act 1998, we have pleasure
in submitting to you the Commission’s final report on Price Regulation of Airport
Services.
Yours sincerely
Background
2. During 1997 and 1998, long-term leases (50 years with an option to renew for a
further 49 years) were sold over seventeen airports previously operated by the
Federal Airports Corporation, to private sector operators. In July 1998 two wholly
Australian Government-owned companies were formed to acquire leases over the
four Sydney basin airports (Sydney, Bankstown, Camden, Hoxton Park) and
Essendon airport.
3. All 22 of the leased airports are regulated under the Airports Act 1996 and
twelve of the airports (Adelaide, Alice Springs, Brisbane, Canberra, Coolangatta,
Darwin, Hobart, Launceston, Melbourne, Perth, Sydney and Townsville) are
currently subject to prices regulation under the Prices Surveillance Act 1983.
4. Except for Sydney Airport, the prices regulation of the airports comprises a
CPI-X price cap on declared aeronautical services, prices monitoring of aeronautical
related services, and special provisions for necessary new investment at airports. At
Sydney Airport aeronautical services are subject to prices surveillance and
aeronautical related services are subject to price monitoring. The arrangements are
administered by the Australian Competition and Consumer Commission.
IV TERMS OF
REFERENCE
Scope of Inquiry
TERMS OF V
REFERENCE
9. In undertaking the review, the Commission is to advertise nationally, consult
with key interest groups and affected parties, and produce a report.
10. The Government will consider the Commission’s recommendations, and the
Government’s response will be announced as soon as possible after the receipt of
the Commission’s report.
ROD KEMP
21 December 2000
VI TERMS OF
REFERENCE
Contents
Terms of reference IV
Glossary XIII
Overview XVII
1 Introduction 1
1.1 Terms of reference 1
1.2 Background to the current inquiry 2
1.3 The Commission’s approach 4
1.4 Conduct of the inquiry 6
CONTENTS VII
4 Assessing the need for price regulation of airport services: some
preliminary issues 79
4.1 Why regulate prices of airport services? 79
4.2 Potential efficiency and distributional effects of market power 82
4.3 Principles of efficient pricing of airport services 87
4.4 Principles of good regulation 93
VIII CONTENTS
8.2 The price cap: CPI-X and prices notification of aeronautical
services 221
8.3 The price cap: allowable price increases above the cap 231
8.4 Recent changes to price regulation 246
8.5 Price regulation of Sydney Airport services 248
CONTENTS IX
C.3 Arguments for and against a single till 373
References 445
X CONTENTS
Abbreviations and explanations
Abbreviations
AAA Australian Airports Association
AAL Adelaide Airport Limited
ACA Airport Coordination Australia
ACCC Australian Competition and Consumer Commission
ACTO Australian Cargo Terminal Operators
Airports Act Airports Act 1996
APAC Australia Pacific Airports Corporation
APAM Australia Pacific Airports (Melbourne)
APS Australian Protective Services
ASA Airservices Australia
BAC Brisbane Airport Corporation
BARA Board of Airline Representatives of Australia
BTE Bureau of Transport Economics
BTR Bureau of Tourism Research
CAA Civil Aviation Authority (UK)
CASA Civil Aviation Safety Authority
CBD Central business district
CC Commerce Commission (NZ)
CPA Competition Principles Agreement
CPI Consumer Price Index
DoTRD Department of Transport and Regional Development
DoTRS Department of Transport and Regional Services
FAC Federal Airports Corporation
ABBREVIATIONS XI
AND
EXPLANATIONS
GAA General aviation aircraft
GATS General Agreement on Trade in Services
IATA International Air Transport Association
IC Industry Commission
ICAO International Civil Aviation Organization
JUHI Joint user hydrant installation
MTAA Super Fund Motor Trades Association of Australia
Superannuation Fund
MTOW Maximum take-off weight
MUDT Multi-user domestic terminal
NCC National Competition Council
NEC National Electricity Code
NECG Network Economics Consulting Group
NNI Necessary new investment
NTTC Northern Territory Tourist Commission
OECD Organisation for Economic Co-operation and
Development
PC Productivity Commission
Pers. comm. Personal communication
PS Act Prices Surveillance Act 1983
PSA Prices Surveillance Authority
RPT Regular public transport
RRCB Revised Regulatory Cost Base
SACL Sydney Airports Corporation Limited
s. Section
ss Sections
Sub. Submission
Sydney Airport Sydney Kingsford Smith Airport
TP Act Trade Practices Act 1974
Trans. Transcripts
Explanations
Recommendations RECOMMENDATION
Glossary
Access The terms and conditions under which an airport owner will
undertaking provide access, as agreed with the Australian Competition
and Consumer Commission under Part IIIA of the Trade
Practices Act 1974.
GLOSSARY XIII
Core-regulated Leased airports designated as such under the Airports Act
airports 1996. They comprise Adelaide, Alice Springs, Brisbane,
Canberra, Coolangatta, Darwin, Hobart, Launceston,
Melbourne, Perth, Sydney and Townsville airports.
Dual till An arrangement for setting airport charges whereby only the
costs and revenues of providing aeronautical services are
included in the assessment of allowable aeronautical prices.
In other words, aeronautical services are priced on a ‘stand-
alone’ basis, without regard to any net revenues from non-
aeronautical services.
Locational rent Payments to land above opportunity cost that derive from its
locational advantages for a particular use. Locational rents
are consistent with efficient use of a scarce resource and do
not reflect an abuse of market power (which occurs where
scarcity is created by the supplier).
Regional ring A feature of the Slot Management Scheme 1998 for Sydney
fence Airport which effectively creates a separate pool for regional
slots.
XIV GLOSSARY
Revenue Passengers paying any fare on a scheduled regular public
passengers transport service, including passengers travelling on tickets
acquired through frequent flyer programs.
Weight-based Airport charges for the use of airport services based on the
charges weight of the aircraft (usually maximum take-off weight).
GLOSSARY XV
Key messages
• Detailed analysis of the demand and supply characteristics of airport markets
reveals that only four airports — Sydney, Melbourne, Brisbane and Perth — have
substantial market power.
– Adelaide and, to a lesser extent, Canberra and Darwin, have moderate market
power.
– Any market power of other airports does not warrant special regulation.
• The airport services where market power is strongest include facilities for aircraft
movements (runways, taxiways, aprons) and ‘front-door’ vehicle access.
• The scope for airports with market power to use (or abuse) that power is
constrained by commercial pressures and opportunities, particularly the substantial
‘non-aeronautical’ income to be had from promoting airline passenger traffic.
• In these circumstances, because of the risks and potential costs of strict price
controls relative to more light-handed price regulation, such controls are judged not
to be required even at the four airports with substantial market power.
• The uncertain outlook for the aviation market since September 2001 also calls for a
more flexible approach, as the Government has recognised in removing price caps
from other key airports, including Adelaide, Canberra and Darwin.
• The Commission’s preferred approach is to put in place a light-handed regulatory
regime (additional to general competition law) in which all seven airports assessed
as having some market power would have their pricing and other behaviour
monitored for a ‘probationary’ five-year period.
– A review towards the end of the five years would assess the need for continued
regulation (if any) of these airports.
– Monitoring would promote more productive commercial relationships between
airports and airlines, while providing the discipline of the possible reintroduction
of stronger regulation after five years.
• If the Government nevertheless were to opt for a stricter form of price regulation,
CPI-X price caps are preferred because they can offer incentives for efficient airport
operation.
– Unlike the existing price caps, however, any new price caps should be explicitly
based on a ‘dual till’ and factor in anticipated investment.
– Conventional price caps would be confined to Melbourne, Brisbane and Perth
airports. For a capacity-constrained Sydney Airport, arrangements should not be
such as to force prices down.
• Under both options, the general access and anti-competitive conduct provisions of
the Trade Practices Act would apply to all airports.
• Whatever the regulatory framework decided for Sydney Airport, that policy, in
particular the pricing and investment provisions, should be clearly and publicly
articulated to bidders so that the sale price can adequately reflect it.
Though the terms of reference encompass all Australian airports, the Commission
has mainly focused on the ‘core-regulated’ airports: that is, the eleven so-called
Phase 1 and Phase 2 privatised airports plus Sydney Airport (box 1). These
twelve airports account for 96 per cent of international, 93 per cent of domestic and
63 per cent of regional passenger movements.
OVERVIEW XVII
• promoting transparency and competition.
Thus the key tasks for the inquiry have been to:
• analyse the functions of airports and the markets in which they operate;
• identify the objectives of price regulation;
• identify which airports have significant market power and in which services;
• assess the potential for exploiting market power by those airports, including any
commercial constraints;
• identify and assess options for future price regulation, taking into consideration
the performance of existing price regulation; and, finally,
• determine the extent and type of future price regulation required, if any.
XVIII OVERVIEW
less profitable ones, and revenues from complementary (non-aeronautical)
activities, such as car parking and retailing, subsidised aeronautical services.
In 1997 and 1998, 50-year leases for 17 major Australian airports (excluding
Sydney) were sold to private operators. The stated rationale was to ‘improve the
efficiency of airport investment and operations in the interests of users and the
general community, and to facilitate innovative management’ (Harris 1997, p. 2).
Most leases were sold for individual airports.
At the same time, however, there was a concern that privatised airports might abuse
their market power with respect to aeronautical services. Thus, privatisation was
accompanied by what were described as transitional price-regulation measures,
designed to allow all parties to adjust to the new operating environment for airports.
Price regulation comprised a five-year, CPI-X annual cap on prices for aeronautical
services at 11 of the largest privatised airports — Melbourne, Brisbane, Perth,
Adelaide, Alice Springs, Canberra, Coolangatta, Darwin, Hobart, Launceston and
Townsville. Essentially, these arrangements extended, for the first five years of
privatisation, the FAC aeronautical prices that were in place prior to privatisation.
The cap was complemented by cost pass-through provisions for ‘necessary new
investment’ and government-mandated security services as well as by quality
monitoring and by special access arrangements designed to facilitate new airline
entrants.
Though Sydney Airport was not privatised, its lease was transferred to the
government-owned Sydney Airports Corporation Limited (SACL). It has been
subject to prices notification under the Prices Surveillance Act 1983 (where any
price increases have to be vetted by the ACCC) but not to a price cap or any
requirement to reduce aeronautical charges each year.
The Commission released its draft report on 24 August 2001. In the following
month, the Australian aviation market was rocked by two events: the terrorist
attacks in the United States and the cessation of services by Australia’s second-
largest carrier, Ansett. Immediately following these events, airports reported
OVERVIEW XIX
reductions in traffic of 30–40 per cent, though the level of services has recovered
somewhat since then. The effect of reduced domestic and international services on
several airports (especially the smaller Phase 2 airports) prompted the
Commonwealth Government on 5 October 2001 to announce major changes to
airport price regulation. It described these changes as ‘consistent with the findings
in the Productivity Commission’s draft report’.
• Price caps on aeronautical charges at the eight Phase 2 airports were removed.
They were replaced with price monitoring of aeronautical charges at Adelaide,
Darwin and Canberra airports while remaining Phase 2 airports were no longer
subject to any price regulation.
• Phase 1 airports (Melbourne, Brisbane and Perth) remained subject to price caps
but were allowed to implement one-off average price increases for price-capped
services of up to 6.2, 6.7 and 7.2 per cent, respectively.
When announcing the changes, the Minister for Financial Services and Regulation
said that ‘the Government will give further consideration to the prices oversight
arrangements at airports in the light of developments in airport prices and the
Productivity Commission’s final report’ (Hockey 2001).
Australian airports
Australian airports not only provide a range of services to airlines, they also provide
or facilitate ‘non-aeronautical’ services to passengers and others (box 3).
XX OVERVIEW
revenue of the 11 privatised core-regulated airports. Sydney Airport earned about
60 per cent of its revenue from non-aeronautical activities in 2000-01.
Aeronautical charges
There are three main types of aeronautical charge levied by Australian airports.
• A landing charge that covers use of runways, taxiways and aprons. Landing
charges at airports still subject to price caps averaged around $6.30 per aircraft
tonne (GST inclusive) in January 2002.
• A terminal charge at airport-operated terminals (averaging about $4 per
international passenger at the larger international privatised airports).
• Additional charges sometimes are levied for aircraft parking ($50 per day at
Melbourne Airport, but around $10 per day is more common).
Since the removal of price caps for Phase 2 airports on 5 October 2001, list prices
have risen at most of those airports (Adelaide, Alice Springs, Canberra,
Coolangatta, Darwin and Townsville). The airport operators claim that this has been
necessitated by significantly lower traffic volumes, and consequently higher unit
costs, and increased security costs. At Hobart and Launceston airports, charges have
remained at levels that applied under price caps.
Charges for regular public transport (RPT) flights at other Australian airports often
are not publicly available because rates are negotiated with airlines. For those that
are available, comparisons are very difficult because the airports concerned, which
are mostly owned by local municipalities, usually supply terminal and other
services not supplied by core-regulated airports, and their traffic volumes typically
are much lower.
OVERVIEW XXI
power — that is, an ability to raise prices above the efficient costs of supplying
aeronautical services — and their scope to use it.
Such pricing could increase airfares and reduce the consumption of air travel below
efficient levels. Airports that exercise market power could earn excessive profits or
operate inefficiently; they also could allow quality to deteriorate and not invest
appropriately. It is also possible that market power could be used selectively to deny
access to the airport, either by way of higher prices or by imposing other
unacceptable conditions of access.
Any abuse of market power would also have distributional effects, involving
transfers between airports, airlines and consumers. However, while such transfers
may be substantial in total, there do not appear to be major differences between
income profiles of the various groups. Moreover, attempting to use airport charges
to redistribute income would be a very blunt and inefficient approach. Hence, in
assessing the need for appropriate regulation, it has been the possible efficiency,
rather than distributional, outcomes that have guided the Commission’s assessment.
The existence of market power is not, of itself, sufficient justification for price
regulation of airports. Price regulation should promote more efficient outcomes than
those otherwise likely to be achieved by the market.
In most Australian cities (and cities of similar size elsewhere) there is only one
airport catering for RPT services. This is because:
• basic airport infrastructure, such as runways and taxiways, must be used as a
package and thus requires a single provider of a large, lumpy investment;
• there is some evidence of economies of scale, at least in relation to runways and
taxiways, though economies of scale for the airport as a whole may be exhausted
at quite low levels of output;
XXII OVERVIEW
• most major aeronautical assets, other than land, typically cannot be used for
other purposes and thus, once invested, are ‘sunk’. This may deter new entrants
by raising the cost of failure; and
• airports require very large land allocations and buffer zones for environmental
and safety reasons and this may make duplication prohibitively costly (or, for
planning and regulatory reasons, impossible) in convenient locations.
Network or coordination benefits also accrue to airlines and their passengers from
using one airport. Airlines can coordinate aircraft and passenger transfers at lower
cost and passengers do not have the inconvenience of transferring between airports.
Even given the choice of two similar (uncongested) airports serving the same
destination, airlines would be unlikely to spread similar services across both.
On average, charges for airport services account for a small share of airfares. In the
absence of any substitution possibilities, this suggests low price sensitivity and
strong market power. But, substitution possibilities for some airports may be quite
strong, so the sensitivity of some travellers to price changes at particular airports
may still be quite high.
For example, tourists are more likely to compare package prices for different
destinations and to substitute different travel modes to a destination (self-drive
versus flying, for example). International tourists may be flexible as to their
OVERVIEW XXIII
entry/exit point. On the other hand, destination-specific, time-sensitive business
travellers are likely to be less responsive to price changes than tourists. But even
business travellers are likely to have some scope to adjust their frequency of travel
or, increasingly, to use forms of electronic communication such as teleconferencing.
The Commission agrees with the ACCC that Alice Springs, Coolangatta, Hobart
and Launceston airports appear to have little market power because they rely
heavily on the tourism market and there is scope for competition from ‘nearby’
airports. The Commission also considers that Townsville Airport has limited market
power because it relies on the holiday market (and there is scope for competition
from other holiday destinations and other transport modes).
On the other hand, it appears that Brisbane, Melbourne, Perth and Sydney airports
possess significant market power in domestic markets due to high proportions of
business travellers and those ‘Visiting Friends and Relatives’, and their status as the
main international ports of arrival and departure in the country. Competition among
those airports for international traffic is likely to moderate, but not eliminate, this
latter effect.
XXIV OVERVIEW
The degree of market power held by Adelaide, Canberra and Darwin airports is less
clear. On balance, the Commission’s assessment is that these airports appear to have
at most a moderate degree of market power.
More than 200 non-core-regulated airports cater for some RPT services (rather than
just general aviation). No charges are imposed at some regional airports, while at
others charges can be very high. Of themselves, high charges do not necessarily
indicate an abuse of market power. While the Commission has not been able to
assess the likely market power of individual non-core-regulated airports, the small
traffic volumes of most regional airports suggest that unit costs would often be high.
High charges at many regional airports may also reflect revenue-raising objectives
of the local municipalities that own them. Privately-owned airports servicing resorts
generally operate in the highly competitive tourist market.
OVERVIEW XXV
Market power appears to be strongest for:
• facilities for aircraft movements, including access to runways, taxiways and
aprons; and
• vehicle access, including front-door access to the airport for passengers,
transport providers and off-airport car-parking providers.
A range of other airside services are necessary for passenger and cargo processing,
but there is some, albeit limited, discretion as to quality and quantity of service —
for example, aerobridges, check-in facilities and baggage handling. This suggests
that an airport’s market power in these services may be somewhat less than for
services provided by aircraft movement facilities but, in most cases, it would still be
significant.
The degree of airport market power in relation to aircraft refuelling has been a
particularly contentious issue. For some flights and some destinations, there is a
degree of choice as to where an aircraft refuels, but this discretion is limited and, at
more remote airports, probably non-existent.
Areas where market power is likely to be more limited include international airline
lounges, catering and freight storage facilities, and services that can easily be
located off-airport. Airports (and State Governments) also compete keenly for
aircraft heavy maintenance facilities.
While passengers value the convenience of shops and food outlets at airports, the
purchase of these services in most cases is likely to be highly price sensitive. The
services do not have to be consumed as part of the airport ‘bundle’ and there are
many alternatives to buying at the airport. Passengers also have choices in relation
to duty-free purchases — destination, transfer, or origin airports; on-board duty-free
and downtown outlets; and whether to buy duty free or not.
Passengers require transport to and from an airport but typically there is a choice of
several modes (taxi, self-drive, public transport) that are not provided by the airport.
For those who require parking, major airports (eg Sydney and Melbourne) have
substantial off-airport competition, at least for long-term (one day or more) parking.
Higher parking charges at airports relative to off-airport locations appear largely to
reflect greater convenience. Nevertheless, by controlling access to their ‘front door’,
airport operators could attempt to limit competition from off-airport providers of car
parking or other transport providers (eg taxis).
XXVI OVERVIEW
The potential for abuse of market power
Assessing the likely conduct of airports with market power is prerequisite to
assessing whether regulation is required and, if so, in what form. There are two
aspects that need to be considered: first, the existence of any constraints on the
abuse of market power; and second, the economic consequences of exercising
market power.
While some major Australian airports appear to have substantial market power in
the core aeronautical services they provide, they may not use this power to its full
extent, because of commercial incentives and constraints.
There is fairly strong evidence that the potential earnings from passenger spending
on non-aeronautical services (including retailing, car parking and restaurants)
provide airports with an incentive to encourage extra passengers to the airport.
• In 1999-00, for every dollar of operating profit earned from the provision of
aeronautical services at Australia’s major international airports, more than four
dollars of profit were earned from non-aeronautical activities. Though there are
some issues regarding the classification of earnings (eg lease payments which
for domestic terminals are classified as non-aeronautical), and the data do not
necessarily indicate the incremental earnings from an extra passenger, non-
aeronautical activities clearly are of great importance to airports.
• There are numerous examples of financial incentives being offered by airports to
encourage additional airline services, suggesting that most airports consider that
airlines are responsive to such incentives. Airports also regard service quality as
an important factor contributing to passenger spending (box 4).
OVERVIEW XXVII
Long-term growth strategies
To a considerable extent, airports’ market power relies on the relatively small effect
of an increase in airport charges on air travel costs. But this also provides airports
with some incentive to cooperate with other input providers (eg in the tourism and
aviation industries). In other words, airports, by themselves, will have little
influence over the attraction of their location, but they may be able to increase
demand and/or reduce demand uncertainty by working with other providers who are
in a better position to influence demand.
The reduction in demand for airport services since September 2001 is likely to have
enhanced airline countervailing power, at least in the short term. In the current
market environment, threats by international airlines to withdraw services, or threats
by domestic carriers not to increase services to an airport, would carry more weight
than previously.
XXVIII OVERVIEW
Likely effects of airport market power
Pricing efficiency
How far beyond their efficient levels or, indeed, whether aeronautical prices at
airports with market power would increase in the absence of any airport-specific
price regulation, no-one can say with certainty. However, for reasons outlined
above, the Commission considers that any price increases would be constrained by a
range of market forces, including commercial interests of the airports themselves.
Moreover, to the extent that airports can discriminate in pricing, such that charges
are allocated across airlines, aircraft and (through fare structures) across passengers
in a way that roughly reflects different passengers’ willingness to pay, the net effect
on consumption of air travel of a given increase in airport charges will be reduced.
Airports, like any business, have a strong incentive to discriminate among users in
their pricing to increase their profits. Though such price discrimination will not be
‘perfect’, there are numerous examples of airport price structures designed to
promote or retain marginal users of the airport, including direct incentives designed
to encourage additional flights and new entrant airlines.
Distributional effects
If airports increased their prices, then broadly speaking the losers would be
passengers (who may pay higher fares) and airline shareholders (who may have to
accept lower returns). While the Commission is not in a position to make a
judgement about preferred income distributions, it makes the following
observations:
• there does not appear to be any great difference between the income profiles of
passengers and airline shareholders on the one hand and the shareholders of
airports (including large Australian superannuation funds) on the other;
• owners of airports and airlines comprise both Australian residents and non-
residents (foreign interests can own up to 49 per cent of privatised airports); and
OVERVIEW XXIX
• many passengers are not Australian. In 1999, almost 60 per cent of passengers
on international flights were non-residents. This represents about 15 per cent of
all passenger movements at the major international airports. Non-residents also
fly domestic and regional routes but the data on the proportions are not available.
Several airline participants considered that airports with market power also would
allow their costs to rise to inefficient levels (at the expense of potentially higher
airport profits). The Commission has not been persuaded by this argument. The
ability of owners to monitor managers in this respect is unlikely to be significantly
less for privatised airports than for firms operating in other markets.
Airlines also have suggested that an airport with market power would allow quality
to deteriorate to increase profits. This is a possibility, particularly if prices are
constrained by regulation. However, an airport is unlikely to allow quality to
deteriorate if higher prices can be charged for higher quality and if passenger
spending on non-aeronautical services is sensitive to quality levels. Both of these
conditions seem to apply.
Airports with market power may also have an incentive to under-invest in order to
limit supply and maximise monopoly profits over time. New investment will occur
only when the expected additional profits from that investment exceed any profits
forgone from lower prices at the existing facility. But to the extent an airport can
discriminate in pricing, its incentives to under-invest would be reduced.
Market power could be used to deny access to the airport, either by way of higher
prices or by imposing unacceptable access conditions. An airport is unlikely to have
an incentive to deny access to its major customers, the airlines. (On the whole, the
response of airports to new airline entrants seems to confirm this point.) But, it may
have an incentive to deny or frustrate access to potential competitors, such as off-
airport car-parking operators or providers of other forms of transport to the airport.
XXX OVERVIEW
Box 6 Contrasting views on airport behaviour without price control
The airlines
‘In BARA’s view, failing to effectively regulate airport charges will weaken the incentives for
airport operators to provide airport services efficiently … In the absence of competition there
is scope for productive inefficiencies. Effective regulation, through acting as a surrogate for
some of the cost pressures on a firm facing effective competition, can reduce these costs.’
(Board of Airline Representatives of Australia, sub. 41, pp. 29–30)
‘Left unregulated, airport operators can be expected to use their market power through
monopoly pricing, diminishing service quality and the imposition of unreasonable terms and
conditions of access to the airport.’ (Qantas, sub. 48, p. 29)
The airports
‘Airports in an unregulated environment will have strong incentives to consult with their
customers on investments and quality outcomes to avoid wasteful investment … while
facilitating an optimal level of demand.’ (SACL, sub. 27, p. 34)
‘It is Melbourne Airport’s view that the commercial incentives for airports in Australia are
such that … they will pursue pricing and investment policies that are likely to maximise
economic welfare in the long run. In contrast, regulatory intervention through price controls is
likely to reduce welfare in the long run.’ (Melbourne Airport, sub. 7, p. i)
Cost-based regulation aims to ensure that a regulated firm earns no more than its
production costs, including a ‘normal’ rate of return on capital. It covers rate-of-
return regulation and cost-justified price increases (as currently apply under the
prices-notification regime for Sydney Airport). Regulated price increases based on
costs typically provide insufficient incentives for firms to operate efficiently — the
incentive to reduce costs is weakened because increased profits cannot be retained.
Cost-based regulation also requires detailed assessment by the regulator of the
firm’s capital and operating costs, asset base, and expected sales.
OVERVIEW XXXI
Incentive regulation is designed to reduce some of the problems of cost-based
regulation. It has usually taken the form of a CPI-X price cap. Over the period of
the price cap, regulated firms have an incentive to reduce costs (particularly beyond
the cost savings implied by the cap) to increase profits. But if prices are not to
persist at levels that deliver excessive profits or losses, eventually price caps must
be adjusted to allow prices to converge to levels that (just) cover costs. While the
use of benchmarks can reduce the need to consider costs incurred by the regulated
firm, it is unlikely that benchmarking can remove the need for cost assessment
altogether. In other words, the incentive advantages of the price caps tend to be
eroded over time, as the caps converge to cost-based regulation. For this reason,
price caps are regarded generally as providing a transitional form of price
regulation.
At best, a lack of clarity has promoted strategic behaviour by all parties, increased
compliance costs and discouraged commercial negotiation. At worst, the
arrangements, which combine elements of incentive and cost-based regulation, have
discouraged efficient investment by sending poor price signals both to airport
operators and users about the costs of providing aeronautical services and by
requiring very detailed regulatory assessment of every investment proposal.
Some of these problems could have been avoided by a more transparent process and
clearer guidelines from the outset; others reflect the design of the price caps.
Though price caps could be redesigned to incorporate planned investment, and
benchmarks could be used to provide independent estimates of achievable
productivity growth, inevitably there will have to be an eventual assessment by the
regulator of an airport’s operating and capital costs, land values, risk, and demand
growth. Given the substantial conceptual and information problems in asset
valuation and cost assessment (assessing the opportunity cost of airport land being
especially problematic), the risks of regulatory error and the potentially damaging
consequences of this for investment correspondingly increase.
Accordingly, the Commission considers that price caps, while preferable to explicit
rate-of-return regulation, should be reserved for situations where there is a strong
likelihood of excessive pricing and where such pricing is likely to impose major
costs on the community.
XXXII OVERVIEW
Single or dual till?
Leases for privatised core-regulated airports were sold with an explicit undertaking
that a single till would not be mandated. It appears that Sydney Airport will be sold
on the same basis. Nonetheless, various airline participants have argued that price
regulation should ensure that some or all non-aeronautical profits are applied to
reduce aeronautical charges.
Price monitoring
On the other hand, the potential to exercise market power may be greater under a
price-monitoring regime than under price caps or cost-based regulation. However,
such potential can be constrained by a credible threat that the Government would in
time re-introduce stronger regulation at airports where market power clearly was
being abused.
OVERVIEW XXXIII
Access provisions and general competition law
Airport operators currently are subject to s. 192 of the Airports Act 1996 and
Part IIIA (the National Access Regime) of the TP Act, while anti-competitive
practices are subject to Part IV of that Act. The five-year, automatic declarations of
privatised core-regulated airports cannot be renewed under s. 192 as it stands.
However, new airport-specific access arrangements or Part IIIA would continue to
complement any future price regulation of airport services or, indeed, could provide
an alternative to an industry-specific price-regulation regime. Prices of airport
services could be regulated indirectly through regulation of the terms and conditions
of access to a declared airport service.
As already noted, airports do not have strong incentives to deny access to their
major customers, the airlines. They may have some incentives to frustrate access to
those with whom they directly compete (eg car-parking operators) or where they
can control competition in a market through their control of access to the airport
facility in question (eg ground-handling operations). However, there is little
evidence that airports have sought to do this. The Commission has not been
persuaded that there is a case for the continuation of special access provisions that
impose more easily satisfied declaration criteria for airports than other industries.
Commercial agreements
That such guidance from government may be helpful for commercial entities in a
commercial environment may seem surprising. The reason for it is the historical
legacy of decades of government ownership of this industry and the pervasive
effects of regulation.
XXXIV OVERVIEW
The Commission’s assessment
Major Australian airports — Sydney, Melbourne, Brisbane and Perth — have been
assessed as having a high degree of market power in core aeronautical services.
This suggests that some form of airport-specific price regulation is required for
these airports, additional to general third-party access and competition regulation.
The Commission is not convinced that Adelaide, Canberra and Darwin airports
have substantial market power and they may be comparable in this respect to Cairns
Airport (the sixth-largest in Australia, albeit State owned), which is not subject to
any special price regulation. However, some form of monitoring may be appropriate
for these smaller airports at least as a transitional measure.
Remaining core-regulated airports, because they appear to have much less market
power, or because, given their size, the costs of regulation would far outweigh any
potential benefits, should not be subject to any airport-specific economic regulation,
including price or quality monitoring. (They would continue to be subject to the
TP Act and relevant provisions of the Airports Act.)
For those airports warranting continued regulation, the Commission considers that
the choice essentially comes down to forms of regulation that can provide
incentives for efficient outcomes. Of the stricter forms of price regulation, CPI-X
price caps provide the best incentives but they also bring inevitable risks of
regulatory error. Given that airports face significant commercial constraints and
incentives that will moderate abuse of any market power, the Commission sees
significant advantages in a more light-handed approach involving price monitoring.
Each of the options is outlined and their relative merits then assessed in more detail.
The stricter option essentially would continue the regulatory regime introduced on
5 October 2001, but with some refinements in the setting of price caps (designed to
promote efficient investment at airports and reduce regulatory intervention in
investment decisions) and also some changes to price-monitoring arrangements.
For Melbourne, Brisbane and Perth airports, there would be a CPI-X price cap for
five years, complemented by price and quality monitoring.
• The cap would apply only to the aeronautical services in which those three
airports have been assessed as having a high degree of market power: aircraft
movement facilities (including refuelling services), vehicle access facilities and
most passenger movement facilities. In broad terms, this coverage is very similar
to current price caps, except for refuelling services.
OVERVIEW XXXV
• Average prices allowed under the cap should broadly reflect the anticipated cost
of efficiently providing regulated aeronautical services on a dual-till basis
(box 7). In other words, unlike current price caps where inherited single-till
prices are adjusted incrementally as new investment is put in place, the cap
should correspond to anticipated efficient dual-till prices.
XXXVI OVERVIEW
deteriorate), with most investment incorporated in allowable prices, there may
also need to be monitoring to ensure that investments are not being delayed
intentionally by the airport to increase profits. Airlines would be expected to
play a role in developing the forward investment program and their input should
be sought in monitoring its implementation.
• Price monitoring would continue for some services currently designated as
‘aeronautical-related’ in which market power has been assessed as moderate (eg
check-in counters, staff car parking). Some other services currently designated
aeronautical related (eg public car parks), would not be subject to monitoring.
Reporting of aggregate financial data for both aeronautical and non-aeronautical
services would continue.
For Sydney Airport, for reasons discussed in box 8, in the absence of slot sale or
trading mechanisms, regulation preferably should allow aeronautical prices to
reflect more closely the opportunity costs incurred by airlines and their passengers
in using the facility (that is, the value of slots to those who miss out at peak times),
rather than simply reflecting the calculated costs of production. At the very least,
provided capacity remains constrained, aeronautical prices should not be required to
decline in real terms and should be adequate to encourage efficient, feasible
expansion of aeronautical capacity at that facility.
• This could be implemented either by requiring notification of aeronautical price
increases above the CPI, or by imposing a CPI-X cap with the X set at zero.
• In either case, price increases should be allowed to reflect peak-period demand
(as provided for in the current regulatory framework for Phase 1 airports), and to
accommodate necessary investment.
For all other airports, there would be no airport-specific price regulation or quality
monitoring. This would require amendment of the Airports Act so that Alice
Springs, Coolangatta, Hobart, Launceston and Townsville airports no longer were
designated as ‘core-regulated’ airports.
All airports should be subject to the generic provisions of the Part IIIA National
Access Regime. An airport-specific access regime should be considered only if
procedural improvements already identified by the Commission, such as scope
for multilateral arbitrations, are not made to the National Access Regime.
OVERVIEW XXXVII
Box 8 The benefits of price rationing at Sydney Airport
Prior to September 2001, Sydney Airport experienced excess demand for aircraft
movement slots for several hours a day. This situation is likely to resume in the not-too-
distant future. The limited supply of slots is currently due to a movement cap and
curfew, and the regional ‘ring fence’. It is likely that the market-clearing price at peak
times exceeds airport production costs.
Appropriate peak/off-peak charges at Sydney Airport would promote more efficient use
of the airport and, given the massive investment required to establish a second airport,
also would provide important signals to the Government about the need for a new
facility and the costs of the various constraints imposed on the use of Sydney Airport.
Though prices approaching market-clearing levels at peak times would be likely to
promote use of the airport by those who value it most — even if ring-fenced regional
flights were quarantined from such price increases, in line with announced Government
policy — the airport could earn large profits, reflecting the scarcity value of slots.
(Efficient peak/off-peak charging would balance lower off-peak charges against higher
peak charges — this would tend to moderate the extent of profit increases.)
It is important to note that any rise in peak prices is unlikely to lead to higher passenger
fares. There is strong evidence that the scarcity value of the slots is factored into fares
already; it is very difficult to obtain discounted fares to Sydney at peak times. In other
words, it is the airlines that are currently benefiting from the excess demand for landing
slots at peak times.
If bidders were informed prior to the sale of Sydney Airport that efficient peak/off-peak
charges would be permitted, then any anticipated scarcity rents would accrue to the
Commonwealth Government (and taxpayers generally) in the bid price, rather than to
the new airport operator.
Source: appendix H.
This option would extend price monitoring to Phase 1 airports and Sydney Airport
for a probationary period, and maintain (modified) price monitoring of Adelaide,
Canberra and Darwin airports. As in Option A, there would be no airport-specific
price regulation of any other airports.
For Sydney, Melbourne, Brisbane, Perth, Adelaide, Canberra and Darwin airports,
there would be mandatory price monitoring by the ACCC. The monitoring regime
would continue for five years.
• During this probationary period, the regulator would not have the power to alter
unilaterally the monitoring regime or impose stricter price regulation.
XXXVIII OVERVIEW
• Information requirements would be specified at the commencement of the period
and could not be amended without agreement of the parties. The Commission
envisages somewhat more detailed monitoring of Sydney, Melbourne, Brisbane
and Perth airports, including the weighted average cost of capital (WACC) for
aeronautical assets. Otherwise, proposed information requirements for the seven
airports broadly would be consistent with existing disclosure and reporting
requirements.
• As under current monitoring and reporting arrangements, information would be
formally audited. There also should be provision to treat some data as
commercial-in-confidence where disclosure could undermine commercially-
negotiated agreements. An annual report presenting monitored information
would be made publicly available, with commentary (but not a pre-emptive
assessment of the monitoring regime) by the ACCC (and auditors) where
considered warranted.
• Quality-of-service monitoring would continue at all price-regulated airports.
• Voluntary commercial agreements between airports and users (including non-
airline users) would be encouraged by providing guidelines regarding coverage,
consultation and dispute-settlement mechanisms. (The Commission sees no need
to exempt from access regulation airports that enter into such agreements.)
• An independent public review would be conducted towards the end of the five-
year monitoring period to ascertain whether there should be any future price
regulation of those airports. Other airports could be included in the review only
where there is prima facie evidence of persistent misuse of market power.
• Factors to be taken into account by the review in assessing whether airports had
abused market power should be specified at the start of the regulatory period
(box 9). Efficient pricing principles for airports are discussed in this report and
also have been developed more generally by the Commission in its reviews of
the National Access Regime and Telecommunications Competition Regulation.
They are predicated on the need to avoid excessive prices, without the regulator
attempting to set prices too precisely, with the resultant risk that prices may be
pushed too low and efficient investment discouraged.
For all other airports, there would be no airport-specific price regulation or quality-
of-service monitoring. This would require amendment of the Airports Act so that
Hobart, Launceston, Alice Springs, Coolangatta and Townsville Airports no longer
were designated as ‘core-regulated’ airports.
All airports should be subject to the generic provisions of the Part IIIA National
Access Regime. An airport-specific access regime should be considered only if
OVERVIEW XXXIX
procedural improvements already identified by the Commission, such as scope for
multilateral arbitrations, were not made to the National Access Regime.
Pricing principles
• At airports without significant capacity constraints, efficient prices broadly should
generate expected revenue that is not significantly above the long-run costs of
efficiently providing aeronautical services (on a dual-till basis). Prices should allow a
return on (appropriately defined and valued) assets (including land) commensurate
with the regulatory and commercial risks involved.
• At airports with significant capacity constraints, efficient peak/off-peak prices may
generate revenues that exceed the average production costs incurred by the airport.
• Price discrimination and multi-part pricing that promote efficient use of the airport
should be encouraged. This may mean that some users pay a price above the long-
run average costs of providing aeronautical services, whereas more price-sensitive
users pay a price close to marginal cost.
Other criteria
• Whether quality-of-service outcomes have deteriorated and/or failed to meet the
requirements of users.
• The extent to which commercial agreements on prices and quality of service have
been negotiated.
• The degree of consultation with airport users and the extent of the exchange of
information.
• The number and outcome of applications for third-party access and the extent and
validity of user complaints.
XL OVERVIEW
view, perform better than the regulatory arrangements in place before 5 October
2001 and those that have applied since then. In particular:
• by making allowance for anticipated investment in the price-cap parameters, it is
likely that regulatory involvement in and, therefore, scope for distortion of,
investment decisions will be reduced. In addition, airports and their users would
receive much better signals from efficient dual-till prices regarding the real costs
and benefits of supplying aeronautical services;
• airports and their customers would have greater incentives to negotiate price and
quality agreements within the overall limits of the designated caps (at least
where there is unused airport capacity), reflecting incentives to increase
aeronautical and non-aeronautical profits by expanding use of the airport at the
margin;
• use of benchmarking, where feasible, could help to sustain the positive incentive
effects of price caps and avoid them converging to rate-of-return regulation; and
• maximum average aeronautical prices at Melbourne, Brisbane and Perth airports
would be set on a dual-till basis, consistent with prices approved by the ACCC
for Sydney Airport.
The Commission has not been persuaded, however, that there is a strong case for
the continuation of price caps at any privatised core-regulated airports. This is for
two principal reasons.
The first is the ever-present risk of regulatory failure, given the severe information
problems confronting any regulator. Setting price caps inevitably entails detailed
regulatory assessment of, and involvement in, airport operations and investment
decisions. It should therefore be used only where the potential efficiency costs of
abuse of market power are significant. Even then there is a risk that regulation will
cause its own distortions to production and investment decisions. While the
Commission agrees that some transitional problems with current price-cap
arrangements may have been settled, and that the price caps proposed under
Option A should reduce regulatory involvement in investment decisions, the risk of
regulatory failure remains high. This risk has been amplified by the uncertainty that
currently pervades global aviation markets.
The second and related reason is that the ‘problem’ to be addressed does not
warrant such a heavy-handed regulatory regime. Though the four largest airports
have considerable market power, the prospect of them using that power in a way
that would generate significant costs to the economy or community is supported
OVERVIEW XLI
neither by the evidence nor the analysis. There are strong commercial incentives
pulling in the other direction, including scope for increased profits in non-
aeronautical activities from increasing passenger volumes and incentives to
discriminate and differentiate in pricing.
On balance, therefore, the Commission considers that while the market power of the
four major airports warrants some form of regulatory oversight, the continuation of
price caps is not the best approach. Option B offers a much better regulatory
mechanism for promoting the principles for regulation identified in the terms of
reference.
In this regard, the proposed length of the monitoring period is crucial. If it were too
short, some parties might be encouraged not to deal in good faith, in order to
increase the likelihood of re-regulation. If the period were too long, airports with
market power might have an incentive to make use of that power. The
Commission’s view is that five years would achieve the right balance.
To give airports guidance as to what behaviour could provide grounds for re-
introduction of stricter price controls (or removal of airport-specific prices
oversight), the Commission has elaborated some broad principles for a review body
to apply in five years’ time in assessing how the industry and regulatory framework
XLII OVERVIEW
were performing (box 9). Some participants expressed concern about the need for
additional public scrutiny of any such principles. However, the broad pricing
principles proposed have already been discussed extensively during this inquiry and
parallel inquiries into infrastructure regulation (the National Access Regime, the
Prices Surveillance Act 1983 and Telecommunications Competition Regulation).
Concluding remarks
In the Commission’s view, the regulatory approach of Option B provides the best
balance of incentives and disciplines for major airports.
Some participants also have argued against discontinuation of price caps at a time of
upheaval and uncertainty in the aviation industry. The Commission is firmly of the
view that the uncertain outlook calls for more, not less, flexibility. Indeed, this has
been recognised by the Government in discontinuing price caps for Phase 2 airports.
If airport operators themselves cannot predict what will happen over the next few
months or years, regulators are unlikely to be able to fix price caps that can deal
efficiently with future market conditions.
Some have cited their interpretation of the recent New Zealand experience with
light-handed regulation in an attempt to rebut the Commission’s price-monitoring
option. But closer examination suggests that the New Zealand system,
notwithstanding some deficiencies, has not been a failure (box 10). For example,
OVERVIEW XLIII
Auckland and Christchurch airports have agreed on new aeronautical prices with
their major airline customers and those price outcomes do not appear excessive.
While light-handed regulation currently is not the dominant model worldwide, there
are signs that the direction is changing. For example, in the United Kingdom, the
Civil Aviation Authority recently has proposed modifications to regulatory
arrangements that are in part designed to foster commercial negotiation between
airports and airlines at major airports.
XLIV OVERVIEW
The Commission recognises that its preferred option would involve a considerable
shift from current arrangements at the four major airports — though one largely
envisaged by the architects of the regulatory arrangements put in place at the time
of airport privatisations. The Commission also recognises that some parties may
find such a transition difficult, particularly given the long history of government
provision of airport services at those airports, and pricing structures that have
effectively subsidised aeronautical charges. Nonetheless, even if price caps were to
be maintained (in any form), aeronautical charges would still need to rise to
encourage efficient long-run service provision.
The Commission considers that the full benefits of privatisation of airports are
unlikely to be realised if commercial relationships between airports and airlines
continue to be heavily conditioned by intrusive price regulation. The ongoing need
for substantial investments at major airports requires a more commercial and
cooperative approach. The potential for heavy-handed regulation unduly to
constrain prices and commercial relationships poses a real risk and one that could
impose large costs on consumers in the future.
OVERVIEW XLV
Recommendations and findings
Recommendations
Recommendations 1–8 should be read in conjunction with chapter 12, which sets
out the details of Options A and B.
RECOMMENDATION 1
For Sydney, Melbourne, Brisbane and Perth airports, price caps and prices notification
arrangements should be replaced by mandatory price monitoring arrangements for a
probationary five-year period, as outlined in Option B.
• Airport-specific price-monitoring arrangements could be incorporated either in the
Airports Act 1996 (Airports Act) or the Trade Practices Act 1974 (TP Act), but
should be consistent with any generic price-monitoring provisions that may be
introduced into the TP Act following the Commission’s separate review of the Prices
Surveillance Act 1983 (PS Act).
In the event that the Government opted for a stricter form of price regulation at these
four airports, Option A should apply such that:
• annual price caps of the form CPI-X continue for five years at Melbourne, Brisbane
and Perth airports. Price caps should be set to reflect the efficient costs of providing
aeronautical services in the long run, on a dual-till basis. Price caps should be
complemented by price monitoring of some ‘aeronautical-related’ services; and
• for a capacity-constrained Sydney Airport, prices should not be required to fall in
real terms. Regulation should comprise either prices notification or a price cap of the
form CPI-X, with X set at zero. Price increases should be allowed to reflect peak-
period demand and to accommodate necessary investment.
RECOMMENDATION 2
Quality monitoring of regulated services (as outlined under Option B) should continue
at all airports subject to price regulation; that is, at Sydney, Melbourne, Brisbane, Perth,
Adelaide, Canberra and Darwin airports.
RECOMMENDATION 4
Neither price monitoring nor price caps should be reintroduced for Alice Springs,
Coolangatta, Hobart, Launceston and Townsville airports. The Airports Act should be
amended so that these airports are no longer designated as ‘core-regulated’ airports.
RECOMMENDATION 5
RECOMMENDATION 6
Price regulation of airports should be reviewed towards the end of the five-year
regulatory period. The review should be independent and public. Its objective should be
to ascertain the need for any future price regulation of airports (including price
monitoring or more stringent price regulation). In making its assessment, the review
should be guided by principles of efficient pricing plus several other criteria set out
under Option B. Agreed review criteria should be spelt out at the beginning of the
regulatory period.
Other airports should be included in the review only where there was prima facie
evidence of persistent misuse of market power (namely, evidence of inefficient prices,
poor quality etc).
RECOMMENDATION 7
All airports should be subject to the generic provisions of the National Access Regime in
Part IIIA of the TP Act. An airport-specific access regime should be considered only if
procedural improvements, such as scope for multilateral arbitrations, are not made to
the National Access Regime.
RECOMMENDATION 8
Prior to implementation of the chosen regulatory approach, airports and airlines should
be consulted on the practicalities of the proposed regulation and made aware of its
various requirements, in order to reduce uncertainty and the potential for disputation. In
particular, bidders for Sydney Airport should have a clear picture of the regulatory
framework for that facility so that expected future airport charges can be factored
adequately into the sale price.
RECOMMENDATIONS XLVII
AND FINDINGS
Findings
This section draws together all findings contained in this report. Findings are listed
under the relevant chapter.
FINDING 5.1
There are significant barriers to entry in the provision of airports. These arise from
natural monopoly characteristics that are reinforced by regulatory constraints.
FINDING 5.2
The price elasticity of demand for the services of a particular airport is influenced
by a number of factors. Although the typically low proportion of airport charges in
airfares and airline costs suggests low price sensitivity, this will be mitigated by any
potential for destination, modal and airport substitution, and the supply responses
of other input providers to changes in airport charges.
Airports that face more significant substitution possibilities will face more
price-sensitive demand (and hence have lower market power).
FINDING 5.3
Of the core-regulated airports, Sydney, Melbourne, Brisbane and Perth have most
market power. Adelaide Airport is likely to have a moderate degree of market
power. Canberra and Darwin airports also are likely to have a moderate degree of
market power, though they appear to face stronger substitution possibilities than
Adelaide Airport.
Core-regulated airports that do not appear to have significant market power (due
mainly — except for Townsville — to the scope for effective inter-airport
competition) are Alice Springs, Coolangatta, Hobart, Launceston and Townsville.
FINDING 6.1
For those airports with a moderate to high degree of market power, the extent of
market power varies across the services provided. It appears to be most significant
in aircraft movement facilities, vehicle access, some forms of passenger processing
facility and aircraft refuelling. With respect to aircraft refuelling, market power
appears to be most significant at Brisbane, Perth and Sydney airports.
XLVIII PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
Where other providers potentially compete with the airport in the provision of
services, access may be an issue if these providers require access to the airport site.
FINDING 7.1
FINDING 7.2
The countervailing power of airlines in their dealings with major capital city
airports appears limited. However, airlines may have a degree of countervailing
power even at those airports where there is scope for airport substitution (for
example, entry ports for international flights), where airlines form alliances and
bargain as a group, or where selective threats can be made to reduce services that
are highly profitable to airports.
For smaller core-regulated airports, airline countervailing power is likely to be
stronger, due to the commercial strength of major airlines relative to smaller
airports, the market segments served by those airports and greater scope for airport
competition.
FINDING 7.3
FINDING 7.4
RECOMMENDATIONS XLIX
AND FINDINGS
efficiency losses arising either from the need to cover the fixed costs of providing
aeronautical services or from the exercise of airport market power.
FINDING 7.5
FINDING 7.6
FINDING 7.7
Managers of privatised airports with market power are unlikely to have much scope
to allow inefficiencies in production.
FINDING 7.8
In principle, airports with market power may have some incentive to delay
investment or to allow quality to deteriorate, in order to maximise their profits.
However, in practice, to the extent that airports with market power can discriminate
in pricing or differentiate products for different users, those incentives will be
weakened. The scope to earn additional non-aeronautical profits from higher
quality or expanded aeronautical capacity and passenger throughput, will also
encourage the provision of appropriate quality and investment levels.
L PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
FINDING 7.9
An airport with market power has little incentive to deny or frustrate access to its
major customers, the airlines.
An airport with market power may have an incentive to restrict ‘front-door’ access
to off-airport providers of competing services such as car parking, or providers of
competing transport modes, though there is little evidence of this occurring.
FINDING 8.1
The single-till basis of the starting prices (also incorporating some cross subsidies
between airports), and the real declines in aeronautical prices at most airports
under the price cap suggest that, for many airports, aeronautical prices by the end
of 2000-01 may have been below the level necessary to justify future aeronautical
investment.
FINDING 8.2
The necessary new investment provisions have not promoted the commercially-
negotiated outcomes that were envisaged by the architects of the regime. This has
been partly due to the need to develop criteria and procedures for necessary new
investment after purchase and for participants to adapt to the very different
business environment following airport privatisation.
However, the observed difficulties also point to some fundamental problems. In
particular:
• the lack of transparency regarding what investment was considered to be
included in the base aeronautical prices and what was to be covered by
necessary new investment, with resultant effects on incentives to invest;
• the incentives for some participants to approach the regulator rather than
achieve commercially-negotiated solutions;
• the high costs of complying with the regime; and
• the regulatory risk due to the uncertainty and delays introduced by the need to
have every investment-related price increase vetted by the regulator.
FINDING 8.3
The aeronautical price increases implemented at Sydney Airport place its pricing
on a fundamentally different and more appropriate (dual-till) basis than that at
other core-regulated airports. The significant range of possible outcomes for a
number of cost parameters (for example, land values, cost of capital etc) indicates
the imprecision of regulatory price setting and the potential for inefficient prices
being established by regulation.
If significant excess demand returns at Sydney Airport at peak times,
production cost-related or rate-of-return based regulation would be likely to
constrain the setting of efficient aeronautical charges for those times.
FINDING 9.1
FINDING 9.2
Though privatised core-regulated airports have facilitated access for new entrant
airlines, airport-specific access provisions (s. 192 of the Airports Act) do not
appear to have been instrumental in achieving this outcome.
FINDING 10.1
FINDING 10.2
The Commission considers that if price-cap regulation were to be continued for any
airports, then the cap should apply only to those aeronautical services in which the
airport has substantial market power. Profits earned in non-aeronautical activities
should not be taken into account in setting the cap.
If an airport exercises significant market power (as opposed to earning locational
rent) in any non-aeronautical activity, separate price monitoring or other
regulation may be appropriate.
FINDING 11.1
Where airport market power is not substantial, or where there are commercial
constraints on the misuse of market power, price monitoring has significant
advantages over stricter forms of price regulation. Provided there is no easy
recourse to regulatory intervention, a price-monitoring regime can promote
efficient outcomes while reducing the risk of regulatory failure. Price monitoring
also has the potential to reduce compliance costs and promote commercial
negotiations.
FINDING 11.2
FINDING 11.3
FINDING 11.4
RECOMMENDATIONS LIII
AND FINDINGS
1 Introduction
This chapter sets out and clarifies the terms of reference, provides background to
this inquiry, and outlines the Productivity Commission’s approach to the inquiry.
The terms of reference state that the purpose of the inquiry is to:
… examine whether new regulatory arrangements, targeted at those charges for airport
services or products where the airport operator has been identified as having most
potential to abuse market power, are needed to ensure that the exercise of any such
power may be appropriately counteracted. (terms of reference, para. 6)
In so doing, the Commission is to take into account several principles, the first of
which states:
The CPI-X price cap applied to aeronautical charges during the first five year period of
private ownership will no longer operate. (terms of reference, para. 7(a))
Shortly after commencement of the inquiry, the Commission wrote to the Assistant
Treasurer, seeking clarification of paragraph 7(a) of the terms of reference. In its
letter, the Commission stated:
The Commission understands that Paragraph 7(a) essentially conveys the
Government’s intention that the current price cap arrangements for Phase I and II
airports will cease after five years of operation. It is also our view that paragraph 7(a) is
not intended to preclude from consideration price cap arrangements of the general form
of CPI-X as an option for future prices regulation of airport services, should some form
of prices regulation be regarded as appropriate.
The Commission sought confirmation from the Assistant Treasurer that this general
approach to price regulation could be considered as one of the range of options
where there is most potential for abuse of market power. The Commission’s
INTRODUCTION 1
understanding of paragraph 7(a) was confirmed by the Assistant Treasurer in
correspondence with the Commission (appendix A).
Other principles that the Commission is to take into account include that price
regulation:
• be applied to those aeronautical services and to those airports where airport
operators have most potential to abuse market power;
• minimise compliance costs on airport operators and the Government;
• promote the efficient operation of airports; and
• facilitate benchmarking comparisons between airports, competition in the
provision of services within airports, and commercially negotiated outcomes in
airport operations.
Leases were granted to private sector operators at Brisbane, Melbourne and Perth
airports in 1997 (Phase 1), and for a further 14 airports (Adelaide, Alice Springs,
Canberra, Coolangatta, Darwin, Hobart, Launceston, Townsville, Mount Isa,
Tennant Creek, Archerfield, Jandakot, Moorabbin and Parafield airports) in 1998
(Phase 2). The remaining five federal airports — the four Sydney basin airports
(Sydney (Kingsford Smith), Bankstown, Camden and Hoxton Park) and Essendon
Airport — were leased but not privatised, with their ownership transferred to two
wholly Government-owned companies in 1998. The FAC subsequently ceased
operation.
The sale of Essendon Airport was completed in September 2001. The sale of
Sydney Airport has been deferred from late 2001 to early 2002. The three other
Sydney basin airports are to be sold in the second half of 2002.
At the time of the sale of leases, 12 of the 22 leased airports were designated as
‘core-regulated’ airports under the Airports Act 1996 and were subject to price
regulation under the Prices Surveillance Act 1983 (PS Act). They comprised
Sydney Airport and 11 privatised airports (all Phase 1 airports, and eight of the
Phase 2 airports — Adelaide, Alice Springs, Canberra, Coolangatta, Darwin,
2 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
Hobart, Launceston and Townsville). These airports are characterised by significant
interstate and, in some cases, international regular public transport services.
The review was to be completed before the end of the first five-year period of the
leases.
1 In 1995, the CPA was signed by the Commonwealth, States and Territories as part of the
National Competition Policy reform package. The CPA, in essence, sets out the principles to be
followed by governments in relation to the agreed competition policy reforms.
4 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
and current inquiries, particularly those noted above by the then Assistant Treasurer,
Senator Kemp.
As noted above, the terms of reference ask the Commission to report on whether
‘there is a need for price regulation of airports, and the appropriate form of any
price regulation’. In other words, the terms of reference do not constrain the
Commission to considering only those airports subject to price regulation following
the granting of leases, that is, core-regulated airports. Other airports include those
leased in Phase 2 but not subject to price regulation, regional airports with regular
public transport services, and smaller general aviation airports. Nonetheless, the
inquiry has focused on whether there is a need for continued price regulation at
core-regulated airports and, if so, the appropriate form of such regulation.
Sydney Airport, which is leased but not yet privatised, has not been subject to the
price-cap arrangements of other core-regulated airports. As a core-regulated airport,
it is, however, subject to other forms of price regulation and therefore included in
this inquiry.
This report assesses price regulation as it applied to all core-regulated airports for
the period following the granting of leases until October 2001, when regulation
changed. It also examines price regulation since October insofar as the effects of the
regulatory change are evident between October and the finalisation of this inquiry.
INTRODUCTION 5
Although the regulatory focus is on price regulation under the PS Act, other
regulations are considered insofar as they affect, directly or indirectly, the prices of
services provided by airports. Examples of such regulation are the Airports Act, the
TP Act, environmental regulations, and international aviation agreements.
Since the release of the Commission’s draft report domestic and international events
have, at least in the short term, altered the environment in which airports operate.
The Commission has endeavoured to address the impact of these events in this
report.
Report structure
6 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
The Commission held informal discussions with organisations, companies, and
individuals to seek information and canvass a wide range of views. A list of those
with whom discussions were held is set out in appendix B. Fifty submissions were
received in response to the issues paper (appendix B). Interested parties were given
the opportunity to respond to matters raised in the draft report by way of written
submissions and at public hearings held in October 2001. Twenty-nine
supplementary submissions were received in response to the draft report
(appendix B). Transcripts of hearings and all non-confidential submissions (or
non-confidential parts of submissions) are available on the Internet, at Commission
and State libraries, and from Photobition Digital Imaging Centre.
Professor Richard Snape (Presiding) and Dr Neil Byron were the Commissioners
for the majority of this inquiry. Due to the illness of Professor Snape after the
hearings on the draft report, the Productivity Commission’s Chairman, Gary Banks,
formally joined this Division of the Commission in order to provide additional
assistance to the inquiry. Due to these events, the final report was signed on
23 January 2002, somewhat later than the original reporting date.
INTRODUCTION 7
2 Australian airports and their markets
Airport facilities
AUSTRALIAN 9
AIRPORTS AND THEIR
MARKETS
In addition, landside facilities encompass facilities outside the terminals, such as
perimeter roads, car parks, and taxi, bus and rail points linked to terminals by
walkways.
Airside facilities include runways, taxiways and aprons, as well as airfield lighting,
aircraft parking bays, visual navigation aids, hangars, freight terminals and facilities
for aircraft maintenance and refuelling, and in-flight catering.
Airport services
Of the range of services provided at airports in most OECD countries, only a small
number is directly supplied by the airport operator (section 2.3). The services and
activities provided at airports can be divided into three groups: essential operational
services, handling services and commercial activities (Doganis 1992).
Essential operational services are concerned primarily with ensuring the safety of
aircraft and airport users. These include:
• air traffic control and meteorological services;
• runway, building and aircraft maintenance services;
• communications, security, and fire and medical services; and
• aircraft movement services for the runways, taxiways and aprons, such as nose-
in guidance and marshalling.
Handling services
Handling activities cover services directly associated with the aircraft itself
(sometimes referred to as ground handling) and include:
• cleaning and catering;
• the provision of power and fuel; and
• loading/unloading of baggage and freight.
Also commonly classified as handling activities are services associated with the
various stages of processing passengers, baggage and freight through the respective
terminals and onto the aircraft. These services include:
• baggage make-up, handling and reclaim, ticketing and check-in; and
• immigration, customs and quarantine services (for international flights).
10 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
Commercial activities
Commercial activities cover a range of services and activities not directly related to
the interchange of passengers and freight between surface and air transport. They
include retail outlets, banks, restaurants and bars, car-hire desks, car parking, and at
some large airports, such as Frankfurt, can extend to activities such as conference
centres and hotels, cinemas, night clubs and supermarkets.
Airport capacity
AUSTRALIAN 11
AIRPORTS AND THEIR
MARKETS
movements.1 RPT services in Australia are divided into three categories:
international, domestic and regional.2 In 2000-01, domestic travel accounted for
68 per cent of approximately 76 million passenger movements, followed by
international passengers with 22 per cent and regional passengers with 10 per cent.
Core-regulated airports
Except for Cairns Airport, the largest airports in Australia are all core-regulated
(chapter 1). In 2000-01, core-regulated airports accounted for 89 per cent of
scheduled passenger movements. Sydney, Melbourne and Brisbane airports are by
far the largest airports (figure 2.1), together accounting for 67 per cent of total
passenger movements at Australian airports in 2000-01.
Domestic International
30000
25000
Passenger movements (’000s)
20000
15000
10000
5000
0
in
lle
ey
gs
t
ne
ne
rth
de
rra
ta
on
ar
rn
w
at
vi
dn
rin
ba
ai
ur
st
Pe
ob
be
ai
ar
ng
ns
el
ce
bo
Sy
Sp
is
H
an
D
Ad
w
la
Br
un
el
To
oo
e
M
La
ic
C
Al
a Revenue passengers on RPT services. Domestic totals include (provisional) regional data.
Data source: DoTRS (unpublished).
1 Includes revenue passengers arriving at, and departing from, Australian airports on scheduled
international, domestic and regional RPT services. Revenue passengers are passengers paying
any fare and include passengers travelling on tickets acquired through frequent flyer schemes.
2 ‘Domestic’ and ‘regional’ are data classifications of revenue traffic carried on scheduled RPT
services performed within Australia and its territories. Domestic airline data refer to revenue
traffic carried by high-capacity aircraft (aircraft with more than 38 seats or a payload greater
than 4200 kg). Regional airline data refer to revenue traffic carried by low-capacity aircraft
(aircraft with 38 seats or less, or with a payload of up to 4200 kg) (DoTRS 2000b).
12 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
In 2000-01, there were approximately 17 million passenger movements on
international RPT services at Australian airports and nearly 96 per cent of these
movements were at core-regulated airports, with Sydney accounting for around half.
300
250
Aircraft movements (’000s)
200
150
100
50
0
in
lle
ey
s
ne
ne
de
rth
rra
ta
rn
at
vi
dn
ba
ai
ur
Pe
be
ai
ar
ng
ns
el
bo
Sy
C
is
an
D
Ad
w
la
Br
el
To
oo
M
AUSTRALIAN 13
AIRPORTS AND THEIR
MARKETS
Figure 2.3 Passenger shares at core-regulated airports, 2000-01a
100
90
80
70
60
Per cent
50
40
30
20
10
0
rth
ne
in
lle
ey
gs
t
ne
de
ta
rra
on
ar
w
at
vi
dn
rin
ba
st
ai
ur
Pe
ob
be
ar
ng
ns
ce
el
bo
Sy
Sp
is
H
an
D
Ad
w
la
Br
un
el
To
oo
e
M
La
ic
C
Al
a Based on revenue passengers carried on scheduled international, domestic and regional RPT services.
Includes (provisional) regional data.
Data source: DoTRS (unpublished).
Other airports
In addition, a number of capital cities have large airports (in terms of aircraft
movements) that primarily serve the general aviation sector. These include
privatised ex-FAC airports such as Archerfield (Brisbane), Jandakot (Perth),
Moorabbin (Melbourne) and Parafield (Adelaide).
3 Australian Airports Limited owns and operates both Mount Isa and Townsville airports.
14 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
Figure 2.4 Passenger movements at Australia’s 20 largest non-core-
regulated airports, 2000-01a
Domestic Regional
500
450
400
Passenger movements (’000s)
350
300
250
200
150
100
50
rt
Br e
lie
ga ove
a
ry
k)
am y
nd
on
Ka me
bo
ie
ne
Ka ur
ch n
ou a
ka
or
ur
th
llin
Is
w
po
g
rn
bu
oc
bo
or
oc sla
ub
to
pt
ag
to
oo
rra
yd
ild
ac
nt
Bu
on
Ba
R
go
Al
am
ds
ar
D
W
I
M
M
ev
rs
H
on
la
kh
illi
oo
M
ye
G
D
fs
ilt
ag
ar
of
(A
am
C
M
W
ra
H
la
Yu
a Excludes Cairns Airport. Revenue passengers carried on scheduled international, domestic and regional
RPT services. Included with the domestic passenger movements at Broome Airport are approximately
4200 international passenger movements. Includes (provisional) regional data.
Data source: DoTRS (unpublished).
4 Ownership can take the form of a central government having control of all, or the majority, of a
country’s airports (such as Greece, Sweden and Norway); alternatively, ownership of airports
can reside with regional or local governments. Another variation on the public ownership
model is for the government to establish an authority to manage one or more airports on its
behalf. In the late 1970s and 1980s, several national airport authorities came into being,
modelled on the British Airports Authority, as it was prior to privatisation. Examples include
the Airports Authority of Thailand, the Israeli Airports Authority, the Mexican Airports
Authority and Aer Rianta (the Irish airports authority).
AUSTRALIAN 15
AIRPORTS AND THEIR
MARKETS
the Federal Aviation Administration in the United States introduced an airport
privatisation pilot scheme with the opportunity for five airports to be privatised —
by 2000, only two sales had been completed.5
Ownership
While the range of services and activities provided at airports varies across the core-
regulated airports, the division of responsibility for the provision of these services
(operational, handling and commercial activities) follows a similar pattern. As with
most major airports in developed countries (and as was the case with the core-
regulated airports’ previous operator, the FAC) the airport operator provides
relatively few services directly to airport users. Rather, Australian airport operators
tend to provide and maintain facilities that allow other organisations to carry out
their activities. These organisations include government agencies such as
5 A 99-year lease on Stewart International in New York State has been sold to National Express,
and Niagara Falls International has been sold to a Spanish company, CINTRA (TRL 2000b).
6 Australia Pacific Airports Corporation operates Melbourne and Launceston airports, and
Northern Territory Airports Group operates Darwin and Alice Springs airports.
7 BAA plc operates a number of airports in the United Kingdom, including Heathrow, Gatwick,
Glasgow and Edinburgh airports.
8 For example, the Port of Brisbane Corporation, a wholly State-owned enterprise, has interests
in BAC, and Launceston City Council has an equity share in Australia Pacific Airports
(Launceston) Pty Ltd.
16 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
Airservices Australia (ASA), airlines (and other specialist providers of operational
and handling services) and concession holders.
While ASA is responsible for air traffic control and airspace management services,
it is not responsible for allocating landing and take-off slots. The Airports Act
(described in chapter 3) provides for the Minister of Transport and Regional
Services to authorise a body to be the slot coordinator at Australian airports.
Currently, Airport Coordination Australia (ACA), a private company, is the
authorised slot coordinator. ACA provides timeslot management services for all
international airline services and new entrant airlines servicing domestic routes at
Australian airports, and all operations at Sydney Airport.9
Australian airport operators also provide and maintain runways, taxiways, visual
navigation aids, airfield lighting, roads and aircraft parking areas. Usually, ground-
handling services such as cleaning, the provision of power, baggage handling and
9 Slot management at Sydney Airport is regulated separately from other airports under the
Sydney Airport Demand Management Act 1997 (chapter 3).
AUSTRALIAN 17
AIRPORTS AND THEIR
MARKETS
other operational services (for example, aircraft push-back and towing, and ground
engineering) are supplied by the airlines and/or independent suppliers.
The arrangements for the management of the domestic terminals used by Australia’s
major domestic carriers, Ansett and Qantas Airways, have been quite different from
those at the common-user terminals (both domestic and international). Since the late
1980s, the two major domestic airlines have operated their own domestic terminals
under long-term leases negotiated prior to the establishment of the FAC. Under the
leases, which at most core-regulated airports run to around 2018, airlines are
responsible for all operational aspects at the terminal, including managing the
provision of retailing and advertising activities. In addition, at some airports,
including Melbourne and Sydney, airline responsibility extends to providing and
maintaining terminal infrastructure, with the airport operator providing only the
land for the domestic terminals under the leases. At other airports, such as Brisbane,
the airport operator provides and maintains the terminal infrastructure. While
Qantas continues to operate its domestic terminals under these arrangements, the
future of Ansett’s domestic terminals is uncertain. Currently, Ansett’s domestic
terminals are operated by Ansett’s administrator and are being used by Ansett
Mark II.
The airport operators (or, in the case of domestic terminals, the airlines) engage
specialist operators to provide commercial activities. Retail, car-hire and catering
activities are delivered under this type of arrangement. Car-parking management
18 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
appears to be the only commercial activity that some airport operators perform
directly. Airport operators at Brisbane, Perth and Sydney airports, for example,
manage some or all of their car-parking services directly, whereas operators at
Melbourne and Canberra airports have engaged the services of a car-parking
management company.
International comparisons
The arrangements for the provision and management of airport facilities and
services at core-regulated airports generally are similar to those in place at major
airports in other developed countries. Although the ownership structures differ
significantly, airport operators do not tend to provide many services directly.
Instead, as is the case in Australia, they manage the facilities and infrastructure that
allow airlines and other organisations to carry out their business.
Common to nearly all airports is that local or central government authorities provide
air traffic control and navigation services. Even when the airport operator provides
these services, government policies or international arrangements (chapter 3)
heavily influence the nature of the service.
Some airport operators also are directly involved in the provision of commercial
activities. For example, Aer Rianta, the Irish airport authority, operates the duty and
tax free shops at its airports (including Dublin) and, in the case of Shannon Airport,
it operates catering and bars (Aer Rianta no date). At Fiumicino Airport in Rome,
the airport authority also operates a number of retail outlets (ADR no date).
Perhaps the most significant difference between the organisational structure of core-
regulated airports and those of airports overseas is in the management of domestic
terminals. Airline management of their own terminal infrastructure is unusual in an
international context. The only other developed country where this type of
arrangement is common is the United States, where airlines own or lease most
The demand for airport services is, in general, a derived demand: the demand for
airport services is derived from the demand for airline services; in turn, the demand
for airline services is derived from the demand for business meetings, for visiting
friends and relatives, for migration, for tourism, for freight handling and so on. The
demand for airport services is also filtered through the cost structure of other input
providers, including airlines. This section describes in broad terms the different air
travel segments served by Australian airports, and changes in demand over time.
Demand elasticities of airport services are discussed in chapter 5.
Most international visitors come to Australia for tourism purposes (figure 2.5) —
around 56 per cent in 1999. These visitors to Australia must choose an international
gateway airport, the five largest being Sydney, Brisbane, Melbourne, Perth and
Cairns.
5000
4500
4000
3500
Passengers (’000s)
3000
2500
2000
1500
1000
500
0
1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999
20 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
The airlines in the domestic market link the principal cities throughout Australia by
operating high-capacity jet aircraft. In 2000, 10 routes (city pairs) accounted for
over two-thirds of all passenger movements in Australia (table 2.1). For each
principal city, the domestic market is concentrated at one airport. The regional
market generally links the smaller centres with the larger principal cities, with each
regional city served by one airport.
AUSTRALIAN 21
AIRPORTS AND THEIR
MARKETS
Figure 2.6 Passenger movements at core-regulated airports, 1991-92 to
2000-01a
Passenger movements (’000s)
30000
25000
20000
15000
10000
5000
0
1991-92 1992-93 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 1996-97 1997-98 1998-99 1999-00 2000-01
5000
4500
4000
3500
3000
2500
2000
1500
1000
500
0
1991-92 1992-93 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 1996-97 1997-98 1998-99 1999-00 2000-01
22 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
Figure 2.6 (continued)
1200
1000
800
600
400
200
0
1991-92 1992-93 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 1996-97 1997-98 1998-99 1999-00 2000-01
a Based on revenue passengers carried on scheduled international, domestic and regional RPT services.
Includes (provisional) regional data.
Data source: DoTRS (unpublished).
The first half of 2001 was characterised by high growth in passenger movements on
major domestic routes. The entry of two airlines providing discount services in the
domestic market in 2000 — Impulse Airlines in June and Virgin Blue in August —
contributed to this growth. The total number of domestic passenger movements over
the first six months of 2001 was around 10 per cent higher than the corresponding
figure in the previous year.11
However, in the latter half of 2001 the aviation industry altered substantially.
Impulse Airlines ceased independent operations in May, and in September
Australia’s second-largest domestic carrier, Ansett, entered into voluntary
administration and briefly suspended all operations. By October 2001, Ansett had
resumed operations as Ansett Mark II, albeit with significantly reduced capacity. As
at January 2002, questions over the longer-term structure and organisation of the
airline remained unresolved. This, combined with a general reduction in
AUSTRALIAN 23
AIRPORTS AND THEIR
MARKETS
international air travel worldwide in response to the terrorist attacks in the United
States on 11 September and their aftermath, resulted in a significant reduction in
flights and consequently in the demand for airport services. The initial impact of the
reduction in Ansett services was felt heavily at all core-regulated airports, in
particular those dependent on domestic airlines. At Coolangatta Airport, for
example:
In the week following the Ansett collapse domestic seat capacity … was reduced to
64 per cent of that for the week before the collapse. For the week ending 4 October this
had fallen to 62 per cent before increasing to 67 per cent for the week ending
11 October. (sub. DR58, p. 2)
In October 2001, Adelaide Airport noted that the reduction in Ansett services
resulted in:
… a loss of around 182 weekly flight arrivals equivalent to 43 per cent of the Airport’s
domestic landed tonnes/week and a similar short-term reduction in available seat
capacity to and from the city. (sub. DR57, p. 3)
Since September 2001, Ansett Mark II has resumed some services, and Qantas and
Virgin Blue have moved to increase capacity on a number of routes or introduced
services on new routes. However, domestic airline capacity is still below the level
that existed when Ansett was fully operational.
These changes in the structure of the airline industry are expected to result in
Qantas having a significantly larger share of the domestic aviation market in the
short to medium term. In the medium term industry analysts have predicted that
Qantas’ share of the domestic commercial aviation market could remain at
65 per cent at least and potentially much higher (Bartholomeusz 2001; Ferguson
and Meyrick 2001).12
12 Prior to September 2001, Ansett had 37 per cent of the domestic market, Qantas had
56 per cent and Virgin Blue had 7 per cent (Ferguson and Meyrick 2001).
24 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
In Australia, for core-regulated airports over the period 1997-98 to 2000-01,
aeronautical revenue was defined to include revenue earned by airports from
services subject to prices notification under the Prices Surveillance Act 1983
(chapter 3). Included was revenue derived from the provision of a number of
essential operating and handling services and facilities, with most aeronautical
revenue earned from runway charges and (international and domestic common-user)
terminal charges.13 From 1998-99, revenue from vehicle access charges levied on
taxis at Brisbane, Perth and Canberra airports was classified by the ACCC as
aeronautical revenue (appendix E). At all three airports in 1999-00, revenue from
these vehicle access charges amounted to less than 1 per cent of total aeronautical
revenue.
In 1999-00, across all core-regulated airports, only 34 per cent of total revenue was
earned from aeronautical services. Coolangatta Airport reported the highest
proportion of revenue from aeronautical services — 55 per cent. In 1995-96, prior
to privatisation, when all current core-regulated airports were operated by the FAC,
the average share of revenue from the same bundle of aeronautical services at the
same airports was 38 per cent. Since 1995-96, the share of revenue earned from
non-aeronautical services has increased at all privatised core-regulated airports apart
from Coolangatta and Townsville airports (figure 2.7).
13 Also included in aeronautical revenue were airport charges levied on airlines to cover the costs
of services provided by Australian Protective Services.
14 Retail revenue is a component of non-aeronautical revenue. In this instance, retail revenue
refers to four revenue streams: (1) duty free, food and beverage, currency exchange and
speciality stores within the international terminal; (2) short- and long-term car parks; (3) car-
rental concessions; and (4) advertising sites.
AUSTRALIAN 25
AIRPORTS AND THEIR
MARKETS
Figure 2.7 Comparison of revenue shares: FAC and core-regulated
airportsa
Aero FAC (1995-96) Aero (1999-00) Non-aero FAC (1995-96) Non-aero (1999-00)
90
80
70
60
Per cent
50
40
30
20
10
0
in
lle
gs
ey
t
de
ne
rra
ta
ne
rth
on
ar
w
at
vi
rin
dn
ba
ai
ur
st
ob
Pe
be
ar
ng
ns
ce
el
bo
Sy
Sp
is
H
an
D
Ad
w
la
Br
un
el
C
To
oo
e
M
La
ic
C
Al
a The high share of non-aeronautical revenue at Adelaide Airport may be explained partly by the importance
of property revenue to the airport. Property revenue accounts for around half of Adelaide Airport’s total
revenue, with major sources including the domestic terminals leased to Qantas and Ansett, and a light-
industrial business precinct.
Data sources: ACCC (2001b–f); FAC (1996).
As noted above, airport operators generally do not provide retail services directly;
rather, they provide space for retailers to carry out their business. The payment
agreements between airport operators and retailers are based primarily on
concession fees (whereby airport operators receive payments based on the volume
of revenue generated by the retailer),15 often complemented by a small fixed annual
rental component. Airports can be an attractive location for retailers because they
provide access to potentially large volumes of relatively affluent customers
(Melbourne Airport, sub. 7). Doganis (1992) noted that concession income is
strongly related to passenger numbers generally, and to the number of international
travellers in particular. The two airports at which the percentage of non-aeronautical
revenue has fallen since privatisation — Coolangatta and Townsville — do not have
significant international RPT services.
15 Concession fees can also be based on passenger numbers, although this form of payment is less
common.
26 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
Several privatised core-regulated airports — particularly Brisbane and Adelaide —
see property revenue as a means of increasing non-aeronautical revenue. Brisbane
Airport, for example, has established a light-industrial precinct on airport property
to take advantage of its large land holdings. Current and committed tenants at the
precinct include a mobile phone and accessories wholesaler and Australia Post, as
well as operations more traditionally associated with airports, such as freight
operations (BAC 2001).
Rentals paid to airport operators by the holders of the domestic terminal leases are
classified as property revenue, in both the regulatory accounts and company annual
reports. Property revenue also includes payments to airport operators from the
providers of operating and handling services for the use of land and facilities.
Consequently, property revenue is often a significant component of an airport
operator’s total revenue. It is approximately one-third of total revenue at Hobart
Airport (sub. 11) and nearly half at Adelaide Airport (Adelaide Airport Limited
(AAL), sub. 20).
At smaller airports, the reliance on the major domestic carriers tended to be even
greater. At Launceston Airport, for example, Qantas and Ansett accounted for
98 per cent of aeronautical revenue (Melbourne Airport, sub. 7). In March 2001,
AAL noted:
Qantas and Ansett alone, and their regional airlines … contribute about 75 per cent of
aeronautical revenues at Adelaide Airport (or approximately 23 per cent of total current
revenue) … In total, more than half of AAL’s total revenue is sourced from Qantas and
Ansett. (sub. 20, p. 8)
Charges subject to the price cap at core-regulated airports at June 2000 are shown in
table 2.2. Airport operators typically levy a landing charge for the use of runways,
taxiways and aprons (airport operators do not supply air traffic control services)
and, where they operate the terminal, a terminal charge. At some airports additional
charges are levied for aircraft parking. In addition to charges covered by the price
cap, airport operators levy charges to recover the costs of government-mandated
security services, and to recover the costs of necessary new investment as approved
by the ACCC.
Table 2.2 Airservices Australia (ASA) charges, and charges subject to the
price cap at core-regulated airports, 2000 a,b
International
Runway charges terminal charges Aircraft parking ASAc
The starting point for runway charges at privatised airports was the FAC charge at
the time of privatisation, which was the same at all these airports apart from
28 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
Adelaide. The differences in the runway charges shown across privatised airports in
table 2.2 reflect differences in their respective price-cap arrangements (chapter 3).
The starting point for terminal charges was also the FAC charge — shortly before
privatisation (in January 1997) the FAC increased charges for the use of terminals at
Sydney, Melbourne, Brisbane, Adelaide and Perth airports by varying amounts for
each airport.
Most user charges at core-regulated airports are levied on the same basis as the
system used by the FAC. User charges still tend to be calculated on the basis of the
maximum take-off weight (MTOW) of the aircraft. However, some airports have
introduced passenger-based charges, particularly for the international and common-
user domestic terminals. Sydney Airport now levies a per passenger charge on
international passengers to cover runway, international terminal, and passenger and
checked-baggage security screening services. Melbourne Airport charges for use of
its multi-user domestic terminal on a per passenger basis. Canberra and Coolangatta
airports (see below) are currently the only core-regulated airports to levy runway
charges on a per passenger basis.
Also shown in table 2.2 are the ASA charges for navigation and rescue services.
ASA moved from network charges to location-specific charges (based on full cost
recovery) for firefighting and rescue services in 1997 and for terminal navigation
charges in 1998. The variation in ASA charges is much greater than that in airport
charges and, as costs are largely fixed, unit charges are higher in airports with lower
traffic volumes.
Under the price-cap regime, airport operators are permitted to ‘pass through’ to
users 100 per cent of the costs related to government-mandated security
requirements. Such charges do not affect compliance with the price cap. Cost pass-
through is allowed for charges levied on the airport operator by Australian
Protective Services and for the provision of passenger and checked-baggage
screening services.
Pass-through provisions also exist for charges levied to recover costs for necessary
new investment (NNI) (chapter 3). Examples of ACCC-approved NNI charges at
core-regulated airports since privatisation are shown in box 2.1. Airport operators
are permitted to increase approved charges in line with the CPI.
AUSTRALIAN 29
AIRPORTS AND THEIR
MARKETS
Box 2.1 Examples of ACCC-approved necessary new investment
charges
• In August 2000, the ACCC approved the introduction of a charge of $1.65 per
passenger (GST inclusive) to recover the costs associated with the construction of
the multi-user domestic terminal at Melbourne Airport. The decision was based on a
commercially-negotiated agreement between Melbourne Airport and Impulse and
Virgin Blue airlines. (ACCC 2000g)
• In April 2000, the ACCC approved increases in landing and international terminal
charges at Brisbane Airport to recover the costs of a range of projects (including
apron expansion and improvements in taxiway lighting). Landing charges were
permitted to increase by 3 cents a tonne in 2000-01 and by a further 9 cents a tonne
in 2001-02 (MTOW). International terminal charges were permitted to increase by
38 cents a tonne in 2000-01 and by a further 61 cents per tonne in 2001-02
(MTOW). (ACCC 2000f)
• In April 2000, the ACCC approved an increase in landing charges at Perth Airport of
2 cents per tonne (MTOW), and the introduction of a charge of 10 cents per
international passenger. The charges were allowed in order to recover the costs of a
range of projects over the period 1997-98 to 1999-00. (ACCC 2000c)
In recognition of the need to give airports greater pricing flexibility to manage the
sudden and significant decline in the volume of airport traffic, the Commonwealth
Government changed prices oversight arrangements at core-regulated airports in
October 2001 (chapter 3). Among other things, the changes allowed the Phase 1
airports (Brisbane, Melbourne and Perth) a once-only price increase (by varying
amounts for each airport) as a pass-through in the price cap. Price-cap regulation
was removed from all other privatised core-regulated airports (with price-cap
regulation replaced by price monitoring of aeronautical services at some airports).16
Since implementation of the new prices oversight arrangements, there have been
changes in the level and, in some cases, structure of charges for airport services at
most core-regulated airports (all charges GST inclusive). In many cases, airports
offer various rebates. However, details of these often are confidential (chapter 7).
• The Phase 1 airports — Melbourne, Brisbane and Perth — have all increased
charges by the full amount determined by the ACCC to be in accordance with
the Government’s October announcement. However, the structure of the price
changes differs by airport.
30 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
- Melbourne Airport increased average aeronautical charges by 6.2 per cent in
January 2002. Landing charges were increased by 59 cents to $6.40 per tonne
(MTOW), an increase of approximately 11 per cent. At the same time,
international terminal charges were reduced by 59 cents per tonne, leaving
the total charge (per tonne) paid by international airlines unchanged.
- In November 2001, Brisbane Airport increased all aeronautical charges by
6.7 per cent.
- In November 2001, Perth Airport increased domestic landing charges by
19 per cent to $6.30 per tonne (MTOW). Other charges remained unchanged.
This represented a weighted average increase in aeronautical charges of
7.2 per cent.
• Adelaide Airport increased landing charges for domestic RPT services by around
22 per cent to $6.00 per tonne (MTOW) in December 2001. Charges for
international and regional services were not altered. This represented a weighted
average increase in charges of approximately 14 per cent.
• Coolangatta Airport moved from weight-based charges to passenger-based
charges in November 2001. A passenger charge of $5.90 is now levied on
arriving and departing passengers. This represents an increase of approximately
170 per cent on the estimated equivalent per passenger charge of the previous
weight-based charges. (Gold Coast Airport, sub. DR58)
• In October 2001, Canberra Airport increased its per passenger landing charge by
113 per cent to $5.40 per passenger.
• Darwin and Alice Springs airports (both operated by Northern Territory
Airports) moved from weight-based landing charges to passenger-based charges
in December 2001. A charge of $6.02 per international passenger movement and
$4.93 per domestic passenger movement was introduced at Darwin Airport. A
$5.48 charge per passenger movement was introduced at Alice Springs Airport.
The switch to passenger charges makes comparisons with previous weight-based
charges difficult, but the new charges are more than double the previous
aeronautical charges at both airports.
• Townsville Airport introduced a 60 cent per passenger charge in December
2001, additional to their existing weight-based landing charges.
As at December 2001, Hobart and Launceston airports had not announced any
increases in their charges. A number of airports have indicated that they will review
their charges in the first half of 2002 in light of developments in traffic volumes.
AUSTRALIAN 31
AIRPORTS AND THEIR
MARKETS
International comparisons
User charges at major Australian airports appear to be among the lowest in the
world. The Transport Research Laboratory (TRL) compiles an annual index of user
charges at 40 major international airports.17 The index ranks airports on the basis of
the composite basket of airport services required to land and turn around an
international passenger service, including air traffic control charges, terminal
charges, aircraft parking charges and noise levies (figure 2.8). In 2000, Sydney
Airport (one of Australia’s more expensive airports in terms of international
terminal fees, and the only Australian airport included in the study) was ranked as
the sixth cheapest in the study (TRL 2000b). The ACCC (2001i) noted in its final
decision on the proposed price increases at Sydney Airport that, taking into
consideration the approved price increases, user charges would still be below the
average charges of those airports surveyed by TRL.
The Board of Airline Representatives of Australia (BARA) commented that the use
of the TRL study was of limited assistance as it failed to take into account
adequately the differences in the way in which a number of airports charge. In
particular, BARA noted that:
• several airports in the sample offer large discounts to frequent users, and/or levy
charges which depend on the destination or origin of the aircraft;
• … the impact of different charging policies in relation to transfer passengers is
not taken into account; and
• the study excludes taxes, even though at several airports, taxes are used to
recover costs in the same way as aeronautical charges in other airports.
(sub. DR54, p. 33)
While the study does not account for all differences in pricing policies across
airports, it does provide some indication of the level of user charges at Sydney
Airport relative to the level of charges at a number of major airports worldwide.
Moreover, even if features such as discounts, taxes and transfer passenger charges
were taken into account, it would not necessarily result in an increase in Sydney
Airport’s aeronautical charges relative to the charges levied by other airports in the
study. For example, taxes are not levied at Sydney Airport to recover the costs of
aeronautical services, and Sydney Airport offers discounts to some airport users.
17 Airports are included in the survey to represent the different approaches to airport pricing in
both public and private-sector operating environments. They are not necessarily the 40 largest
airports in the world (TRL 2000b).
32 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
Figure 2.8 Airport charges at selected international airports, 2000a,b
120
100
Airport charges index number
80
60
40
20
0
rid
y
Mexic ow
i
r
ey
lulu
bay
en
Berlin
ich
na
- LIN
i
inki
pest
s
cisco
do
burg
Kong
sels
Oslo
ago
ns
ah
o
LHR
- JFK
G
kholm
WR
kfurt
rth
n
LGW
Miam
Duba
ouve
o Cit
ngele
Dubli
Lisbo
apor
Toky
hingto
- CD
terda
Sydn
Athe
Mad
nhag
Vien
Orlan
Jedd
rt Wo
Mun
Mosc
Hels
Hono
Bom
Chic
y-E
Brus
Buda
Fran
nnes
Fran
on -
Milan
Vanc
Sing
on -
Hong
York
Stoc
Los A
Paris
Ams
Was
Cope
s/Fo
Jerse
Lond
Joha
Lond
San
New
Dalla
New
a Based on the charges for a composite basket of airport services required to land and turn around an
international passenger service. b To derive the airport charges index, airport charges in local currencies are
converted to Standard Drawing Rights (SDRs). The SDR is an artificial currency unit calculated using a
weighted basket of five national currencies — the US dollar, the German deutschmark, the UK pound, the
French franc and the Japanese yen. It reflects actual exchange rates, not purchasing power parity.
Data source: TRL 2000b, Review of Airport Charges 2000, Crowthorne, UK.
Another TRL study, reported by the ACCC (2001i), compared 40 major airports
and airport groups on the basis of aeronautical revenue per aircraft movement and
per passenger. The five Australian airports covered in the survey were ranked
among the lowest in the world in terms of revenue per passenger (in the bottom 10
— figure 2.9) and in terms of revenue per aircraft movement (in the bottom 15).
The ACCC (2001i) noted that, allowing for the approved increase in charges at
Sydney Airport, charges at that airport would remain below the international
average for both measures. However, because the bundle of aeronautical services
provided by airport operators can differ substantially between airports, the
conclusions that can be drawn from these rankings are limited. For example, unlike
many overseas airports, the major domestic airlines operate their own domestic
terminals under long-term leases at the Australian airports included in the study. In
addition, a small number of airports included in the study (such as Frankfurt and
Munich) earn aeronautical revenue through the provision of ground-handling
services, which tend to be provided by airlines or specialist providers at other
airports.
AUSTRALIAN 33
AIRPORTS AND THEIR
MARKETS
Figure 2.9 Aeronautical revenue per passenger at selected international
airports, 2000a,b
12
10
8
SDR
0
e
ey
ich
row
i
hingto pain)
ter
lulu
oup
ide
ane
ianta
town
cisco
ary
en
ick
roup
na
frica)
ugal)
Perth
rio
burg
land
roup
apore
aris
Kong
kholm
oup
l
kfurt
lles
Miam
tiona
ouve
ngele
ourn
Maca
Grou
Grou
Sydn
nhag
Vien
Onta
ches
Gatw
Mun
Adela
Calg
Hono
n Du
eath
de P
ts Gr
Brisb
m Gr
Auck
Fran
rts G
nnes
rts G
Cape
Aer R
A (S
(Port
uth A
Fran
n Na
Vanc
Melb
Sing
Hong
Stoc
Los A
Berlin
BAA
Man
Cope
on-H
-
irpor
terda
ports
Airpo
AEN
Joha
Airpo
o
hingto
A (So
San
ANA
Lond
Lond
an A
Aero
Ams
Was
egian
dish
ACS
Was
aii
Swe
Haw
Norw
a Based on total passenger movements (international, domestic and, where applicable, regional). b The SDR
is an artificial currency unit calculated using a weighted basket of five national currencies — the US dollar, the
German deutschmark, the UK pound, the French franc and the Japanese yen. It reflects actual exchange
rates, not purchasing power parity. SDR Standard Drawing Right.
Data source: TRL 2000a, Airport Performance Indicators 2000, Crowthorne, UK.
Airport expenditure
34 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
Figure 2.10 Expenses per passenger movement at core-regulated airports,
1999-00
Total expenses per passenger movement, including interest Total expenses per passenger movement, excluding interest
25
20
15
$A
10
0
ne
in
rth
lle
gs
ey
t
de
rra
ta
ne
ar
o
w
at
vi
rin
dn
ba
ai
ur
st
ob
Pe
be
ar
ng
ns
ce
el
bo
Sy
Sp
is
H
an
D
Ad
w
la
Br
un
el
C
To
oo
e
M
La
ic
C
Al
On average, capital costs (defined as depreciation plus interest expense) is the main
expense category for Australian core-regulated airport operators (figure 2.11).
However, given that financing structures (equity and loans) vary significantly
between airports and, in some instances, the distinction appears to be rather
arbitrary, the figure for the interest category is of limited value. Salaries and wages
also tend to be significant on average, although they are a much smaller component
of total costs than interest and depreciation. This in part reflects the fact that labour-
intensive components of airport services do not tend to be provided directly by core-
regulated airports. Land also is an important component of their operations but the
classification of expenses in the regulatory accounts does not provide consistent and
separate measures of the land expenses incurred. The value that should be placed on
land is contentious (appendix F).
AUSTRALIAN 35
AIRPORTS AND THEIR
MARKETS
Figure 2.11 Expenses of core-regulated airports, by category, 1999-00a
Depreciation
18%
Interest
44%
Amortisation
5%
a Expense categories used are those contained in the ACCC regulatory reports.b ‘Other’ includes the ‘other’
category contained in the ACCC regulatory reports plus consultants and advisers, general administration and
leasing for Adelaide Airport; passenger screening for Alice Springs and Darwin airports; and passenger and
checked-baggage screening for Perth Airport. APS Australian Protective Services.
Data sources: ACCC (2001b–d).
In broad terms, the cost pattern illustrated in figure 2.11 is indicative of the situation
at individual airports. However, there is (sometimes significant) variation across
airports. For instance:
• labour costs tend to be a more significant proportion of costs at smaller airports
than they are at the larger ones; and
• not all expense categories are relevant to all airports. For example in 1999-00,
only seven of the 12 core-regulated airports incurred Australian Protective
Services expenses and only eight included amortisation expenses.
36 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
1999-00.18 Non-aeronautical expenditure exceeded aeronautical expenditure at
three airports only in 1999-00 — Adelaide, Launceston and Melbourne.
Aeronautical Non-aeronautical
100
90
80
70
60
Per cent
50
40
30
20
10
0
in
lle
gs
ey
t
de
ne
rra
ta
ne
rth
on
ar
w
at
vi
rin
dn
ba
ai
ur
st
ob
Pe
be
ar
ng
ns
el
ce
bo
Sy
Sp
is
H
an
D
Ad
w
la
Br
un
el
C
To
oo
e
M
La
ic
C
Al
a Classification of expenses as aeronautical and non-aeronautical is based on ACCC regulatory reports. Total
costs exclude costs that have not been classified as either aeronautical or non-aeronautical.
Data sources: ACCC (2001b–d).
The high proportion of aeronautical expenses possibly reflects the fact that airport
operators are more likely to be directly involved in operations on the aeronautical
side than the non-aeronautical side of the business, where they typically act as
landlords. The relatively low proportion of aeronautical expenditure for Adelaide
Airport is affected by its use of contractors to provide many of its day-to-day
operations. This is because contracting expenses at Adelaide Airport are recorded as
non-aeronautical expenses in the regulatory accounts even though some contracted
labour is used to provide aeronautical services.19
The data presented here rely on information provided in the ACCC regulatory
reports by the airports. Thus, measured differences across airports also are likely to
18 Total expenses in this case exclude interest and other expenses that have not been classified as
either aeronautical or non-aeronautical in the ACCC regulatory reports.
19 Adelaide Airport contracts out its day-to-day operations to Serco Australia, which provides the
staff required for these operations (AAL 2000).
AUSTRALIAN 37
AIRPORTS AND THEIR
MARKETS
be influenced by different accounting and cost allocation methods. According to
WAC:
Regulated airports lodge annual accounts with the ACCC, and while the form of the
final published accounts is consistent between airports, there is no way of determining
whether each airport has applied the same methodology in reporting aeronautical and
non-aeronautical costs. WAC understands that each airport employs different cost
accounting tools to achieve the split. (sub. 21, p. 25)
Investment expenditure
38 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
thousand dollars per year to over $30 million per year,20 with further investment
planned. Terminal upgrades, apron and runway enhancements, the erection of
fencing and retail development are among the types of investment already
undertaken or planned for the next few years.
Productivity
There have been few recent studies on the productivity of core-regulated airports.
One recent study, by Abbott and Wu (2001) measured the (total factor) productivity
growth21 of core-regulated airports over the period 1990-91 to 1999-00 and
benchmarked these airports against a selection of international airports using data
envelopment analysis. Over the period of the study, core-regulated airports
improved their performance in terms of total factor productivity, with productivity
growth averaging 7.7 per cent per year, well above that of the rest of the economy
(which had an average growth rate of 1.36 per cent per year) (Abbott and Wu
2001, p. 17). The high growth rates in productivity were driven by rapid
technological change, particularly over the period 1990-91 to 1994-95. Abbott and
Wu (2001) suggested that improvements came in the form of the introduction of
more advanced computer and air traffic systems, which allowed for the
accommodation of greater traffic flows through the airports. This process helped the
airports to overcome delays and accommodate an expansion of output without the
construction of new and enlarged terminals and runways.
Profitability
In 1999-00, the operators of all privatised core-regulated airports earned profits and
positive returns on non-current tangible assets. However, with the exception of the
operators of Townsville Airport, all operators reported a loss after interest and tax
(table 2.3). All Phase 1 airports are highly geared (ACCC, sub. 36, attachment A)
20 This does not include Sydney Airport, where SACL (sub. 27) invested in excess of
$800 million over two years leading up to the 2000 Olympics.
21 Productivity refers to the relationship between inputs and outputs. Productivity growth implies
an increase in the ratio of outputs to inputs. Total factor productivity is a measure of overall
productivity, capturing all sources of productivity.
AUSTRALIAN 39
AIRPORTS AND THEIR
MARKETS
and, in general, high interest payments at all privatised core-regulated airports have
been an important factor contributing to the low returns. Sydney Airport is less
highly geared than other core-regulated airports (although it has substantial
borrowings) and was able to generate sufficient operating profit to cover interest
payments and generate net profits — approximately $43 million in 1999-00.
The ACCC regulatory accounts (ACCC 2001b–f) indicate that the non-aeronautical
segment of the airport business is much more profitable than the aeronautical
business. In 1999-00, non-aeronautical businesses generated high operating profit
margins at nearly all core-regulated airports, while aeronautical businesses mostly
made small profits or had losses — around half of the core-regulated airports made
a loss on the aeronautical side of their businesses in 1999-00 (tables 2.4 and 2.5).
40 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
Table 2.4 Financial indicators for aeronautical and non-aeronautical
business segments at Phase 1 and Sydney airports, 1999-00
Airport Revenue Costs Operating profita Operating returnb
$m $m $m %
Brisbane
Aeronautical 38.211 38.016 0.195 0.0
Non-aeronautical 91.320 23.241 68.079 21.0
Melbourne
Aeronautical 55.160 39.277 15.883 3.7
Non-aeronautical 111.823 33.700 78.123 26.5
Perth
Aeronautical 20.471 17.595 2.876 3.1
Non-aeronautical 49.207 14.431 34.776 32.5
Sydney
Aeronautical 120.052 126.003 (5.951) (0.4)
Non-aeronautical 190.001 66.540 123.461c 8.2
a Before abnormal items, interest, tax and amortisation. b On tangible non-current assets. c Approximately
$3 million of Sydney Airport’s revenue has not been allocated between aeronautical and non-aeronautical
sources.
Source: ACCC (sub. 36, attachment A).
As noted previously, the disaggregation of costs and assets into aeronautical and
non-aeronautical components is determined by airport operators’ interpretation of
the regulatory guidelines. Consequently, there may be some variation in how costs
and assets are allocated across core-regulated airports. Even allowing for variation
in the disaggregation of costs and assets, it seems likely that returns from non-
aeronautical businesses are greater than those from aeronautical businesses at core-
regulated airports. As KPMG observed:
On the assumption that revenue allocations are fairly stated and not at risk of
significant subjectivity, the cost and/or asset allocations disclosed in the regulatory
accounts would need to be materially misstated to change the view that aeronautical
returns are less than non-aeronautical returns. (ACCC, sub. 36, attachment A, p. 6)
AUSTRALIAN 41
AIRPORTS AND THEIR
MARKETS
Table 2.5 Financial indicators for aeronautical and non-aeronautical
business segments at Phase 2 airports, 1999-00
Airport Revenue Costs Operating profita
$m $m $m
Adelaide
Aeronautical 9.867 8.681 1.186
Non-aeronautical 39.442 11.087 28.355
Alice Springs
Aeronautical 1.812 2.724 (0.912)
Non-aeronautical 2.795 1.466 1.329
Canberra
Aeronautical 4.372 5.178 (0.806)
Non-aeronautical 6.255 1.419 4.836
Coolangatta
Aeronautical 5.804 5.447 0.357
Non-aeronautical 3.593 3.703 na
Darwin
Aeronautical 5.334 8.357 (3.023)
Non-aeronautical 6.341 2.264 4.077
Hobart
Aeronautical 3.311 2.375 0.936
Non-aeronautical 2.184 1.038 1.146
Launceston
Aeronautical 1.525 1.617 (0.092)
Non-aeronautical 2.914 1.558 1.356
Townsville
Aeronautical 2.188 2.747 (0.559)
Non-aeronautical 3.611 1.509 2.102
a Before abnormal items, interest, tax and amortisation. na Not available, due to non-allocated revenues.
Of the remaining non-core-regulated airports that receive RPT services, some are
privately owned (for example, Hamilton Island and Mount Isa). However, most are
owned and operated by local councils which, in most cases, assumed the running of
the airports under the ALOP.
23 Refers to revenue directly related to the aircraft operations, and comprises charges on aircraft
(33 per cent) and charges on goods and passengers (22 per cent).
AUSTRALIAN 43
AIRPORTS AND THEIR
MARKETS
3 The regulatory environment
In 1997 and 1998 the Commonwealth Government negotiated long-term leases for
22 Commonwealth-owned airports, with 17 being privatised (chapter 1). The
objectives were to:
… improve the efficiency of airport investment and operations in the interests of users
and the general community, and to facilitate innovative management. (Harris 1997,
p. 2)
This chapter describes the regulatory environment affecting the operation of these
and other airports in Australia. It also describes the changes to prices oversight
arrangements for several airports, as announced by the Commonwealth Government
in October 2001.
Where relevant, the terms and conditions of lease and sale agreements are also
described. Although the inquiry’s terms of reference embrace all airports, this
chapter focuses on the regulation, particularly price regulation and access
arrangements, of airports leased from the Commonwealth given their importance
and the emphasis in the terms of reference.
Chapters 8 and 9 assess price regulation for the period from the granting of leases
against the criteria for efficient regulation, and weigh the costs and benefits of the
regulation. Chapter 9 also examines the effect of other regulations, such as s. 192 of
the Airports Act.
THE REGULATORY 45
ENVIRONMENT
oversight arrangements were changed for most airports. Section 3.2 describes the
regulatory changes announced in October 2001.
Prices oversight arrangements, introduced when Phase 1 and 2 airport leases were
sold, were designed to complement the objectives (see above) of leasing the
Commonwealth-owned airports.
Another objective was the protection of airport users. The paper noted that ‘the
arrangements should also aim to protect airport users from any potential abuse of
market power by airport operators’ (DoTRD 1996, p. 1).
In early 2001, these objectives were re-stated by the Minister for Transport and
Regional Services in correspondence with the ACCC. The Minister also noted that
implicit in the prices oversight arrangements:
… was that regulatory intervention would only occur where it was apparent that airport
behaviour was adversely impacting on consumers or competition between airlines
through the exercise of a real or perceived monopoly power. (Anderson 2001b, p. 1)
The Commonwealth Government at the time of leasing the airports recognised that
a period of adjustment to prices oversight might be necessary in the new regulatory
environment. The first five years were therefore viewed as a transition period, with
a review of prices oversight arrangements to be completed prior to the end of this
period (chapter 1).
In essence, price regulation of the Phase 1 and 2 airports, in the period from the sale
of leases until October 2001, comprised:
• prices notification for aeronautical services;
• a CPI-X price cap on aeronautical services at privatised core-regulated airports;
• price monitoring of aeronautical-related services; and
• provisions for necessary new investment (NNI) at airports.3
These arrangements were administered by the ACCC under the PS Act. In carrying
out its functions, the ACCC was to have regard to the following, among other
factors:
(a) the need to maintain investment and employment, including the influence of
profitability on investment and employment; [and]
(b) the need to discourage a person who is in a position substantially to influence a
market for goods or services from taking advantage of that power in setting prices.
(PS Act, s. 17(3))
2 The regulatory environment for airports leased from the Commonwealth and not subject to
price regulation is described in section 3.4. These airports were: Mount Isa, Tennant Creek,
Archerfield, Jandakot, Moorabbin, Parafield, three Sydney basin airports (Bankstown, Camden
and Hoxton Park) and Essendon.
3 All of these regulations, except price caps, also applied to Sydney Airport.
THE REGULATORY 47
ENVIRONMENT
Box 3.1 Regulation of facilities and activities
Aeronautical services (those notified for the purposes of s. 21(1) of the PS Act)4 at all
core-regulated airports, including Sydney Airport, were grouped in two main categories:
aircraft movement facilities and activities, and passenger processing facilities and
activities.
Aircraft movement facilities and activities comprised: airside grounds, runways,
taxiways and aprons; airfield lighting, airside roads and airside lighting; airside safety;
nose-in guidance; aircraft parking areas; and visual navigation aids.
Passenger processing facilities and activities included: forward airline support area
services; aerobridges and airside buses; departure lounges; immigration and customs
services areas; public address systems and closed circuit surveillance systems;
baggage make-up, handling and reclaim; public areas in terminals; flight information
display systems; landside road and lighting; and covered walkways.
Some aeronautical-related services provided by airport operators were not subject to
notification but were subject to price monitoring under s. 27A of the PS Act.5 These
were: aircraft refuelling; aircraft maintenance sites and buildings; freight equipment
storage sites; freight facility sites and buildings; ground support equipment sites;
check-in counters and related facilities; and public and staff car parks.
Not all services provided by airport operators were subject to prices oversight. For
example, there was no prices oversight of airport operators’ revenue from rents or
leases for retail shops and cafes, administration and office space, catering facilities,
valet parking services and VIP lounges.
Moreover, airport operators did not have responsibility for all aeronautical services
provided at airports. Aeronautical services outside airport operators’ areas of
responsibility included: en-route navigation and terminal navigation (air traffic control
and airspace management); aeronautical information; communications; and firefighting
and rescue services.
Sources: Prices Surveillance Act 1983; ACCC (2000a).
Services and facilities provided by domestic terminals that were leased for the long-
term to airlines were not subject to price regulation. However, domestic common-
user terminals and international terminals were covered by price regulation.
4 Declaration No. 87, June 2000, covered Brisbane, Melbourne and Perth airports, Declaration
No. 88, June 2000 (Adelaide, Alice Springs, Canberra, Coolangatta, Darwin, Hobart,
Launceston and Townsville airports), and Declaration No. 89, June 2000 (Sydney Airport).
These Declarations replaced previous Declarations.
5 Declaration Nos 87, 88 and 89. The Minister for Financial Services and Regulation (pursuant
to s. 27A of the PS Act) directed the ACCC to undertake formal monitoring of prices, costs
and profits related to the supply of specified aeronautical-related services at all core-regulated
airports (Direction No. 21, October 2000, replacing previous Directions).
48 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
Aeronautical services were subject to prices notification under the PS Act. This
required specified companies to notify the ACCC of all proposed price increases for
these services. Financial penalties applied for failure to notify price increases. The
ACCC was required to make a determination about the notified price increase
within 21 days unless the company agreed to an extension. Although any such
determinations were not enforceable, failure to comply could, under the PS Act,
trigger a public inquiry (upon direction by the Minister) and the freezing of charges.
Moreover, the Commonwealth Government reserved the right to consider advice
from the ACCC regarding the need for stronger regulation (DoTRD 1996).
The Ministerial direction under the PS Act required the ACCC to monitor and
report publicly on prices of aeronautical-related services and their relationship to
costs. The ACCC could make no determination, but it could recommend whether
more or less rigorous prices oversight of aeronautical-related services was needed.
Price-cap arrangements
Aeronautical services were subject to an annual CPI-X price cap at all core-
regulated airports, except Sydney Airport, for a five-year period following
privatisation (pursuant to s. 20 of the PS Act). Direction No. 20, by the Minister for
Financial Services and Regulation, described the price-cap arrangements.6
Airport operators were required to provide the ACCC with sufficient information to
enable these assessments to be made. For individual price notifications, this
included information on initial and new prices and previous years revenue shares of
the relevant component. Information to enable an assessment of price-cap
compliance included revenue from each of the charging components for the year of
6 Direction No. 20, October 2000, replaced Direction No. 17, and previously, Direction No. 13.
THE REGULATORY 49
ENVIRONMENT
assessment and the previous year, and volume and output for each component
(ACCC 1997a).
CPI-X
The CPI measure for the price cap was the Treasury Underlying Rate of Consumer
Price Inflation. Each airport’s X value was set by the Commonwealth Government,
on advice from the ACCC, and ‘reflects expected productivity improvements that
the Government considers can be made in the provision of aeronautical services at
each airport’ (Direction No. 12, June 1997, p. 1). The X values varied substantially
between airports, ranging from 1 per cent for Canberra and Townsville airports to
5.5 per cent for Perth Airport (table 3.1). The starting prices for the price cap were
the FAC prices at the time of privatisation — shortly before privatisation (in
January 1997), the FAC increased charges for the use of terminals at Sydney,
Melbourne, Brisbane, Adelaide and Perth airports by varying amounts for each
airport.
Table 3.1 X values applying in each year of the price cap at core-
regulated airports
Airport X values (%)
Adelaide 4.0
Alice Springs 3.0
Brisbane 4.5
Canberra 1.0
Coolangatta 4.5
Darwin 3.0
Hobart 3.0
Launceston 2.5
Melbourne 4.0
Perth 5.5
Townsville 1.0
Sources: Direction No. 12, June 1997; Direction No. 13, May 1998.
The formula
The price-cap formula measured annual changes in the prices of the aeronautical
services for each airport. It was a modified revenue-weighted average price. The
formula took the percentage change in price of each charging component (for
example, landing charges), weighted this by the revenue share in the previous
50 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
period, and then summed over all components.7 This was referred to as the ‘tariff
basket’ approach (chapter 10).
According to the DoTRD Pricing Policy Paper, the ACCC would not object to price
changes unless they breached the price cap. Airport operators therefore could
continue to ‘rebalance’ charges within their airport’s overall price cap (DoTRD
1996).
Under-recoveries, where prices were below the cap in a particular year, could be
carried over between years within the five-year price-cap period. Over-recoveries,
where prices exceeded the price cap, were to be passed back to customers within
two years from the period of over-recovery (except in the case of year 4, where it
was to be passed back fully in year 5).
Cost pass-through
Under Direction No. 20, the ACCC was to allow 100 per cent pass-through in the
price cap of mandated security requirements and congestion charges employed as
part of an airport demand management scheme under the Airports Act (described in
section 3.3). Pass-through provisions also existed for NNI.
The price-cap arrangements allowed airport operators to seek ACCC approval for
charges in excess of the price cap, to recoup costs associated with NNI.
7 For more information on the price cap formula, see Direction No. 20, October 2000, and
ACCC (1997a).
THE REGULATORY 51
ENVIRONMENT
The DoTRD Pricing Policy Paper explained:
While price caps on aeronautical charges are directed towards ensuring that there is no
abuse of the potential market power of the airport operators, price oversight
arrangements dependent solely on these price caps may restrict the timely development
of necessary new aeronautical infrastructure.
As a result, some flexibility is afforded airport operators to rebalance charges outside
the price cap. In particular, operators need sufficient incentive to invest in new
infrastructure, and the ability to meet the costs of necessary new investment. (DoTRD
1996, p. 4)
The operator could seek to recoup these costs where price rises were required to
fund the new investment and ‘users with a significant interest in the new investment
support the investment, including the associated charges’ (DoTRD 1996, p. 4).
Following industry consultation, the ACCC, as administrator of the price cap and
assessor of NNI proposals, defined the words ‘necessary’, ‘new’ and ‘investment’ to
be able to distinguish between NNI and other forms of airport expenditure
(ACCC 2000b). For example, the ACCC assessed several projects proposed by
Perth Airport and decided that some projects did not fall within its definition of new
investment (ACCC 2000c).
8 These guidelines are set out in the DoTRD (1996) Pricing Policy Paper, and replicated in
Direction No. 20, October 2000.
52 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
Box 3.2 Guidelines for the assessment of proposals for price
increases related to necessary new investment
These criteria will, where relevant for its purposes, guide the ACCC in its assessment of
proposals related to necessary new investment to increase aeronautical charges at a rate in
excess of the CPI-X cap:
(a) the operator’s plans for new investment or service innovation and the associated
costs;
(b) the relationship between the proposed increases in aeronautical charges and the
costs (including the level of rate of return) of the new investment or service;
(c) support from airport users with a significant interest in the investment for the
operator’s proposals, including in relation to charging changes;
(d) contribution of the new investment/service to productivity improvements at the
airport;
(e) overall efficiency of the airport’s operation;
(f) the particular demand management characteristics of individual airports, including
any demand management schemes in place, capacity constraints and any
underutilisation of airport infrastructure;
(g) airport performance against quality of service measures, including services under the
control of the airport operator;
(h) airport performance vis á vis other Australian airports and any comparable
international airports; and
(i) the extent to which the proposed investment will facilitate the operations of new
entrants to domestic or international aviation.
While the ACCC must take the above into account in deciding whether to approve a
proposal to increase charges outside the cap, each proposal will be considered on its merits
having regard to the information available to the ACCC. The weight provided by the ACCC
to each of the criteria (a) to (i) may vary on a case by case basis.
Consistent with the provisions of the Prices Surveillance Act 1983, where the ACCC does
not approve a proposal to increase charges outside the price cap, it will provide a statement
of reasons for its determination. (DoTRD 1996, attachment B)
These guidelines were incorporated in Government directions to the ACCC under the
PS Act.
Sydney Airport
Price regulation for Sydney Airport, which was leased but not privatised in 1997,
differed in some respects from that of other core-regulated airports. Aeronautical
services at Sydney Airport were subject to prices notification under the PS Act but a
THE REGULATORY 53
ENVIRONMENT
price cap did not apply to those services. Aeronautical-related services were subject
to price monitoring.9
Because Sydney Airport was not subject to the price-cap arrangements set out in
Direction No. 20, the NNI provisions of this Direction did not apply. However,
Direction (No. 18) provided for Sydney Airport to seek an increase in charges for
aeronautical services to cover NNI.10 The criteria used by the ACCC in assessing
Sydney Airport proposals were the same as those for the core-regulated airports
subject to a price cap (box 3.2).
Quality of service monitoring at Sydney Airport took place under the Airports Act.
Moreover, the Minister for Financial Services and Regulation directed the ACCC
(Direction No. 18) to take account of quality of service information obtained from
Sydney Airport in considering notifications to increase prices for aeronautical
services.
The Minister also directed the ACCC to give consideration to the following when
considering price notifications for Sydney Airport (in effect, a dual-till approach):
In assessing prices for aeronautical services, the Commission should not take into
account the revenues generated, or costs incurred, in the provision of services other
than aeronautical services. (Direction No. 22)
54 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
point prices at privatisation respectively.11 The basis of calculation underlying
these price increases has not been made public. In all other respects, price
regulation at these airports remained unchanged; aeronautical services continued
to be subject to prices notification with price caps.12 Airport prices notification
arrangements, the basket of aeronautical services and price-cap arrangements,
including the X values and NNI provisions, remained unchanged from those
described in section 3.1.
Also unchanged for Melbourne, Brisbane and Perth airports were price
monitoring arrangements for aeronautical-related services.13
As with Melbourne, Brisbane and Perth airports, these airports must continue to
comply with all of the regulatory requirements of core-regulated airports
described in section 3.5, including the Airports Act.
• Coolangatta, Alice Springs, Hobart, Launceston and Townsville airports are no
longer subject to any price regulation — that is, both the price caps and price
monitoring have been removed.16 These airports remain, however, designated as
core-regulated airports and therefore must comply with all of the relevant
regulatory requirements described in section 3.5, including the Airports Act.
11 Direction No. 24, October 2001. Replaced Direction No. 20. According to the Direction,
starting point prices are the ‘Federal Airports Corporation prices introduced on 1 January
1997, as adjusted in accordance with the price cap arrangements applying since that time, and
accounting for under-recoveries or over-recoveries under those price cap arrangements’. The
ACCC has interpreted this to mean starting point prices at 1 January 1997 with no allowance
for adjustments under the price caps. The ACCC (2001k) has treated the price increases as
GST inclusive.
12 Direction No. 24, October 2001. Replaced Direction No. 20.
13 Direction No. 25, October 2001. Replaced Direction No. 21.
14 Direction No. 26, October 2001. Replaced Direction No. 21.
15 Direction No. 26, October 2001. Replaced Direction No. 21.
16 Revocation No. 28, October 2001.
THE REGULATORY 55
ENVIRONMENT
• No changes were made to price regulation at Sydney Airport.17 Sydney Airport
remains subject to prices notification of aeronautical services and price
monitoring of aeronautical-related services (section 3.1). Other regulations,
outlined in section 3.5, continue to apply.
The Government noted that these changes were consistent with the findings of the
Commission’s draft report and that it would give further consideration to price
regulation of airport services ‘in the light of developments in airport prices and the
Productivity Commission’s final report’ (Hockey 2001).
Prior to October 2001, quality of service monitoring applied to all airports subject to
price regulation (that is, all core-regulated airports). As noted above, since the
October 2001 regulatory changes, quality of service monitoring has continued to
apply to all core-regulated airports, even though several are no longer subject to
price regulation (Coolangatta, Alice Springs, Hobart, Launceston and Townsville).
Under the Airports Act, the ACCC is limited to monitoring the services and
facilities provided by, or which could be influenced by, airport operators. Thus the
ACCC does not directly monitor service quality of other key organisations
providing services at the airport — for example, airlines, Airservices Australia
(ASA), Australian Customs Service, Australian Quarantine and Inspection Service,
Department of Immigration and Multicultural Affairs, and Australian Federal
56 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
Police. Consequently, key aspects of an airport’s operations, such as domestic
terminals leased to airlines, are not subject to ACCC monitoring.
There are usually several indicators for each service. The services covered, and the
indicators, for Phase 1 airports and Sydney Airport, are different in some respects
from those for Phase 2 airports.
The indicators specified for gates and aircraft parking services for Phase 2 airports
are illustrative of the indicators used. They are:
• any change over time in the number of aircraft parking bays;
• any change over time in the total area of designated bay area; and
• the change over time in satisfaction with the system, according to a
questionnaire of airlines (Airports Regulations, Schedule 2, Part 2).
Some indicators are ‘static’ and objective (for example, the number of aerobridges)
and others are subjective (for example, satisfaction with check-in waiting times).20
Information on the indicators is sought from a variety of sources, including airport
operators (information for static indicators), passengers (survey), airlines (survey),
ASA and Australian Customs Service (survey).
Records to be kept by the airport operators, to be provided to the ACCC, are also set
out in the regulations.21 These vary between Phase 1 and Sydney airports, and
Phase 2 airports.
THE REGULATORY 57
ENVIRONMENT
3.4 Access regulation
The access framework applying to airports determines the airport services or
facilities to be subject to access regulation, and sets out procedures for the terms and
conditions (including prices) of access to be determined. There are two separate
legislative instruments providing for access to airports: an airports-specific
instrument (s. 192 of the Airports Act); and a general instrument (Part IIIA of the
TP Act).
Other aspects of these acts that affect airport operations and have the potential to
affect the prices of airport services are described in section 3.5.
Section 192 sets out an access regime for all privatised airports designated as core-
regulated airports under the Airports Act. Section 192 continues to apply to those
core-regulated airports no longer subject to price regulation since the regulatory
changes of October 2001 (Coolangatta, Alice Springs, Hobart, Launceston and
Townsville). The access regime allows airport operators 12 months after an airport
has been privatised (with a possible 12-month extension for Phase 2 airports) to
have an access undertaking accepted by the ACCC. An access undertaking is a
legally binding document setting out the terms and conditions under which access to
the services provided by essential airport facilities will be made available to access
seekers. If an undertaking is accepted by the ACCC, the services covered by the
undertaking cannot be declared for the purposes of Part IIIA of the TP Act (see
below).
If an undertaking is not accepted by the ACCC within the designated period, the
Minister must determine that each ‘airport service’ at the airport is a declared
service for the purposes of Part IIIA. There is no scope to appeal an ACCC decision
not to accept an undertaking, and an undertaking cannot be lodged once a service
has been declared. The Minister is required to specify the expiry date of the
determination, and no power is conferred on the Minister under s.192 to renew the
declaration once it has expired (ACCC, pers. comm., 5 July 2001).
Rather than listing declared services, the Airports Act sets out specified criteria for
declaration. The criteria are that the service:
(a) is necessary for the purposes of operating and/or maintaining civil aviation services
at the airport; and
58 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
(b) is provided by means of significant facilities at the airport, being facilities that
cannot be economically duplicated;
and includes the use of those facilities for those purposes. (s. 192(5))
Section 192 provides for the ACCC to determine whether a specified service
satisfies the criteria and, therefore, whether it is an airport service covered by the
Minister’s declaration. Amendments were made to s. 192 in 1998 (s. 192(4A–D)),
which gave the ACCC the power to make a written determination that a service is,
or is not, an airport service without reference to the criteria in s. 192(5). However,
the ACCC has stated that a determination always will involve an assessment of the
criteria in s. 192(5), and only where application of the criteria will result in perverse
outcomes will the ACCC make a decision that appears inconsistent with the criteria
(ACCC 1998g). A determination under the amendments can be disallowed by the
Parliament under s. 48 of the Acts Interpretation Act 1901, and can be reviewed by
the Federal Court under s. 39B of the Judiciary Act 1903 in limited
circumstances.22
The ACCC may determine that a service is an airport service on its own volition,
but generally will do so only on the application of an interested party. It will
generally conduct a public inquiry, except where it is clear the service satisfies the
declaration criteria (ACCC 2000a). If a service is determined to be an airport
service, then the airport operator must negotiate commercial terms with access
seekers, or submit to arbitration.
The Airports Act does not provide for appeal against a decision to declare a service
as an airport service.23 However, s. 44K of the TP Act provides limited scope for
appeals to be lodged with the Australian Competition Tribunal within 21 days of the
Minister’s automatic declaration of airport services at an airport.24 There is
currently no scope for appeal against undertaking decisions. Appeal rights for
arbitrated terms and conditions of access exist under Part IIIA.
Given that no undertakings had been accepted by the ACCC prior to expiry of the
designated period, the Minister determined that airport services at all privatised
core-regulated airports were declared. The Minister also determined that the
declarations should expire on 30 June 2002 for Phase 1 airports and 30 June 2003
for Phase 2 airports. Included are services provided by those other than airport
operators, such as freight operators and terminals leased by airlines. As noted
above, there is no provision for the Minister to renew these declarations.
The ACCC has received two applications for a determination on whether a service
is a declared airport service under s. 192. The applications — from Delta Car
Rentals and Virgin Blue — both related to services at Melbourne Airport. (ACCC
decisions relating to these applications are discussed in chapter 9.)
As noted above, s. 192 sets out an access regime for the privatised core-regulated
airports. Airport services at Sydney Airport are currently not declared under s. 192.
However, the Part IIIA access regime applies to Sydney Airport (and non-core-
regulated airports — section 3.6).
25 Facilities that are the source of intermediate services essential to upstream or downstream
service provision.
60 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
airports, including core-regulated airports and airports operated by local
government.26
In providing for access to the services of an essential facility, Part IIIA allows
regulation of the terms and conditions for use of the facility. This is considered
necessary because imposing an obligation to supply could be circumvented by the
terms and conditions of supply, especially price.
Under Part IIIA, a third party can seek access to eligible services through one of
three avenues:
• through a request that the National Competition Council (NCC) recommend that
the responsible Minister declare access to those services;
• through a legally binding undertaking from the facility operator approved by and
registered with the ACCC; or
• through a State or Territory access regime certified by the responsible Minister
as being effective following a recommendation by the NCC.
Specific criteria must be satisfied before access can be obtained through any of
these avenues. While the exact criteria differ among the three avenues, the criteria
generally refer only to access to the services provided by nationally significant
natural monopoly facilities.
Given that no airport undertakings have been accepted by the ACCC and that
certification is not relevant in the case of access to airport services (Commonwealth
access regimes currently are not covered by the certification provisions), parties
seeking access to airport services under Part IIIA must request the NCC to
recommend that the responsible Minister declare the service.
When assessing declaration applications, the NCC and the designated Minister must
consider six criteria specified in the TP Act:
(a) that access (or increased access) to the service would promote competition in at
least one market (whether or not in Australia), other than the market for the service;
(b) that it would be uneconomical for anyone to develop another facility to provide the
service;
(c) that the facility is of national significance, having regard to:
(i) the size of the facility; or
26 While all airports are subject to declaration, there may be limits on arbitration of access
disputes. Under s. 44R, access disputes can only be dealt with if either the provider or access
seeker is a corporation, or if access is required for interstate trade or commerce (ACCC, pers.
comm., 3 May 2001).
THE REGULATORY 61
ENVIRONMENT
(ii) the importance of the facility to constitutional trade or commerce; or
(iii) the importance of the facility to the national economy;
(d) that access to the service can be provided without undue risk to human health or
safety;
(e) that access to the service is not already the subject of an effective access regime;
(f) that access (or increased access) to the service would not be contrary to the public
interest. (ss 44G(2) and 44H(4))
As noted above, s. 44K of the TP Act provides for the service provider (if the
Minister declares a service) or the access seeker (if the Minister decides not to
declare a service) to apply in writing to the Australian Competition Tribunal for a
review of the declaration decision. The application for review must be made within
21 days after publication of the Minister’s decision. The review by the Tribunal is a
re-arbitration of the access dispute, and the Tribunal may affirm, vary or set aside
the Minister’s decision.
There has been only one case seeking declaration of an airport service under
Part IIIA. In November 1996, Australian Cargo Terminal Operators Pty Ltd
(ACTO) — a small business which provides cargo terminal services to international
airlines — sought access to various freight handling and related services provided
by facilities owned by the FAC at Melbourne and Sydney airports (chapter 9).
Part IIIA of the TP Act and the associated Clause 6 of the Competition Principles
Agreement (CPA) were the subject of a Productivity Commission inquiry in 2001.
(For a more detailed discussion of Part IIIA, see PC (2001a).)
62 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
applicable) air transport.27 The leases provide for the lessee to comply with any
demand management scheme under the Airports Act, and to refuse to give access to
aircraft where an owner or operator of the aircraft has failed to pay any amount due
for the use of the airport (and where the lessee has provided the Government with
notice of its intention to refuse access), without being in default of these obligations.
While the access provisions in airport leases provide for access to airports by
aircraft operators, they do not provide for determination of the terms and conditions
of access. Further, the access provisions do not provide for access by other airport
users.
In some cases, access arrangements are also contained in airport sale agreements.
For example, the sale agreement for Canberra Airport requires the airport operator
to negotiate in good faith on access arrangements for the Very High Speed Train
project (Commonwealth of Australia 1998b).
Most of the larger Australian airports have developed a general ‘conditions of use’
document, which sets out physical arrangements, and security and other
requirements, together with commercial conditions such as facilities provided, fees,
services and indemnities that would apply for potential new airlines to obtain access
to the airport. Similar documents exist or are being developed by airports to
facilitate access by operators wishing to provide ground-handling services at an
airport (DoTRS 2000c).
27 Subject to a force majeure clause relating to the lessee’s responsibilities in case of an event
that is beyond the reasonable control of the lessee and prevents the lessee from providing for
access.
THE REGULATORY 63
ENVIRONMENT
3.5 Other relevant regulation for core-regulated
airports
All core-regulated airports were subject to price regulation prior to changes in
October 2001. Since then, price regulation has been removed from several of these
airports (Coolangatta, Alice Springs, Hobart, Launceston and Townsville).
However, they all continue to operate within a comprehensive and complex (non-
price) regulatory environment that includes both domestic (Commonwealth, and
State and Territory) and international agreements. These airports are also subject to
the terms and conditions set out in airport lease and sale agreements.
All of these regulations affect the operations of airports (directly or indirectly) and
therefore have the potential to affect the prices of airport services. Moreover, the
domestic regulations are administered independently by different regulatory
agencies, yet often the effects of these regulations are related. For example, the
ability of airports to comply with price-cap arrangements under the PS Act may be
affected by their compliance with other (non-price) regulatory requirements.
Commonwealth regulation
All core-regulated airports are corporations and therefore are subject to the
provisions of the TP Act, administered by the ACCC. Provisions that may be of
relevance to airport operations include those relating to access to services
(Part IIIA — as discussed in section 3.4), and anti-competitive practices (Part IV).
Exclusive dealing and resale price maintenance are prohibited under ss 47 and 48
respectively.
The TP Act also prohibits mergers and acquisitions that would result in substantial
lessening of competition in a substantial market (s. 50). With this in mind, the
64 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
ACCC, which assesses proposed mergers and acquisitions, examined all bids for
airport leases for potential breaches. In particular, the ACCC considered whether
the operator of a major airport (Adelaide) would be permitted to lease a smaller,
nearby airport (Parafield). The ACCC (2000a) concluded that the acquisition would
not substantially lessen competition.
Airports Act
Some of the key features of the Airports Act relate to access, ownership controls,
environmental management, building and construction controls, demand
management and quality monitoring (box 3.3). Regulation under the Airports Act
relating to access arrangements and monitoring of the quality of service at core-
regulated airports is discussed in sections 3.4 and 3.3 respectively.
28 The Airports Act was amended by the Aviation Legislation Amendment Act 1997 and the
Airports Amendment Act 1999, which extended the period available for lessees to negotiate
access undertakings. Neither made substantial changes to the key features of the Airports Act
(box 3.3).
THE REGULATORY 65
ENVIRONMENT
Box 3.3 Key features of the Airports Act
The Airports Act sets out a regime for the regulation of airports, including:
• airport operators are subject to a 49 per cent limit on foreign ownership, a 5 per cent
limit on airline ownership and a 15 per cent limit on cross-ownership for
Sydney/Melbourne, Sydney/Brisbane and Sydney/Perth airports (Part 3). In early
2002 the Government intends to introduce legislation to change the 5 per cent
airline ownership rule so that general aviation airports are exempted (Anderson
2001a);
• each airport must have an airport master plan approved by the relevant Minister.
This 20-year forward plan identifies, among other things, development objectives,
assesses the future needs of aviation users, forecasts noise exposure levels and
includes proposals for land use and related development (Part 5, Div. 3);
• a major development plan (approved by the relevant Minister) is required for each
major airport development — for example, constructing a new runway, constructing
a new building or extending a taxiway or road (Part 5, Div. 4). The Airports (Building
Control) Regulations 1996 establish a system for approval of building and
construction activity on airports;
• an environment strategy, also subject to approval by the relevant Minister, must
specify, among other things, environmental management objectives and sources of
environmental effects associated with airport operations (Part 6, Div. 2);
• an airport operator may be required to give accounts and reports to the ACCC
(Part 7, Div. 3). In addition, the ACCC will monitor the quality of airport services and
facilities (Part 8, Div. 1);
• regulations may implement certain international agreements (Part 10, Div. 8);
• an airport service will be a declared service for the purposes of the access regime
under Part IIIA of the TP ACT unless an access undertaking is given within 12
months of privatisation (Part 13, Div. 2, s. 192). An airport may also be required to
provide access for defence, emergency or disaster relief purposes (Part 9, Div. 10);
• the relevant Minister may formulate a demand management scheme for an airport,
being a category exclusion scheme, a slot allocation scheme, or a movement
limitation scheme (Part 13, Div. 1). The Minister may also declare the capacity of an
airport, in terms of the maximum number of aircraft movements an airport is capable
of handling in a specified time period (Part 13, Div. 4); and
• ASA will oversee the provision of air traffic services and rescue and firefighting
services at airports (Part 14, Div. 10).
Source: Airports Act 1996.
66 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
Other regulation
THE REGULATORY 67
ENVIRONMENT
There are a number of other Commonwealth regulations that affect the operation of
airports, and thus indirectly may affect pricing.
• The Air Navigation Act 1920 and Air Navigation Regulations 1947 regulate air
navigation, such as international aircraft, international airlines, non-scheduled
flights, aircraft on international flights, investigation of accidents, and aviation
and airport security (including passenger and freight). In particular, the Act
approves ratification of the Convention on International Civil Aviation (Chicago
Convention) (see below). Pursuant to this Act, the Air Navigation (Coolangatta
Airport Curfew) Regulations 1999 restrict certain aircraft movements at that
airport between 11pm and 6am.
• The Adelaide Airport Curfew Act 2000 and associated regulations impose curfew
restrictions, similar to those at Coolangatta, on aircraft movements at Adelaide
Airport.
• Curfew arrangements at Sydney Airport are prescribed under the Sydney Airport
Curfew Act 1995 and associated regulations. As at Adelaide and Coolangatta
airports, a curfew applies between 11pm and 6am. However, there are also
several related restrictions controlling use of runways during shoulder times on
week days and weekends, international passenger aircraft movements and quota
requirements applying to take-offs and landings. The Commonwealth
Government has confirmed that the curfew will remain in place following the
sale of the airport (Anderson and Kemp 2001).
• Slot management for aircraft arrivals and departures at Sydney Airport is
regulated separately from other core-regulated airports (box 3.4).
• A ‘noise’ levy is imposed on the operators of jet aircraft landing at leviable
airports under the Aircraft Noise Levy Act 1995 and the Aircraft Noise Levy
Collection Act 1995. An airport is deemed to be leviable if it meets certain
criteria regarding residential exposure to particular noise levels. There are two
leviable airports: Sydney and Adelaide. The levy is not imposed on aircraft with
noise assessed to be below a specified level.
68 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
Box 3.4 Sydney Airport demand management
The Sydney Airport Demand Management Act 1997 prescribes a maximum of 80
aircraft movements in any hour and establishes a framework for a slot management
scheme.29 Details of the system for allocating slots are set out in the Slot Management
Scheme 1998 (made under the Airports Act), including grandfather rights to slots, the
‘use it or lose it’ test, how to apply for a slot, how slots are allocated and slot swaps.
The slots are allocated and administered by the Slot Manager, Airport Coordination
Australia.
One feature of the slot management scheme is the ‘regional ring fence’ which
effectively creates a separate pool for regional slots. Under these special rules, a
regional service operator may gain a permanent slot if a service is operated for two
consecutive seasons (s. 10). Moreover, regional slots cannot be transferred to non-
regional services (s. 19).
Enforcement arrangements are set out in the Sydney Airport Compliance Scheme
1998, also made under the Airports Act. The Commonwealth Government has
confirmed that the 80 movements per hour cap and regional ring fence will continue
after the sale of the airport (Anderson and Kemp 2001).
The lessee of each core-regulated airport (including Sydney Airport even though it
is not privatised) has signed a lease agreement and a sale agreement with the
Commonwealth of Australia (the lessor).
Lease agreements
The lease agreements set out various obligations on the part of lessees.30 For
example, Australian Airports (Townsville), as the lessee:
• must comply with certain access conditions (described in section 3.2);
• must maintain the airport in good repair;
• must develop the airport at its own cost, having regard to the actual and
anticipated future growth in traffic demand, ‘reasonably expected’ quality
standards and good business practice; and
29 A slot is defined under s. 34 of the Act as ‘a permission for an aircraft movement’. A slot
allocated under the scheme permits a specified aircraft movement at a specified time on a
specified day.
30 These agreements also include obligations on the part of the lessor.
THE REGULATORY 69
ENVIRONMENT
• must, if the option to renew the lease has not been exercised, rebuild any
structure damaged or destroyed during the last 10 years of the lease to an agreed
standard. In addition, any removal or demolition of structures during the last 10
years must be approved by the lessor (Commonwealth of Australia 1998a).
Perusal of other publicly-available leases for Phase 1 and other Phase 2 core-
regulated airports indicates that similar conditions apply across these leases.
However, there are some variations in leases to account for specific characteristics
of airports. For example, the Canberra Airport lease includes reference to the
Fairbairn defence base sub-lease (Commonwealth of Australia 1998b).
Sale agreements
Publicly-available airport sale agreements also do not vary significantly across core-
regulated airports in terms of the general contents. Each core-regulated airport’s
sale agreement contains, among other things, provisions relating to the transfer
(sale) price, sale completion process, resale restrictions and superannuation.
However, there are airport-specific variations to the agreements. For example,
unlike other airports, the Canberra Airport sale agreement contains a provision
obliging the airport to negotiate in good faith concerning access arrangements for a
potential very high speed train terminal (Commonwealth of Australia 1998b).
Moreover, clearly the agreements will differ to the extent that sale prices, deposits
and so on vary across airports.
70 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
State and Territory legislation applies, for example, in the areas of waste
management and occupational health and safety.
State and Territory regulation, such as fair trading legislation, also relates to on-site
commercial trading, gambling, liquor licensing and vehicle parking at airports.32
The transition to State and Territory regulation in these areas was aided by the
promulgation of the Airports (Control of On-airport Activities) Regulations 1997.
Businesses operating at the airports are also subject to State and Territory
regulation.
Box 3.5 Territory and State regulation (and regulators) affecting the
operation of Canberra Airport
Some of the Territory and State regulation (and regulators) affecting the planning, and
development and construction, at Canberra Airport are:
Planning
• National Capital Authority;
• ACT Planning and Land Management;
• Environment ACT;
• ACT Retail Leases Code;
• ACT Tree Preservation legislation; and
• NSW Department of Urban Affairs and Planning (land use planning in flight path
corridors).
Development and Construction
• Building, Electrical and Plumbing Control Regional Office, ACT Government;
• ACT Electricity and Water;
• ACT Stormwater;
• ACT Fire Brigade; and
• ACT Public Health.
There are few State and Territory regulations that are specific to airports or aviation.
Most relevant is the Aerodrome Fees Act 1998 in South Australia, which gives
private and public owners of former Commonwealth airports the statutory authority
32 Fair trading legislation substantially mirrors the consumer protection provisions of the TP Act.
THE REGULATORY 71
ENVIRONMENT
to recover fees from users who endeavour to avoid payment. Other States that have
addressed this issue have done so through the amendment of existing legislation; for
example, New South Wales amended its local government legislation.
International agreements
The Chicago Convention is the legal foundation for the regulation of world civil
aviation and includes several Articles that bear on economic regulation of aviation
directly, and thus affect airport operations and pricing (box 3.6). The Chicago
Convention (Article 44) also established the International Civil Aviation
Organization (ICAO) — a worldwide intergovernmental organisation seeking to
promote the safe and orderly development of international civil aviation. As a
United Nations agency, it ‘sets international standards and regulations necessary for
safe, regular, efficient and economical air transport and serves as the medium for
co-operation in all fields of civil aviation’ (ICAO 1996, p. 3.4-1).
33 Brisbane, Melbourne, Perth, Adelaide, Sydney and Darwin airports are designated ‘major’
international airports. Designated ‘restricted use’ and ‘alternate’ international airports are
Canberra, Coolangatta and Townsville. Hobart is a designated ‘restricted use’ international
airport. Launceston and Alice Springs are designated ‘alternate’ international airports.
Currently, there are no international RPT operations at several of these airports (for example,
Hobart, Launceston and Townsville). However, there have been international RPT operations
in the past at some of these airports (for example, Hobart and Townsville). The designated
international status of leased non-core-regulated airports and other airports is described in
section 3.4.
34 Several Protocols amending or supplementing the Chicago Convention have been approved by
ICAO over the ensuing years.
72 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
Box 3.6 The Convention on International Civil Aviation
Key economic regulatory features of the Chicago Convention include:
• state sovereignty over airspace (Article 1);
• rules governing permission for international non-scheduled and scheduled air
services in contracting states (Articles 5 and 6);
• cabotage — that is, contracting states may refuse permission for aircraft from other
contracting states to take on its passengers, mail and so on (Article 7);
• the requirement that regulations of the contracting state regarding entry, customs,
quarantine and so on must be complied with by other contracting states (Article 13);
• the requirement that airports in contracting states that are open for public use by
national aircraft must be open under uniform conditions to aircraft from other
contracting states. Airport charges for aircraft from other contracting states should
be no higher than those for national aircraft (Article 15);
• the requirement that air navigation be expedited and that unnecessary (particularly
administrative) delays to aircraft, passengers, crews and cargo be prevented (Article
22); and
• the requirement that contracting states agree to provide airports and navigation
facilities which facilitate international air navigation and are in accordance with the
Convention. Operational systems should also be in accordance with the Convention
(Article 28).
Source: Convention on International Civil Aviation.
ICAO develops and releases various policies and guidelines on the regulation of air
transport (for example, on airport charges, capacity and tariffs), manuals (including
one to provide guidance to airport managers) and technical annexes to the Chicago
Convention dealing with areas such as aeronautical communications, ground
handling, meteorology, operations and security.
Another major agreement signed at the Chicago Conference was the International
Air Services Transit Agreement (known as the Two Freedoms Agreement), which
provides for the multilateral exchange of rights of overflight and non-traffic landing
for scheduled international air services among contracting states. Australia’s
ratification of this agreement has been approved under the Air Navigation Act.
The General Agreement on Trade in Services (GATS) has the potential to affect
airport operations through the liberalisation of international trade in air services. As
a member of the World Trade Organization, Australia is required to accept the
GATS as part of the outcome of the Uruguay Round of multilateral trade
negotiations concluded in 1994.
THE REGULATORY 73
ENVIRONMENT
GATS coverage of air services is limited. The Annex on Air Transport Services to
GATS excludes aviation with three exceptions where GATS commitments apply:
aircraft repair and maintenance services; selling and marketing of air transport
services; and computer reservation system services. However, these services are
covered only if member countries schedule them as specific commitments. Progress
generally has been slow, and Australia has not yet scheduled all three.
International carriers with access must be treated in accordance with GATS, the
Chicago Convention and bilateral agreements. Airports have an obligation to abide
by the intent and spirit of the agreements negotiated by their governments. If an
international carrier considers that a breach might have occurred, it may ask its
government to take up the complaint with the Australian Government. As noted
above, the Airports Act (Part 10) provides for the introduction of regulations to
require an airport operator to comply with particular international agreements.
Penalties apply for non-compliance. An example of such a complaint occurred in
the 1980s when US carriers alleged that the UK Government (because Heathrow
Airport is operated by the British Airports Authority) had breached the user charges
article in the Bermuda II agreement — a bilateral agreement between the United
Kingdom and United States. The US Government took the complaint of the carriers
to the UK Government. An arbitral tribunal was established to adjudicate the issue
(Toms 1994).
Apart from ICAO, the other major international body to influence the regulation of
international air services is the International Air Transport Association (IATA).
IATA, established in 1945, is a trade association currently representing over 230
airlines. Its stated goals include:
• providing safe, reliable and secure air services;
• developing cost-effective, environmentally friendly standards and procedures to
facilitate the operation of international air services; and
• identifying and articulating common industry positions and supporting the
resolution of key industry issues (IATA 2001).
37 Interlining involves connecting passengers between two airlines on the same ticket.
THE REGULATORY 75
ENVIRONMENT
3.6 Regulation of airports not subject to price
regulation
Most airports in Australia are not subject to price regulation; they cater for general
aviation traffic rather than RPT (chapter 2). The regulatory environment differs
depending on whether these airports are leased from the Commonwealth
Government.
As noted in section 3.2, in October 2001, the Government announced the removal
of all price regulation for five core-regulated airports; Coolangatta, Alice Springs,
Hobart, Launceston and Townsville. The non-price regulatory framework within
which these airports operate remains unchanged, and is described in section 3.5.
Some of the provisions of the Airports Act, such as the access provisions (s. 192)
and the provisions on quality of service monitoring (Part 8), do not apply to these
10 airports because they are not core-regulated airports. However, the Act does
apply where airports are specified in the regulations. For example, all of these
airports, except for Mount Isa and Tennant Creek, are specified in the Airports
Regulations for the purposes of land use, planning and building controls. Thus, they
must meet the requirements of Part 5 of the Act, including the development of a
master plan.
Airport lease agreements for these leased non-core-regulated airports are similar to
Phase 2 core-regulated airport agreements, but with some airport-specific variation.
38 As noted in chapter 1, the sale of Essendon Airport was completed in September 2001 and the
Sydney basin airports are to be sold in the second half of 2002.
76 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
For example, unlike Phase 2 core-regulated airports, Mount Isa Airport has no
provisions in its lease for the costs of an airport environment officer.39
Sale agreements for the airports that have been privatised are, in general, similar to
those for core-regulated airports. However, one important difference is that these
airports are not subject to airport development obligations under the agreement.
Other airports
Other non-core-regulated airports include regional airports with both RPT and
general aviation such as Orange, Mildura and Broome, and numerous smaller
general aviation airports such as Lilydale and Pine Creek (chapter 2). Also included
in this ‘other’ group is Cairns Airport. Over 200 airports are owned and operated by
local government. Other airports are owned and operated by statutory government
authorities (for example, Cairns) and the remainder are under private control.
These other airports are not subject to Commonwealth price regulation or the
provisions of the Airports Act. They are, however, subject to some other
Commonwealth legislation — for example, the Air Navigation Act and Part IIIA of
the TP Act.40 Part IV of the TP Act applies to airports that are corporations.
Airports that are unincorporated businesses are subject to State and Territory
competition codes (a modified version of Part IV) enforceable by the ACCC.
Without the regulation of the Airports Act, State and Territory government
regulation applies to this group of airports to a greater extent than it applies to
airports leased from the Commonwealth. For example, planning and approval of
building and construction at Commonwealth leased airports is regulated by
Commonwealth legislation; State and Territory legislation applies to building and
construction activity at these other airports.
39 Pursuant to the Airports Act, the Airports (Environment Protection) Regulations 1997 exempt
Mount Isa Airport from the environment provisions of Part 6 of the Act.
40 All Australian airports are subject to declaration under Part IIIA of the TP Act. However,
under s. 44R, there may be limits on arbitration of access disputes for some regional airports,
including those operated by local municipalities (section 3.2).
THE REGULATORY 77
ENVIRONMENT
International agreements are of little relevance to these airports because few are
designated international airports, and when they are designated, it is generally on a
limited basis.41 An exception is Cairns Airport, which has a considerable number of
international RPT services. Some others, such as Broome and Port Hedland airports,
have international RPT services from time to time (DoTRS 2000b). International
agreements affect the costs and pricing of these airports in a similar manner to core-
regulated airports.
Possible rationales for future price regulation of airport services are discussed in
this chapter. Principles for efficient pricing of airport services and criteria for
efficient regulation are also outlined.
The prima facie rationale for price regulation of certain airports is their perceived
market power — that is, an ability to raise prices above efficient levels — and their
perceived incentive to use it. (What is meant by efficient pricing is discussed
below.) This concern is reflected in the terms of reference, which state that:
… the purpose of this inquiry is to examine whether new regulatory arrangements,
targeted at those charges for airport services or products where the airport operator has
been identified as having most potential to abuse market power, are needed to ensure
that the exercise of any such power may be appropriately counteracted. (para. 6)
Airports have natural monopoly characteristics (chapter 5). Though the tendency
towards natural monopoly arises from efficiency benefits in the provision of airport
services (one airport in a particular location can provide services more efficiently
than two), it inevitably reduces potential competitive pressures on airports.
However, the extent of market power of a particular airport in practice will depend
on a range of factors, including the price responsiveness of air travellers to that
destination, the share of airport costs in the airfare, airport substitution possibilities
and the cost structures of other input suppliers (chapter 5). Other factors, such as the
PRELIMINARY ISSUES 79
influence of potential profits from commercial activities at airports and
countervailing power of airlines, may affect the incentive for, and ability of, airports
to exercise fully any market power they possess (chapter 7).
Nonetheless, the concern remains that airports with market power will increase
aeronautical charges above (efficient) costs, thus increasing airfares and reducing
consumption of air travel. Persistently-high airport charges normally would also
yield monopoly profits for airports. In these circumstances, price regulation that
promoted efficient aeronautical prices could deliver economic gains to the general
community — provided such regulation did not create offsetting distortions and
costs — and bring benefits to passengers and airlines at the expense of airports.
Airport access
In addition to pricing above (efficient) cost, the market power of airports could also
be used to discourage competition in downstream (or upstream) markets (BARA,
sub. 26; ACCC, sub. 38). This is more likely to occur where airports actively
participate in those markets or can control competition in them. An airport with
market power, for example, may restrict ‘front-door’ access to competing, off-
airport car-park providers. This could be achieved by levying a prohibitively-high
charge or by denying the off-airport provider access to a conveniently-located
contact point at the airport. This is considered further in chapter 7.
80 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
access to new airline entrants, provided that the latter at least pay marginal cost and
that the price does not undermine contracts with incumbent airlines.1
Rather than being a rationale for price regulation, denial of access to competing
providers of ancillary services, or collusive actions between an airline and airport,
could be addressed more directly and satisfactorily by anti-competitive provisions
of the Trade Practices Act 1974, or by access regulation. Price regulation is unlikely
to be adequate to address access issues because access can be denied by employing
means other than high prices (for example, by restricting access to conveniently-
located apron and/or terminal facilities). Nonetheless, price regulation that prevents
excessive across-the-board price levels could help prevent marginal airlines
effectively being denied access, whether this was intended or not.
Another suggested rationale for price regulation, not directly related to market
power as such, is that airports provide essential infrastructure that give benefits to
industries other than direct users, particularly the tourism industry. It is argued that
airlines should not be expected to pay the full costs of providing these facilities
when other industries benefit. However, though marginal-cost pricing will promote
efficient use of existing airport assets, such pricing may not provide adequate
returns on new airport investment and therefore may have perverse long-run
implications for airport users (section 4.3). Thus, price regulation that targets a price
equal to short-run marginal cost is unlikely to be consistent with efficient long-term
provision of airport services, unless it is accompanied by some form of
subsidisation of those services.
1 As noted in chapter 3, airports are not permitted to deny landing access to planes (for safety
reasons) but effectively could deny access by imposing a very high landing charge or by
restricting access to other necessary ground infrastructure such as terminals or aprons.
PRELIMINARY ISSUES 81
mandating a single till suggests that it favours the full-cost approach. This was
confirmed in April 2001, in relation to future regulation of Sydney Airport, by the
Minister for Financial Services and Regulation in Direction No. 22 to the ACCC.
It has been argued by Professor Forsyth that the major rationale for price regulation
is to limit the ability of airports to earn profits in excess of normal rates of return,
even though such regulation is likely to have a net efficiency cost. Thus, he argued
that:
Price regulation lessens, rather than increases, the overall efficiency of airports. While
not perfect, a private, unregulated airport is likely to perform better in pure efficiency
terms than a regulated airport because of the efficiency costs of regulation. (sub. 5, p. 5)
But that:
The dominant rationale in Australia for airport price regulation is one of eliminating
excess profits from the use of market power. (sub. 5, p. 5)
While governments may see a need to regulate some firms to reduce perceived
excess profits, the Commission has focused its attention on the likely efficiency
outcomes of various options, including no price regulation of airports.
This latter distinction is drawn because it is the impact on efficiency that determines
the net effect of market power on the size of the national economic ‘pie’.
Redistribution of income, of itself, as the result of higher (or lower) prices — at
least to the extent that income is transferred between Australian residents — does
not involve efficiency effects, though it may generate concerns in the community
about fairness. Typically, inefficient pricing involves both efficiency losses and
income transfers.
82 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
Efficiency effects of market power
In essence, a firm with market power (and assuming that price discrimination is not
feasible) will restrict the amount supplied and raise the price in order to increase its
profits at the expense of consumers. The source of efficiency loss is the reduction in
production and consumption of the good or service below the efficient level — the
so-called monopoly deadweight loss. This is depicted in a simple framework in
box 4.1.
How large this efficiency loss will be depends on the firm’s cost structure and the
price elasticity of demand. For a given marginal cost, and assuming no price
discrimination, the lower the price responsiveness (elasticity) of demand, the greater
the optimal price mark-up over cost.2
Several airports suggested, if elasticities of demand for airport services are very
low, that potential efficiency losses from airport market power also will be low
(compared with efficiency losses if demand were more responsive to price
increases). However, this result does not necessarily hold — it assumes a price
increase of a given amount, not price increases that accord with profit-maximising
behaviour. In other words, with unconstrained pricing, low demand elasticities
could be consistent with large efficiency losses because low elasticities imply high
prices.3 Therefore, in order to make an assessment of likely efficiency losses from
pricing consistent with market power, knowledge is required about the shape and
slope of the demand curve.
If a firm with market power can discriminate in pricing — that is, set different
prices for different consumers and/or units sold — then efficiency costs will be
reduced to the extent that consumption is not discouraged. In the limit, it is feasible
that the quantity provided could be equal to the competitive level (Qc in figure 4.1),
but with some consumers (with a higher willingness to pay) paying prices above
marginal cost.
2 The optimal mark-up is the inverse of the price elasticity of demand for the firm’s output,
where the relevant elasticity is measured at the mark-up inclusive price. Therefore some
caution is required in applying the inverse elasticity formula to an elasticity measured at a point
on the demand curve before a mark-up is imposed. Even if that measured elasticity is very low,
as the price is increased, the price elasticity typically will increase, with the rate of increase
depending on the slope of the demand curve. The flatter the demand curve, the more rapidly
will elasticity increase and therefore the smaller the optimal mark-up over costs.
3 Unless the elasticity of demand is zero — in which case, the optimal price mark-up is infinite
but the efficiency loss is zero.
PRELIMINARY ISSUES 83
Box 4.1 Pricing with market power
Figure 4.1 depicts the cost and demand curves for a firm with market power. For
simplicity, it is first assumed that marginal costs (MC) are constant and therefore equal
to average costs (AC). (D is the demand curve; MR the marginal revenue curve.)
Pricing with decreasing costs is discussed in box 4.2. The framework is static in the
sense that it is concerned with the efficient use of existing airport infrastructure. Over
time, a firm with market power will invest to increase profits.
Figure 4.1
Pm a
Pc MC=AC
b
D
MR
Qm Qc Q
Market power could lead to other efficiency losses. Lack of competitive pressure
could enable a firm to operate inefficiently by allowing its costs to rise or by it not
adopting cost-saving or innovative technologies. Such inefficiency could be at the
expense of the airport’s profits but may yield a ‘quiet life’ for managers. Firms with
market power may also seek to increase profits by allowing quality to fall, for
84 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
example, by reducing staff and investment levels. As discussed in chapter 7, the risk
of such inefficiency at privatised airports appears to be constrained by a
combination of competitive pressures, the incentive of airport owners to increase
profits (especially from non-aeronautical activities) and the ability of airports to
discriminate in pricing. Firms with market power also may seek to keep out
potential competitors by lobbying government — engaging in so-called rent-seeking
activities — or by investing pre-emptively in additional capacity. In other words,
firms with market power may use up real resources (and profits) in a bid to retain
their position in the market.
Some participants argued that the efficiency costs of higher aeronautical charges
would extend beyond the immediate effects in the market for the intermediate
service (that is, aeronautical services). BARA observed that the exercise of airport
monopoly power would generate ‘flow-on inefficiency and costs in the broader
economy’ (sub. 26, p. 10). The ACCC stated that:
There are further allocative efficiency implications where the service is also an
intermediate input. High prices can distort production and consumption patterns of the
goods and services using air travel as an input. For example:
• Air travel is a business input for many companies. Higher prices can affect business
input costs and the ability of such companies to compete in Australia and overseas.
• Air travel is critical to the development of the tourism industry. Tourism is a major
contributor to the Australian economy. High airport charges have the potential to
damage both domestic and international tourism. (sub. 36, p. 6)
It is almost certain that activity levels and prices in user industries will be affected
by the exercise of any airport market power. The extent of the impact generally will
depend on the price responsiveness of demand and supply in those markets and the
degree of competition in them. However, measures of efficiency losses in the
(intermediate) market for aeronautical services resulting from airport market power
(as depicted in figure 4.1) generally will capture allocative efficiency losses in
downstream markets. This is because the derived demand for airport services distils
all the demands and supplies in those markets.
The result holds provided demand and supply in downstream markets (and, indeed,
in the market for aeronautical services itself) are not distorted. If there are no
(positive or negative) spillover effects in downstream markets that are not already
accounted for in prices, then analysis need only focus on efficiency effects in the
market for services provided by airports. On the other hand, if airlines have market
power, the detrimental impact of excessive airport charges on air travel could be
amplified.
PRELIMINARY ISSUES 85
Distributional effects of market power
Higher prices generally mean that there is a transfer of income from consumers to
the producer. (In figure 4.1, at the price Pm, there is a transfer equal to rectangle
PcPmab from consumers to the firm exercising market power.) As noted above,
however, provided the transfer occurs among Australian residents, and there is no
leakage of economic surplus abroad, it does not constitute economic loss to the
nation. Nonetheless, in the case of airports, there may be concerns about any impact
on the distribution of income among passengers, airline shareholders and airport
shareholders. Possible distributional effects of higher airport charges are discussed
further in chapter 7.
As noted above, the Commission has focused on likely efficiency effects to guide
its assessment of regulatory options. This approach assumes that ‘a dollar is a
dollar’ to whomever it accrues, provided the recipient is an Australian resident. The
Commission considers this to be an appropriate analytical approach for two main
reasons.
• First, as discussed in chapter 7, there do not seem to be large differences in
incomes of the broad groups affected by airport charging.
• Second, even if there were identifiable income disparities between affected
groups, attempting to bring about some desired income redistribution through
the restraint of airport charges would be very blunt and inefficient. Income
redistribution generally is more effectively and efficiently targeted through
taxation policy which takes into account the overall income or consumption of
individuals (and, therefore, a measure of their overall economic welfare), and not
just their purchases of airport services and/or their airport shareholdings. (See
PC (2001e) for a discussion of the policy implications of structural adjustment
and related distributional issues.)
While prices above marginal cost generate efficiency losses, prices below the
market-clearing level can also create problems. This may occur when a price-
regulated facility is approaching, or has reached, its capacity limit. (In figure 4.1, if
capacity were restricted to quantity Qm, the market-clearing price would be Pm.
However, if the price were capped at Pc, then demand would exceed the amount
being supplied (by the amount QmQc).)
Without price rationing, this excess demand necessarily would result in some other
form of formal or informal rationing (for example, queuing or a quantity allocation
scheme), which generally incurs efficiency costs. The magnitude of these costs
86 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
depends largely on the type of non-price rationing. Under certain conditions, the
costs incurred by queuing, for example, could dissipate the entire surplus. Queuing
at an airport may involve aircraft being placed in holding patterns or being made to
wait on the apron/taxiways for clearance to depart, imposing large costs on airlines
(and passengers).
Even with a more orderly rationing scheme, implementation costs of the system,
waiting periods for slot allocation, and the likelihood that some airlines and
consumers with high slot valuations will miss out, will generate efficiency losses. In
other words, a regulated price below the efficient price may incur efficiency costs
larger than the efficiency costs incurred when a firm prices above it. (The potential
for asymmetric outcomes is amplified where investments are ‘lumpy’ and costs are
decreasing. In this case, a regulated price set below average cost may mean that
efficient investment is not undertaken. See PC (2001a) for a discussion.)
Moreover, where rationed slots are allocated (not sold) to airlines, the airlines
effectively hold quotas, the value of which reflects the willingness to pay of
passengers arriving or departing from the capacity-constrained airport. In other
words, airlines have an incentive to price-ration seats, charging passengers (up to)
the market-clearing price for accessing the airport, while they pay a lower price to
the airport. In this way, the airlines, rather than their passengers, can capture at least
some of the scarcity rents (equal to area PcPmab in figure 4.1).4 The airlines could
apply this rent in various ways, including distributing it to shareholders or using it
to cover the fixed costs of providing services on more marginal routes. These issues
are discussed further in appendix H.
Market prices typically perform several roles: they ration use of existing assets and
scarce resources; they indicate the opportunity cost of using those resources; and
they signal the need for investment/disinvestment in a particular activity.
4 For reasons discussed above, likely inefficiencies in the allocation system will reduce available
surplus somewhat.
PRELIMINARY ISSUES 87
Decreasing costs and efficiency
Allocative efficiency, in the sense of the best use of existing resources, generally
requires prices equal to (short-run) marginal cost. Where marginal costs are equal to
or above average costs, pricing at short-run marginal cost also will ensure, in the
long-run, that average total costs are covered — that is, efficient producers will
receive a ‘normal’ rate of return on their investments, including an appropriate
margin for risk.
However, as shown in box 4.2, where marginal costs lie below average costs for
relevant ranges of output — which may be the case for Australian airports with
spare capacity — marginal-cost pricing (for all units sold) will not provide an
adequate return on existing assets and, of greater relevance for economic efficiency,
will not provide adequate incentives for airports to undertake efficient investment,
replacement or otherwise. In other words, short-run (uniform) marginal-cost pricing
is unlikely to lead to efficient long-term service provision when costs are
decreasing.
Thus, efficient pricing for firms that exhibit significant economies of scale (and
which, like privatised airports, are required to be self-financing) generally must
depart from all prices being set at short-run marginal cost. Though such pricing
incurs an efficiency loss, compared with marginal-cost pricing (equal to the shaded
area abc in figure 4.2), uniform marginal-cost pricing, in the absence of government
subsidy, is not consistent with sustained provision of the facility and the services it
provides. Of course, raising revenue to pay subsidies itself has efficiency costs.
5 Marginal opportunity costs will incorporate the marginal cost of supplying the service, which
may increase with high utilisation levels plus, for example, congestion costs incurred by users.
88 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
Box 4.2 Pricing with decreasing costs
Figure 4.2 shows a firm for which, over the relevant range, marginal costs (MC) lie
below average costs (AC). (D is the demand curve while MR is marginal revenue.) This
means, if price is set equal to marginal costs (Pc), that the full costs of providing the
service will not be covered. If the firm is required to be self-financing, then average
prices charged must cover average costs. This could be achieved by levying a uniform
price equal to Pe (with a consequent efficiency loss equal to abc) or levying
discriminatory charges, such that those consumers with higher willingness to pay
contribute more to fixed costs than those with lower marginal valuations. To the extent
that marginal units are priced close to or at marginal cost, total costs will be recouped
while minimising any efficiency loss.
Figure 4.2
Pm e
g f
a
Pe
d AC
b c
MC
Pc
D
MR
O
Qm Qe Qc Q
A firm with market power will have the capacity to raise charges beyond cost-recovery
levels. If constrained to set a uniform price, the firm will increase the price to the point
that marginal cost equals marginal revenue (Pm). At this price, efficiency losses equal
all shaded areas in figure 4.2 — that is, the excess of marginal valuation of the service
over marginal cost for all units forgone (from Qc to Qm), with the area edba
representing the efficiency loss attributable to an increase in price from Pe to Pm. At
price Pm the firm earns excess profits equal to efgPm, while consumers are worse off by
an amount equal to the area eaPePm. However, if the firm can discriminate in pricing
(and it will have an incentive to do so to increase profits), then it is feasible that the
marginal consumers will not be priced out of the market.
Even in the presence of large fixed costs and a requirement for a natural monopoly
to be (just) self-financing, efficient levels of output may be feasible if the firm is not
constrained to set uniform prices. Typically, this will require some form of multi-
part pricing, such as different prices for different units sold to a customer (for
example, an up-front access fee plus user charge) or different prices for different
customers of the same or different goods and services (according to capacity to
pay), or some combination of the two approaches. In this way, fixed costs can be
allocated fully to customers, but with marginal consumers and/or marginal sales
making little, if any, contribution.
As a result, the efficiency loss arising from uniform average cost pricing could in
principle be reduced or even eliminated; marginal units are sold at prices equal to
short-run marginal cost. The limits of such pricing are set by the transaction costs
(including information costs) of doing so, and the ability of the provider to prevent
arbitrage across market segments.
6 Ramsey pricing involves setting prices according to consumers’ willingness to pay — more
technically, setting prices that are inversely proportionate to the elasticities of demand of
90 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
away from weight-based charges towards passenger-based charges for terminal and
even runway facilities. Passenger-based charging reduces scope for price
discrimination on some margins (for example, aircraft size), but scope for
discrimination remains on others (for example, between passengers travelling on
different airlines or at different times of day, or between international and domestic
passengers). There is solid evidence that airports do in fact discriminate in favour of
marginal airlines and/or flights by offering a range of concessions and rebates
(chapter 7).
Price differentiation may occur with respect to the timing of consumption, with
different prices for peak and off-peak users, such that peak users bear a higher share
of an airport’s fixed costs.7 Peak charges also signal the higher opportunity cost of
using the facilities and the need for additional capacity.
At airports experiencing at least some excess demand for landing slots, weight- or
passenger-based charging may send the wrong signals to airlines. A small plane or a
plane with a low passenger load is charged less than a large plane or one with a high
passenger load, even though the former may take up as much, or more, time on
approach and on the runway. Uniform charges for runway use, possibly combined
with differentiated peak/off-peak charges, would be one way of restructuring prices.
Another possible form of multi-part pricing would involve the sale or auction of
landing slots (or sale of leases of slots) combined with a user charge. Options for
the allocation of limited airport slot capacity are discussed in more detail in
appendix H.
Some participants suggested, given the demand management system (slot allocation
scheme) in place at Sydney Airport, that price levels are largely irrelevant for the
efficient use of that facility. Suffice to say here that although a slot management
scheme can ration demand among airlines, it is not necessarily the case that airlines
carrying passengers who value landing at peak periods the most obtain the slots, or
that such schemes operate as efficiently as the price mechanism.
BARA (sub. 41) and Qantas (sub. 48) submitted that efficient pricing of airport
services requires rents earned in non-aeronautical activities to be used to drive down
aeronautical charges. This outcome, they contended, was consistent with airports
operating in a competitive environment. This is a complex issue, but for reasons
explained in chapter 10 and appendix C, the Commission does not agree with their
contention. In competitive markets, efficiency requires that users (on average) pay
the long-run incremental cost of providing a good or service. Even in competitive
markets, owners of scarce factors (such as land) generally retain scarcity rents (after
general taxation).
It may be that the costs of providing aeronautical services will fall as the result of an
airport exploiting non-aeronautical opportunities and this will affect the efficient
aeronautical price. It also may be that an airport operator rewards passengers
(and/or airlines) that generate additional custom and profits. But efficient
aeronautical pricing does not necessarily require the transfer of locational rents to
reduce aeronautical charges. To do so may well lower aeronautical charges below
the marginal (long-run or even short-run) costs of providing those services and
discourage investment in them, as well as discourage the development of valuable
non-aeronautical activities.
8 Quantity rationing may be preferred to price rationing for distributional reasons. But, price
rationing is likely to promote efficiency objectives better.
92 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
4.4 Principles of good regulation
Regulation is not costless. In addition to observable administration and compliance
costs, regulators inevitably must make decisions based on imperfect information.
This creates a risk that the costs of regulating — in terms of creating poor incentives
for investment and high compliance costs — may exceed the costs of inaction.
As Starkie observed:
Unfortunately, a little knowledge can be a dangerous thing; the incentive mechanisms
themselves can lead to distortion and unnecessary costs … In turn, this can lead to
further regulatory intervention, to complex regulation (possibly with significant
compliance costs) and to increased regulatory risk that has the effect of increasing the
cost of capital. At the end of the day, therefore, there is a trade-off between living with
imperfect regulation or with imperfect markets. It is only when the market does not
work well, when there is a clear case of natural monopoly and when regulation can
reasonably be expected to improve matters that the regulatory option is worthwhile.
Market imperfections alone are not a sufficient justification for intervention.
(Starkie 2001a)
The terms of reference also specify that, to the extent it is called for:
7(b) future prices regulation should be applied to those aeronautical services and those
airports where airport operators have most potential to abuse market power; …
7(d) prices regulation should minimise compliance costs on airport operators and the
Government;
7(e) prices regulation should promote the efficient operation of airports;
PRELIMINARY ISSUES 93
7(f) prices regulation should facilitate benchmarking comparisons between airports,
competition in the provision of services within airports (especially protecting
against discrimination in relation to small users and new entrants), and
commercially negotiated outcomes in airport operations.
These criteria (which largely mirror the Competition Principles Agreement (CPA))
suggest that any future regulation should be the minimum required to target the
source of the problem and promote efficient outcomes, while being applied in a way
that fosters market outcomes where feasible, imposes minimal compliance costs on
all parties, and promotes transparency and competition.
Several of these principles are reflected in the terms of reference, including that
regulation should:
• promote overall economic performance;
• minimise the regulatory burden on industry consistent with efficient outcomes;
and
• be transparent and low cost.
Other desirable principles of regulation are that it, as far as possible, be predictable,
promote certainty, and be open to scrutiny and regular review.
94 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
5 Market power of airports
The terms of reference require that, in considering the need for price regulation of
airports, the Commission should take into account that ‘future prices regulation
should be applied to those aeronautical services and those airports where airport
operators have most potential to abuse market power’. This chapter examines
potential sources of market power of airports, and the extent to which market power
exists for particular airports in Australia. Chapter 6 examines market power in
particular services provided at airports in Australia. Chapter 7 considers the
potential for abuse of, and the consequences of, market power.
5.1 Introduction
A firm can be said to have market power if it can profitably sustain prices above the
efficient cost of supply for a significant period of time.
Most firms have some market power. The degree of market power, and the extent to
which it persists, depend broadly on barriers to entry to an industry and the
availability to consumers of reasonably close substitutes (which is reflected in the
price elasticity of demand).
The next two sections examine the market power of airports in detail by considering
barriers to entry (section 5.2) and the price elasticity of demand for a particular
airport’s services (section 5.3). However, some preliminary matters warrant brief
discussion here.
First, the degree of market power a firm is assessed to have depends critically on
how the market in which it operates is defined. The market should be defined so as
to identify fully any potential sources of substitution for the firm’s products or
services.
MARKET POWER OF 95
AIRPORTS
Market definition requires consideration of what is being demanded (and by whom),
the geographic area of the market, the functional level of the market (that is, the
position of the firm in the overall supply chain), and the timeframe.
• Airports provide a number of services (chapter 2). To assess airport market
power in these services, it is important to identify the services that are essential
to airlines — and must be consumed as a bundle — and those that are optional,
either in the quantity or quality consumed. What constitutes the ‘necessary
bundle’ may vary depending on the airline customer. To the extent that services
do not need to be consumed or supplied as a bundle, the degree of market power
may differ across services. In addition, market power can vary depending on the
main market segment being considered — for example, business or holiday
traffic, and international or domestic traffic.
• The geographic dimension of a particular airport’s market could be defined
narrowly as the city in which it is located, or more broadly as the region in
which it operates. The appropriate definition will vary depending on the market
segment — for example, international or domestic — as well as on the particular
airport being examined.
• At a functional level, consideration may need to be given to whether the market
should be defined as that for transport services, airport services, that particular
airport’s services, or particular services at that particular airport. As noted by the
ACCC (sub. 36), for this inquiry, initially it is worth considering the market for
an airport’s services rather than looking at particular airport services.
• The nature of the supply of, and demand for, some airport services may mean
that substitution possibilities are limited in the very short term. To assess airport
market power, enough time must be allowed for all market responses to be made
to a price change. Professor King (ACCC, sub. 36, attachment C) suggested that
an appropriate timeframe for an airport could be one to five years. If a very long
time is required for the market to respond, then that in itself could indicate
market power.
These elements of market definition are part of the framework for assessing market
power that was recommended by Professor King (ACCC, sub. 36, attachment C).
The analysis of market power that follows is consistent with his suggested
framework, although the formal structure of analysis differs somewhat.
Finally, it should be noted that, even where a firm has market power, the potential
for its abuse can be mitigated by factors such as the countervailing power of users
and complementarities in demand. In addition, price discrimination may reduce
efficiency losses that otherwise might result from the exercise of market power
(chapter 7).
96 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
5.2 Airports and barriers to entry
A barrier to entry is something that gives an incumbent firm an advantage over a
potential entrant. Barriers to entry can originate from supply or demand conditions,
or from regulation. They need not be the result of a deliberate action by an
incumbent firm.
In the case of airports, the main potential sources of barriers to entry appear to be
natural monopoly characteristics and regulatory constraints.
A number of conditions can generate natural monopoly (box 5.1), but the essence is
that production of the good or service in question by one firm, for a given market
size, is less costly than production by more than one firm. This may change over
time, however, as demand and technology change.
These characteristics affect industry structure, performance and the efficient pricing
of airport services. However, the focus in this section is on the extent to which they
create potential barriers to entry and exit, and thus hinder the entry of potentially
competing airports.
On the supply side, natural monopoly is more likely, and hence potential barriers to
entry are more significant, the greater the requirement for large fixed investments
and therefore the likely economies of scale, and the more significant the sunk costs
or economies of scope.
MARKET POWER OF 97
AIRPORTS
Box 5.1 Conditions for the existence of natural monopoly
A natural monopoly is said to exist if, given the demand for a good, service or facility,
one firm can produce a given set of outputs at a lower cost than two or more firms can.
The basic conditions for natural monopoly generally relate to the nature of costs and
investment — such as investment indivisibilities, economies of scale, sunk costs and,
in multi-product industries, economies of scope.
• Investment is said to be indivisible, or lumpy, when it can be undertaken
economically only in large increments. To the extent that this makes the cost of
establishing a new facility higher than the cost of expanding an existing facility, this
can create an advantage for an incumbent supplier.
• Economies of scale occur when average costs decline as output increases.
Investment indivisibilities can contribute to economies of scale by increasing the
fixed costs of production. Given the existence of scale economies, any potential
competitor would need to capture a large market share, or increase the total market,
to be competitive. However, competition may not be efficient in this setting, to the
extent that one producer can supply the market at a lower cost than two.
• Sunk costs are costs that, once made, cannot be recouped. The extent to which an
investment is sunk cannot necessarily be ascertained at the time an investment is
made. Nonetheless, from the point of view of a potential entrant, the more
significant the amount of immovable, industry-specific investment required to
establish operations, the higher the potential sunk costs if entry is unsuccessful, and
the higher the risk of investment. Exit costs effectively become an entry barrier.
• Economies of scope exist if it is less costly to have one firm supply a number of
products or services than to have each service provided by a different firm. As with
economies of scale, economies of scope can mean that it is more efficient to have
only one supplier of the relevant products.
These factors may be neither necessary nor sufficient for natural monopoly. For
instance, one firm may be able to produce at a lower cost than two or more firms can
produce, given market demand, even if constant returns to scale (where average costs
are static as output increases) or diseconomies of scale (where average costs increase
as output increases) are present at the margin. Further, for a multi-product business,
there could be diseconomies of scope in the production of several outputs — that is,
the cost of one firm supplying all products is greater than what it would cost for firms to
specialise. This could offset the impact of economies of scale in the supply of the
individual product or service.
Even the coexistence of economies of scale and scope does not necessarily imply the
existence of natural monopoly (Baumol, Panzar and Willig 1982), since the concept of
economies of scope does not consider the possibility of two firms producing different
combinations of output. Nonetheless, an appropriate rule of thumb is that natural
monopoly is more likely where fixed costs are large relative to marginal costs (implying
high average costs compared with marginal costs) (King 2000).
Sources: Baumol, Panzar and Willig (1982); King (2000).
98 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
The characteristics of investment and cost structures can differ significantly
depending on the type of airport being considered. The discussion below considers
the situation of airports, such as Australia’s core-regulated airports, that are capable
of servicing regular public transport (RPT) traffic in large jet aircraft.
Construction of a new airport requires the purchase of land and the development of
facilities such as runways, aprons, terminals and processing facilities. To the extent
that the cost of establishing facilities at new airports is higher than the cost of
expansion at existing airports, this can create an advantage for an incumbent airport
operator.
The most significant sources of indivisibility appear to be land and runways. The
costs of procuring the large area of land required to build an airport can be very
high, particularly in larger cities where vacant land close to population centres and
amenities is scarce. This means that any new operator potentially would have to
locate in a position that is less convenient than that of an existing operator, or try to
‘create’ a large area of land by buying up smaller parcels from a number of
owners.1 This latter option may lead to problems such as hold-out by existing
owners. Regulatory and environmental constraints also may create barriers.2
1 Technically, contiguous land is required for infrastructure, such as runways, taxiways, aprons
and some form of passenger or cargo processing facilities. Due to changes in technology,
however, some services, such as check-in, increasingly may be provided at off-airport locations
(chapter 6).
2 Convenience may not necessarily be related directly to distance. A new airport 200 kilometres
south of Madrid, for example, will be only about 50 minutes from the city on a new high-speed
rail link (Starkie 2001a). Similarly, the Eastern Distributor in Sydney has made the airport
‘closer’ to the city by decreasing journey times, and CityLink in Melbourne has decreased
journey times between Melbourne Airport and some suburbs of Melbourne.
MARKET POWER OF 99
AIRPORTS
The indivisibilities involved in constructing other necessary assets for a new airport,
such as terminals and aprons, do not appear to be as significant. Although the
capital expenditure involved may be substantial, these facilities can be designed to
enable incremental expansion when (and if) traffic grows. According to the Motor
Trades Association of Australia Superannuation Fund (MTAA Super Fund):
Runways … come in very large increments. On the other hand, aprons, taxiways,
terminals, car parks are a little less lumpy due to the modular design nature of modern
airports and airports can plan to add on a few extra aerobridges, another baggage
carousel and another acre of car parking every few years. (sub. 22, p. 33)
Where, for various historical reasons (often defence related), there already are a
number of airports in a given location — such as in Melbourne, which has
Essendon, Avalon, Moorabbin and Point Cook airports, in addition to Melbourne
Airport — a potential airport competitor may not need to build a new airport.
Instead, it may be possible to change the capability of an existing airport, say from a
domestic to an international airport, enabling it to compete in a new market
segment.
In this case, the supply-side barrier to entry depends on how extensive the existing
facilities are. For instance, if upgrading the airport would require a significant
expansion of airport land, then entry barriers will be higher. Similarly, barriers to
entry will be higher if a new runway (to accommodate larger aircraft) is required.
On the other hand, the main investment required may be new facilities, such as
passenger processing and customs facilities, in which case the extent of
indivisibility, and hence the entry barrier, will not be as significant.
Economies of scale
Airports often are said to have strong economies of scale, driven by large indivisible
investments such as runways. However, although there are economies of scale in
the provision of runways, there are likely to be diseconomies in other areas, such as
terminal facilities (passenger handling) (Betancor and Rendeiro 1999;
Walters 1978). Thus, the extent of scale economies in overall airport operations
depends on which effect dominates. Difficulties in maintaining access between
Although these results may not hold precisely for Australian airports (given
differences in airport traffic and general economic and regulatory conditions), they
are likely to be indicative of the situation in Australia.
Sunk costs
Sunk costs are investment costs that ‘produce a stream of benefits over a long
horizon but can never be recouped’ (Tirole 1990, p. 308). Generally, they relate to
investments specific to a firm, industry or location — which means the assets either
cannot be moved, or cannot be sold to another party unless that party intends putting
them to the same use, without substantial loss.
Sunk costs often are said to be significant for airports. For instance, the Board of
Airline Representatives of Australia (BARA) commented:
A number of the costs of investing in an airport are sunk once incurred. The costs of
land development, runways and taxiways, aprons and so on are sunk once incurred …
the size of the sunk costs are significant. (sub. 26, p. 9)
Most major airport investment, such as runways, taxiways, and apron facilities, is in
immovable assets, so it cannot be sold for use in another location. As the Australian
Council for Infrastructure Development noted:
With an airport, which is a very, very big sunk cost investment, if the demand
characteristics for your airport change, it’s very hard to dig up the runway and take it
somewhere else where it will be used. (trans., p. 288)
Some facilities at airports potentially may have alternative uses. Office space and
some aspects of terminal facilities, for instance, could be used (if in a modified
form) for general purposes. The development of business parks by some core-
regulated airports (chapter 2) shows that, even though leaseholders must continue to
operate airports on their land, some of the land does have alternative non-airport
uses. Furthermore, speculation prior to the sale of Essendon Airport that it would be
worth up to six times more as a residential development than as an airport
(Davidson 2001) suggests that the opportunity cost of airport land (that is, its value
in alternative uses) is not zero. (Appendix F discusses aeronautical land valuation in
detail.)
Economies of scope
These non-aeronautical economies of scope appear to derive from having one party
— the airport operator — allocate a large terminal space to multiple uses (and from
the benefits to users of having a number of services in the one general area). This
does not mean necessarily that there are benefits from having the airport operator
directly operate all the services provided in the terminal. First, the airport operator
may not have the expertise to operate each component (for example, different types
of retail stores). Second, most non-aeronautical costs are likely to be attributable to
particular uses, so it is feasible to have different parties operate individual services.
According to the MTAA Super Fund:
The costs of non-aeronautical outputs are distinct from, and more closely attributed to,
particular services than aeronautical services costs. That is, their costs can be more
clearly separately identified than are aeronautical services. (sub. 22, p. 33)
Finally, some participants commented that there are economies of scope in the joint
provision of aeronautical and non-aeronautical services. The MTAA Super Fund,
for instance, noted that airports have:
… strong economies of scope due to the co-location of non-aeronautical services
directly relevant to the demand for air travel (car parking and rental facilities) and of
services less directly related (retail outlets and light industrial property) that are
attracted by the passenger flows through the airport or the proximity of customers for
other services (catering for airlines, mechanical workshops for private aircraft).
(sub. 22, p. 33)
There may be some benefits on the supply side of having all these services provided
by, or at least at, the airport. For example, a large area of land is required to operate
Network benefits
The above discussion suggests that some aspects of the supply of airport services
give airports natural monopoly characteristics.
However, as already noted, there are examples in Australia of more than one airport
in a city (due to various historical factors), yet only one is used for domestic and
international passenger traffic in each city. Avalon Airport, for instance, has some
of the necessary aeronautical infrastructure in place (and reasonable access to the
city) to compete with Melbourne Airport. Indeed, currently it is the designated
alternative airport for Boeing 747 aircraft.
This indicates that supply characteristics are not the only factors that can make one
airport dominant in a location. The overall level of demand obviously is another
factor. However, the network benefits that accrue to airlines and their passengers
from using one large facility appear to be particularly important. In effect, there are
economies of scale on the demand side.
The benefits to airlines and passengers of using one airport accrue in a number of
ways. By concentrating services at fewer airports, airlines can use larger (more
economical) aircraft. Passengers transferring between flights benefit from not
having to commute between airports in a city. Thus, the higher the degree of
interconnecting traffic, the greater the preference for using one airport in a location.
Thus, even with a choice of two similar (uncongested) airports serving the same
destination, airlines are unlikely to spread services across both. Furthermore, they
are unlikely to move to another airport in the area unless charges or congestion
costs increased substantially.
Airports in Australia must comply with a number of regulations, both general and
airport specific (chapter 3). Some of these regulations may form a barrier to entry,
interacting with any barriers created by airport costs, investment, and network
benefits.
Clearly, there are significant barriers to entry in the provision of airports. These
arise from natural monopoly characteristics that are reinforced by regulatory
constraints.
That there are natural monopoly elements in the supply of airport services,
combined with preferences on the demand side to use one airport in a given
location, makes it unlikely that a direct competitor RPT airport would emerge in
any city in Australia, given passenger volumes in most airports.3
3 As already noted, although there is more than one airport in a number of capital cities in
Australia, this tends to be the result of historical accident. In any case, only one airport in each
city is used for RPT traffic, despite the availability of the other airports.
MARKET POWER OF 105
AIRPORTS
Considered in isolation, this would appear to give airports in Australia significant
market power.
FINDING 5.1
There are significant barriers to entry in the provision of airports. These arise from
natural monopoly characteristics that are reinforced by regulatory constraints.
Elasticities can provide an indication of the degree of market power a firm has.
High demand elasticities for a firm’s product reflect competition in a market. (A
firm can face a high price elasticity for its product, even where demand at the
industry level is relatively inelastic.) Firms facing low elasticities of demand for
their product have market power since they can increase their price without
significant substitution away from their product.4
As noted in chapter 2, the demand for airport services is a ‘derived’ demand; indeed
it can be considered a ‘derived-derived’ demand. It is derived from the demand for
airline services, which in turn is derived from the demand for travel for business
4 That said, if a firm sets prices to exploit fully its market power, it will increase prices until the
point at which demand becomes elastic. Thus, the demand elasticity measured from a
‘monopoly price’ would give an erroneous indication of the degree of market power held.
Further, if the demand of a firm (that is unregulated) is estimated to be price inelastic, this
could imply that market power is not being fully exercised. Hence, it could suggest that there
may be some constraint on the exercise of market power (assuming the elasticity is estimated
correctly).
106 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
meetings, holidays, visiting friends and relatives (VFR), migration, cargo handling
and so on.
The analysis here considers the demand for the services of a particular airport,
which may be more elastic than the demand for airport services in general. The
discussion focuses on passenger services since much of the freight passing through
RPT airports is carried on passenger flights (Melbourne Airport, sub. 7).
Nonetheless, where appropriate, dedicated freight services (where freight is not
carried in passenger aircraft) are discussed separately.
Since the demand for an airport’s services is a derived demand, its elasticity will be
influenced by four factors:
• the elasticity of demand for air travel to that destination;
• alternative sources of supply for a particular airport’s services;
• the proportion of airfares (or freight charges) and airline costs that airport
charges comprise; and
• the elasticity of supply (supply responses) of other input providers, such as
airlines (box 5.2).
The focus with respect to airports generally is on the third factor — that is, the (low)
proportion of airfares and airline costs that airport charges comprise on average
(discussed below). The lower the proportion of costs that a particular input (such as
airport services) comprises, the lower the elasticity of demand could be expected to
be, all other things being equal (box 5.2).
However, to the extent that the elasticity of demand for the final product is high, or
that substitutes for the input (in this case, airport services) exist, the elasticity of
demand for the input will be higher. This does not mean necessarily that demand for
airport services will be highly price elastic, but that it could be higher than would be
suggested by its cost share alone.
In addition, different segments in the market may vary in their price responsiveness.
The overall demand elasticity for the airport’s services will be a composite of these
different market segments, appropriately weighted. The question is which customers
or segments drive the behaviour of the airport and its ability to increase prices or
otherwise exercise market power. Further, estimated elasticities generally will be
measured at a point on the demand curve. Less appears to be known about the shape
and/or slope of the demand curve for air travel. Elasticities could increase
significantly as prices increase, which could constrain the scope for any large
changes in airport prices.
Proportion of total cost that the price of the productive service comprises
The lower the price of the service relative to the total cost of the final product (that is,
the smaller the proportion of the total cost it comprises), the lower is its price elasticity.
Intuitively, few people are discouraged from buying a final product if the price of an
input that is a small part of total costs increases (even if its price rises significantly and
the cost is passed on fully). However, this factor can be overshadowed if there are
significant alternative sources of supply for the input. Formally, for this condition to
hold, the elasticity of demand must exceed the elasticity of substitution.
The rest of this section considers the importance of each factor in influencing the
elasticity of demand for a particular airport’s services. As for section 5.1, the
108 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
approach adopted here is consistent with the framework outlined by Professor King
(ACCC, sub. 36, attachment C), though its structure differs.
The higher the elasticity of demand of air travel to a particular destination, the
higher the likely elasticity of demand for a particular airport’s services.
Reliable estimates of price elasticities for passenger air travel are difficult to obtain.
As noted by Oum, Waters and Yong (1992), elasticities differ depending on fare
class (business, economy, discount), as well as distance. Problems obtaining data,
however, mean that only aggregate price elasticities tend to be estimated. (One
exception is a recent Australian study (Battersby and Oczkowski 2001), which
attempts to estimate demand elasticities by market segment and is discussed further
below.) Calculated elasticities also tend to be based on some average estimated fare,
rather than actual prices paid, further distorting estimates.
As a result of these problems, estimates vary widely, ranging from -0.4 to -4.51,
with most falling between -0.8 and -2.0 (Oum, Waters and Yong 1992). Although
these results are not unambiguous, the general conclusion seems to be that business
travel is relatively inelastic, while holiday travel is elastic.
Battersby and Oczkowski (2001) focused on demand elasticities for domestic air
travel in Australia. They found that elasticities differed across the four routes
examined, as well as across airfare classes. The estimated price elasticities tended to
be lower than those found in other studies — and were, in fact, inelastic for most
routes and fare classes — but economy fares tended to be the most elastic.
Counterintuitively, there did not appear to be a significant difference between the
elasticity of demand for business compared with discount fares. As the authors
noted, the relatively fixed supply of discount fares, particularly during the time
under consideration (1992–1998), partly could explain this result.
On the other hand, BARA noted that ‘available evidence suggests that demand for
air travel is relatively elastic’ (sub. 26, p. 11). This point was echoed by Qantas,
which ‘believes that air services have a reasonably high price elasticity’ (sub. 48,
p. 18). Virgin Blue also argued that:
Virgin Blue has proven beyond doubt that more people fly if you lower the price, even
by a few dollars. It’s as simple as that. (Huttner 2001)
The price elasticity of demand for international air travel to Australia seems to
follow broadly the patterns found in the international studies. According to the then
Bureau of Transport and Communications Economics (BTCE 1995), foreign leisure
The available elasticity estimates do not, however, indicate the potential price
responsiveness of travellers to all particular destinations in Australia and are of
somewhat limited use in assessing the elasticity of demand for particular airports.
Although Battersby and Oczkowski (2001) examined elasticities for different
routes, they did so for four routes (covering three airports) only, and the model was
based on data between 1992 and 1998 (that is, before the entrance of Impulse and
Virgin Blue).
Given this, it can be more informative to examine qualitatively the factors that
influence the elasticity of demand for air travel to a particular destination. Broadly
speaking, this elasticity will depend on the relative attractiveness of the destination
and the relative attractiveness of air travel to that destination compared with other
transport modes. The impact of these two factors will vary according to the market
segment being served (domestic or international; business or leisure), and whether
the service is freight or passenger transport.
Given that the demand for air travel is derived from the demand for business trips,
holidays and so on (chapter 2), several factors influence the decision to travel to a
particular destination. These include the tourist attractions and amenities in a region,
business opportunities, friends and relatives, and the cost of travel (including the
cost of the journey and living costs while there).
The primary purpose for travel is likely to influence the relative importance of each
factor and thus the extent to which travellers are willing to substitute one destination
for another, or change their frequency of travel. In particular, holiday makers (both
domestic and international) are more likely to have discretion over their destination
than are those visiting friends and relatives or travelling for business purposes.5
Gold Coast Airport commented:
Competition can come in several ways for a leisure destination such as ours … the
tourism market is reasonably fickle. (trans., p. 373)
5 Conference organisers have much more discretion over destination. Thus, this segment of the
business market is likely to be more price elastic than the general business market.
110 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
Other regions within Australia and, in some cases, overseas can be alternative
destinations for Australian and international holiday travellers. As noted by the
ACCC:
… both international and domestic tourists might substitute destination on the basis of
cost differences. For example, a tourist may decide to visit Coolangatta rather than Fiji,
if the cost of doing so is substantially lower. (sub. 36, pp. 62–3)
In addition, even if international holiday travellers have made the decision to come
to Australia, they have choices about which regions they visit within the country,
and about their points of arrival and departure.
Though often seen to be fairly inelastic market segments, there also are some
substitution possibilities for travellers in other categories. For instance, people
visiting friends and relatives may have little choice over destination but do have a
choice about frequency (and possibly transport mode) and therefore may be quite
price sensitive. Business travellers also may change the frequency of visits (or
choose alternative modes, as discussed below). If business travellers ultimately are
selling their products into competitive export markets, then they are likely to be
more price sensitive.
The potential price responsiveness of travellers, both tourists and those visiting
family and friends, was highlighted by Tourism Tasmania:
… Tourism Tasmania’s own TVS Special Fares Survey … covered the period in
September and October 2000 when $55 fares were placed on Melbourne to Tasmanian
ports as well as most other city pairs across the country. The survey showed that
34 per cent of the fares to Tasmania were purchased by visitors who had no plans in the
next two years or more to visit Tasmania and that the primary reason for purchasing the
tickets for 92 per cent was the price of the ticket. Visiting friends and relatives was the
motivation of 53 per cent of those travellers, with the remainder being predominantly
leisure focused. (sub. 13, p. 1)
Overall, although each market segment has some substitution possibilities, these
possibilities are higher for holiday travellers. Therefore, destinations with a greater
proportion of leisure traffic are likely to be more susceptible to competition from
other destinations. On the other hand, the higher the proportion of business traffic,
the less price sensitive travellers to a destination are likely to be (all other factors
being equal).
As can be seen in table 5.1, the proportion of interstate holiday travellers varies
greatly across regions serviced by Australia’s core-regulated airports.
MARKET POWER OF 111
AIRPORTS
Table 5.1 Primary purpose of visit, interstate overnight visitors in
Australia, 1999a
Visiting friends
Destination Businessb and relatives Holiday/leisure Other
% % % %
New South Walesc 20 32 43 6
Sydney 33 34 28 6
Victoria 34 30 34 4
Queenslandd 22 30 45 3
Brisbane 32 32 30 6
Gold Coast 11 24 62 3
Tropical North Queensland 21 23 53 3
South Australiae 36 25 30 13
Western Australia 40 26 37 1
Tasmaniaf 18 22 56 4
Northern Territory 24 13 55 6
ACT 30 34 32 4
a Percentage of all interstate overnight travellers to the destination who go there for each purpose. Overnight
visitors are travellers aged 15 years and over who do not arrive and depart within the same day. Unless
otherwise stated, the source is BTR (2000b). Rows may add to more than 100 per cent because some people
reported more than one purpose for their visit. b ‘Business’ includes conferences. c NSW data are from
Tourism New South Wales (2001) for 1999-00, and refer to domestic (intrastate and interstate) visitors. Main
purpose of visit does not appear to differ significantly between domestic and interstate categories (though the
proportion of business travel is higher for interstate visitors). d Queensland data are from Tourism Queensland
(2000a–d), and refer to domestic (intrastate and interstate) visitors. Main purpose of visit does not appear to
differ significantly between domestic and interstate categories. e SA data are taken from SATC (2001) for
2000. ‘Other’ includes a ’not asked’ category. f Tasmanian data are from Tourism Tasmania (2001) for 2000.
Sources: BTR (2000b); SATC (2001); Tourism Queensland (2000a–d); Tourism New South Wales (2001);
Tourism Tasmania (2001).
In general, the eastern mainland States, as well as South Australia and Western
Australia, have higher proportions of business and VFR travellers compared with
the other destinations considered.6 Also, there are differences in the main market
segments going to different regions within these States. For example, the proportion
of business traffic to Brisbane is significantly higher than to the Gold Coast and
Tropical North Queensland. Likewise, there is more business traffic travelling to
Sydney than the NSW average. Similarly, in the Northern Territory, business or
VFR travellers account for a greater proportion of visitors to the ‘Top End’ than of
visitors to the ‘Centre’ region (NTTC 2000).7 It is likely that such patterns (that is, a
6 The data presented relate to overnight travellers (that is, travellers who do not arrive and depart
within a day), so the proportion of business travellers is understated.
7 NTTC (2000) provides data on the main purpose of visit of all visitors to the Northern Territory
(not separated by domestic and international travellers), by region visited in 1999-00. Overall,
of visitors to the ‘Centre’ region, 77 per cent went for holiday/leisure purposes and 7 per cent
112 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
lower proportion of leisure traffic in capital cities) would be repeated in the States
for which the data are not available.
This suggests that substitution possibilities and hence demand elasticities for
destinations such as Adelaide, Brisbane, Canberra, Melbourne, Perth and Sydney
will be lower than for the other destinations considered — unless business
frequency is price elastic.
This conclusion effectively assumes that the mean elasticity (that is, an elasticity
based on the main market segments served) is an appropriate measure of price
sensitivity. If, however, most marginal travellers come from elastic market
segments, then an increase in prices will result in a larger quantity response than
suggested by an unweighted average elasticity. That said, if these elastic portions
are a very small part of the market, they are unlikely to affect the overall elasticity
significantly.
International travellers primarily come to Australia for a holiday (table 5.2). The
proportion of foreign business visitors tends to be low, with the highest levels
around 14 per cent for Melbourne and 12 per cent for Sydney in 1999. Melbourne
also had the highest proportion of international VFR visitors in that year, followed
by Sydney, Brisbane and Canberra. Differences in the purpose of visit across
destinations within a State do not appear to be significant. Overall, since holidaying
is the dominant reason for international travellers visiting Australia, international
travellers may be more price sensitive as a group than domestic travellers. However,
the fact that international visitors to Australia have little choice but to fly may
reduce their price elasticity of demand for air travel.
each went for VFR and business purposes. Of visitors to the ‘Top End’, 55 per cent went for
holiday/leisure purposes, 17 per cent went for VFR, and 14 per cent went for business
purposes. The proportion of international visitors was higher for the ‘Centre’ than for the ‘Top
End’.
MARKET POWER OF 113
AIRPORTS
traffic volume, premium revenue mix of business and leisure traffic coupled with
significantly greater frequency and volume of air services gives Sydney significant
advantages over Brisbane in terms of obtaining favourable scale, scope and revenue
efficiencies, for passenger air transport. (sub. 6, p. 2)
Factors that influence the decision over mode include the proposed length of stay,
the distance to be travelled, and the relative cost of each mode (both in financial
terms and in terms of convenience and the time taken to travel). As with the
possibility for destination substitution, the primary purpose for a visit is likely to
influence the relative importance of each factor and thus the extent to which
travellers are willing to substitute modes. Of course, the first decision to be made by
potential travellers, regardless of the purpose of travel, is whether to go at all, or
how often to go.
Several inquiry participants argued that the modal alternatives to air travel generally
are weak, mainly due to time savings associated with air travel. The ACCC, for
example, noted the particular importance of time in determining preferences for
business air travel:
For business travellers the convenience of air travel is vastly superior to the
alternatives. It is likely that for this customer group, location is primarily determined by
factors other than airport pricing, and that time constraints are a critical element of the
travel decision. In such circumstances, there are no viable substitutes to flying to a
particular destination; the choice is simply between travelling and not travelling.
(sub. 36, p. 62)
Though not travelling within a particular day is not always a viable alternative for
business travellers, business is not totally unresponsive to costs. It can minimise the
use of air travel in various ways — for example, by scheduling intercity meetings so
fewer trips are required, or by teleconferencing or videoconferencing.
Although videoconferencing can save time and cost less than face-to-face meetings,
it will not always be an adequate alternative. Its adequacy as an alternative will
depend on the nature and expected duration of meetings. It is unlikely to be
adequate if a large group of people who are not well acquainted need to discuss
sensitive issues, for example. On the other hand, a smaller better-acquainted group
discussing routine issues is more likely to find videoconferencing a viable option.
Virgin Blue argued that time also was an important factor for leisure travellers:
… the time to travel between the major airline destinations is significantly longer by
car, bus or train than by aircraft (12 hours compared to an hour and [a] half for
example) … For leisure travellers, the current low fares compare favourably with other
forms of transport, and any overnight stays relating to the time taken by other forms of
transport contribute to the total cost of the holiday. Accordingly, other forms of
passenger transport are not readily substitutable for aircraft travel. (sub. 30, p. 12)
Assessing the time taken to travel by air, however, should include the journey time
from the initial departure point to the origin airport, as well as the time taken to
travel between the destination airport and the final destination point. In the case of
travel between Canberra and some suburbs of Sydney (particularly southern
Sydney), for example, it may be more time effective (even for business travellers) to
travel by car.
In any case, leisure travellers are likely to be far more sensitive to price than to
time, especially compared with business travellers.
• Holidays tend to be longer than business trips so time may not be as critical for
some holiday travellers. They may, therefore, place a greater emphasis on the
generally higher direct cost of air travel.
• The journey to a final destination often can provide value to holiday travellers
who visit attractions along the way. This means that the extra time taken to
travel using modes other than air may not be viewed purely as a cost.
• The use of a car when at the destination often is valued by holiday travellers.
Thus, driving to a holiday destination may provide benefits to counteract the
extra time taken to travel.
Nonetheless, the further the distance between destinations, the less attractive are
alternative travel modes. The ACCC noted two reasons for this:
Firstly, the difference in journey times between air transport and the alternatives
increases rapidly. Secondly, the cost differential between air transport and any
alternative mode of transport may narrow as the distance increases. (sub. 36, p. 63)
Data provided in BTR (2000b) and reproduced in table 5.3 show that interstate
overnight business travellers are far more likely than holiday/leisure or VFR
travellers to use air transport.
For international travel to Australia, there is little option but to fly. The only real
choice about travel mode for international visitors is how to travel between various
regions within the country.
Overall price elasticities of demand for air travel incorporate factors such as modal
substitution. However, given the variety of factors influencing the choice of travel
modes, the price sensitivity of travellers attributable to modal substitution is likely
to differ across Australian cities.
Since holiday travellers are likely to be more price elastic than business travellers,
one way to assess the potential competition that air faces from other travel modes is
by examining which market segments dominate travel to a particular region. Thus,
using the information in table 5.1, it would appear that air travel is likely to face
more intermodal competition (and greater price elasticity of demand) in destinations
such as the Northern Territory, the Gold Coast and Tropical North Queensland,
where holiday travellers dominate.
However, even for holiday travellers, the viability of modal substitutes is dependent
on factors such as the distance between origin and destination. Thus, examining
modal choice to particular destinations can give an idea of the perceived
substitutability of travel modes (table 5. 4).
As illustrated in table 5.4, air travel comprised no more than around 30 per cent of
total interstate overnight trips made to New South Wales and the ACT. The
dominance of private vehicle travel for those visiting the ACT may reflect the high
proportion of visitors from Sydney (and surrounding areas of New South Wales).
As noted above, for these visitors, the time difference between air and road travel
may be relatively low (and may even favour private vehicle in some cases).
MARKET POWER OF 117
AIRPORTS
Interstate visitors to South Australia were also slightly more likely to travel by
private vehicle than by air in 2000. The use of air travel to Adelaide subsequently
may have increased following the introduction of Virgin Blue services (but before
the reduction in Ansett services). However, given that Virgin Blue’s passengers are
likely to have more price-sensitive demands, this would not have increased the
market power of Adelaide Airport.
For Tasmania, however, sea travel often is seen to provide a viable alternative to air
travel. The ACCC, for instance, argued that:
… ferry services connecting Melbourne and northern Tasmania are an attractive
alternative to flying (for many visitors). In this case the demand side substitution
possibilities are much greater than for other capital city airports. (sub. 36, p. 64)
International
Mode of entry Interstate visitors visitors Total visitors
% % %
Air — domestic 52 59 56
Air — international 1 15 8
Coach 6 7 7
Private vehiclea 37 9 24
Rail 2 6 4
Other 1 1 1
a Private vehicle includes 2-wheel drive vehicles, 4-wheel drive vehicles and ‘other road transport’,
which may include hire cars.
Queensland
In 1999, 71 per cent of domestic (including intrastate) visitors to Queensland travelled
by private vehicle, 21 per cent by air and 4 per cent by rail (Tourism Queensland
2000c). The proportion of interstate visitors who travel by private vehicle is lower than
for the domestic total. However, differences across regions are likely to be similar for
interstate and intrastate travellers. Data for three regions are illustrated below (Tourism
Queensland 2000a, b, d).
Tropical North
Mode of entry Brisbane Gold Coast Queensland
% % %
Air 30 20 43
Private vehicle 58 69 47
Otherb 12 11 10
b ‘Other’ includes rail (7 per cent) for Brisbane; bus/coach (5 per cent) for Gold Coast; and rented
vehicle (5 per cent) for Tropical North Queensland.
Tasmania
Approximately 78 per cent of travellers to Tasmania arrived by air in 2000: 44 per cent
arrived at Hobart Airport, 24.7 per cent at Launceston, 5.7 per cent at Devonport, and
3.1 per cent at Burnie (Wynyard). The remaining 22 per cent arrived by sea (most of
those going to Devonport with TT-Line). (Tourism Tasmania 2001)
Sources: NTTC (2000); Tourism Queensland (2000a–d); Tourism Tasmania (2001).
The response of travellers to the reduction of Ansett services in late 2001 may
provide some additional evidence of potential modal substitutability. Anecdotal
evidence suggests that holiday makers were more willing than business travellers to
change transport modes (although business travellers made more use of
videoconferencing) (Heasley 2001). On the other hand, some holiday makers
decided to take holidays closer to home so they could drive to their destination
(indicating destination substitution for leisure travellers) (Innis 2001). Gold Coast
Airport submitted that:
The surveys indicated that because of Gold Coast’s proximity to the major east coast
population centres, many visitors who had booked flights and accommodation chose to
drive or use other forms of transport to complete their holidays …
Surveys undertaken by other State and national tourism organisations indicate that the
experience on the Gold Coast was not evident at the more distant tourism centres such
as Cairns. (sub. DR58, p. 5)
However, what can be inferred from these responses is limited by the sudden and
‘abnormal’ nature of the events.
• In particular, with significantly diminished air capacity, initial traveller
behaviour (particularly in terms of increased rail and coach bookings) was
dominated by those needing to return home. This would tend to overstate the
apparent substitutability of modes compared with what would be observed in
more normal circumstances.
• The large number of holiday cancellations to certain destinations may indicate:
- the inability to change travel modes at short notice — in which case, potential
modal substitutability may be underestimated if, in the medium to longer
term, the length of holidays can be varied to accommodate the use of slower
transport modes; or
- the inherent unattractiveness of using other travel modes to those destinations
— in which case, modal substitutability would be more accurately reflected
in the number of cancellations. Gold Coast Airport noted that ‘as Gold Coast
did receive an increase in new short term bookings during the holiday period
this indicates it could have benefited at the expense of the more distant
destinations because of its proximity to the main population centres’.
(sub. DR58, p. 5)
As with passenger traffic, demand substitution for dedicated freight services (that is,
where freight is not carried in passenger aircraft) can be looked at in terms of
destination and modal substitution. And, as with passenger traffic, the substitution
possibilities are likely to differ between international and domestic freight.
For international freight, the only possible modal substitute is shipping. For the
transport of domestic freight, on the other hand, road, rail or sea may be viable
alternatives.
Not all freight is amenable to transport by air; shipping is the only viable alternative
for some types of international cargo, for example. However, the freight that is
transported by air tends to be highly time-sensitive. As Virgin Blue noted:
The means of freight transport is determined by the required delivery time and
characteristics of the freight item. Air transport is higher cost than other forms of
transport, reflecting its short delivery time. Highly time sensitive freight is typically
only suitable for air transport. (sub. 30, p. 12)
Apart from the time factor, the relative viability of other modes depends on the
extent of infrastructure for other modes, as well as the location of production of the
goods to be freighted. For example, in Tasmania there are sea freight terminals at
Hobart, Launceston and Burnie. In addition, it was noted by Hobart Airport (and
supported by Launceston Airport (sub. 35)) that:
… Tasmanian salmon producers use both sea and air transport. Our advice is that it
costs $2 per case less to transport salmon by road-sea freight from Hobart to
Melbourne, than by air. The other advantage of road-sea freight is that it is a seamless
service from say the salmon factory at Dover in the south of Tasmania, across Bass
Strait, to the markets of South Australia, Victoria and New South Wales. (sub. 11, p. 5)
The possibilities for destination substitution appear to be lower for freight than for
passenger traffic. To the extent that domestic air freight is generally time-sensitive,
it needs to be sent by relatively direct routes to a required destination.
The extent to which alternative airports can compete for air freight (both
international and domestic) is discussed below.
Given that a decision is made to travel (or send freight) to a particular destination,
some form of airport service is required by airlines (and their users). Substitution
possibilities for a particular airport’s services may be available to airlines in terms
of using larger planes or changing the frequency of landings at a particular airport
(and, therefore, shifting some operations to other airports). Virgin Blue highlighted
the potential to substitute airports when, in relation to charge increases at
Coolangatta Airport, it noted that it:
… will have no option but to operate its new Boeing aircraft on routes where the
relevant airports act as responsible members of the community instead of as
opportunistic monopolies. (Huttner 2001)
As noted with respect to modal substitution, although time may be important for
holiday travellers, for many of them it may not be the primary consideration. Thus,
domestic holiday makers are likely to have a more flexible view than business
travellers of what constitutes a proximate airport. This suggests that airports in
destinations with predominantly domestic holiday (or even VFR) travellers are
likely to be more susceptible to competition from nearby airports.8
As discussed above, Tasmania, the Gold Coast, Tropical North Queensland and the
Northern Territory receive high proportions of holiday traffic. Of core-regulated
airports serving these regions, it appears that Launceston, Hobart, Coolangatta and
Alice Springs face effective competition from other ‘nearby’ airports.
Hobart and Launceston face a potentially high degree of competition from each
other. They are just over two hours drive apart, making them relatively close
destinations for holiday — and even VFR — travellers, who are their main market
segments. In addition, since most holiday makers to Tasmania visit more than one
city in the State (Tourism Tasmania 2001), and many travel around Tasmania in
cars, the particular point of arrival is less important than it may be in other States.
Hobart and Launceston airports also face some potential competition for passenger
traffic from Devonport Airport. Indeed, when Kendell Airlines resumed its
Tasmanian service from Devonport Airport, people from around Tasmania,
including Hobart, reportedly travelled to Devonport to take advantage of the low
fares (Barbeliuk 2001).
8 As discussed below, airport charges are a small proportion of airfares. Nonetheless, at the
margin, holiday travellers are likely to be more responsive to any price change. Further, to the
extent that airlines respond to increased charges at one airport by decreasing the frequency of
service, this also may make another proximate airport more attractive to travellers, and
encourage airport substitution.
MARKET POWER OF 123
AIRPORTS
Coolangatta airports as alternative ways of reaching the Gold Coast by air (Gold
Coast Airport, trans., pp. 373–4).
The reaction of Virgin Blue to the proposed 170 per cent increase in aeronautical
charges at Coolangatta Airport (chapter 2), highlighted the potential substitutability
of Brisbane for Coolangatta. For instance, Virgin Blue was reported as saying:
We are bringing thousands and thousands of tourists every week to the Gold Coast
through Brisbane airport. If we can fly into Brisbane for one third of the cost of the
Gold Coast, why would we fly to the Gold Coast? (in Templeton and Mills 2001)
Brisbane, on the other hand, does not appear to face significant reciprocal
competition from Coolangatta Airport. The Qantas Airways website (and in the past
the Ansett website) suggests Coolangatta as an option for some flights to Brisbane.
However, the scale of Brisbane Airport, the extent of business traffic it has, and the
fact that it has a much stronger ability to service international traffic, mean that it is
in a much stronger position than Coolangatta Airport. The ACCC commented:
… while Brisbane is geographically and functionally distinct from Coolangatta, the
reverse does not apply. That is, Coolangatta faces competition from Brisbane, but
Brisbane is not necessarily constrained in its pricing by the proximity of Coolangatta,
given the capacity limitations at the latter. (sub. 36, p. 67)
In the Northern Territory, Alice Springs Airport faces the most substantial
competition from another airport. Many visitors to Alice Springs use the city as a
starting point for their visit to outback areas such as Uluru. The airport at Alice
Springs faces significant competition for this segment of holiday makers from
Yulara Airport, which is much closer to Uluru. Despite higher charges at Yulara
(Northern Territory Airports, sub. 25), Yulara has experienced strong traffic growth
since 1997, in contrast to Alice Springs.
Potential airport substitution for Darwin Airport appears to be lower than for other
NT airports such as Alice Springs. A higher proportion of visitors to Darwin than
other areas of the Territory go for business and VFR purposes (although the
majority still go for holidays). To the extent that these visitors travel by air, the
relative isolation of Darwin means that other NT airports will not be sufficiently
Northern Territory Airports noted that Darwin’s location along the ‘Kangaroo
Route’ means that ‘it is relatively easy for airlines to bypass Darwin if they feel
unhappy with our prices or our service’ (sub. 50, p. 9). It noted further that Darwin
Airport potentially competes for international hubbing traffic with other airports,
particularly in South East Asia (sub. 50). However, it is not clear that these factors
currently act as strong influences on Darwin’s pricing behaviour. The main
potential for airport substitution, then, is from airports within Australia for holiday
visitors who travel to more than one region within the Northern Territory.
It does not appear that the other core-regulated airports face strong competition
from other airports for domestic passenger traffic. As discussed in section 5.2,
although there is more than one airport in some of these cities, such as Melbourne,
the preference of users for using one hub airport means that the others do not
present significant competition.
For international passenger traffic, the ability to substitute points of arrival and
departure within Australia potentially is more significant. According to Bureau of
Tourism Research data, slightly more than half of all international travellers visit
more than one State or Territory in Australia (BTR 2000a, p. 36). Travellers visiting
for VFR purposes are least likely, and holiday travellers most likely, to visit more
than one State or Territory. To the extent that travellers visit more than one State or
Territory, the potential for airport substitution, and hence the elasticity of demand
for international travel to a particular airport, would be higher.
The potential for airport substitution appears to be most significant along the eastern
seaboard. Melbourne Airport noted that:
Whilst Melbourne Airport does not have any concrete evidence, our experience in
dealing with travellers, airlines and tourist authorities suggests … international visitors
tend to be indifferent to their place of arrival and destination but to prefer to arrive and
depart from locations they wish to visit. (sub. 7, p. 10)
Nonetheless, Sydney tends to be the dominant point of arrival and departure for
international visitors to Australia. Over 45 per cent of international arrivals and
departures went through Sydney, with about 20 per cent arriving or departing
through Brisbane and about 15 per cent through Melbourne in 1999 (BTR 2000a).
According to the Queensland Department of Tourism, Racing and Fair Trading:
Many of the Queensland destined passengers are now being routed via Sydney for
reasons of airline economics and not travelling public desire. Sydney is therefore a
‘close substitute’ and dilutes Brisbane’s opportunity to be ‘sole supplier’ of airport
facilities or access. Although Brisbane receives a proportion of short haul international
services, consolidation of the international services, particularly from South East Asia,
via Sydney continues to transport a significant proportion of Queensland destination
traffic. (sub. 6, p. 2)
For dedicated freight (freight that is not carried in passenger aircraft), the potential
substitutability of airports is likely to be greater than for passenger services.
In some cases, there is more than one airport capable of servicing freight traffic in a
particular city. Therefore, potential competition can come from airports within a
city, as well as from airports in another proximate city. In Melbourne, for example,
airports at Avalon, Essendon and Moorabbin all service freight traffic.
In other cases, such as in Tasmania, the proximity of airports in other cities can
make it less costly (and not significantly more inconvenient) to transport goods
between centres by road than by air. As well as indicating intermodal substitution
possibilities, it suggests that the market power of any one airport is constrained by
the potential for its business to be moved to the other centre by other modes. Hobart
Airport commented:
Due to the close proximity of Launceston to Hobart, intrastate and interstate domestic
producers and manufacturers, and exporters, road freight their goods to Launceston
Airport for transhipment by air, due to the cost impact of a 20-minute flight between
Hobart and Launceston, compared to road freight costs. (sub. 11, p. 4)
In addition, the network benefits that lead to a preference for using one airport for
passenger traffic (section 5.2) are not as great in the case of freight in Australia.
This gives airlines more scope to use more than one airport, or shift operations, for
freight services. This seems to be the case particularly for international freight, for
which the most important issue often is to move cargo to (or from) Australia rather
than to a particular city. Melbourne Airport submitted:
Freight service operators seem to be quite willing to change airports, which is a
reflection that their businesses are driven primarily by the task of delivering imports to
Australia rather than to any particular location or the carriage of export freight from a
specific location. This is because what really drives the provision of freight services is
the known availability of high value cargo. It is this preparedness to move coupled with
a general availability of airport capacity that gives airports little market power in
relation to freight services. (sub. 7, pp. 15–16)
The relative importance of airport charges in total airfares can provide an indication
of the potential responsiveness of (prospective) passengers to changes in airport
charges. The relative proportion of airport charges in airline costs, on the other
hand, may give an indication of the degree to which airlines may be willing to
substitute away from an airport’s services in response to a change in airport charges.
MARKET POWER OF 127
AIRPORTS
Each approach provides a different way of examining the potential price elasticity
of demand for an airport’s services.
On average, airport charges tend to be a small proportion of total airfares. The exact
proportion depends on the airport being considered (because charges vary across
airports), as well as the particular airfare in question. Airfares in turn depend on the
route, carrier and other conditions attached to the ticket, such as discounts for
advance purchase.
9 These calculations were based on charges in place before the ACCC-vetted increase in charges
at Sydney Airport, and before the increases at other airports that followed the Commonwealth
Government’s decision to change price regulation in October 2001 (chapter 3). However, given
that average domestic airfares also rose after September 2001, it is not clear exactly how these
proportions would have changed.
10 For example, the minimum (marginal) cost per passenger incurred by Virgin Blue is the
terminal charge. Terminal charges actually paid by Virgin Blue are difficult to ascertain — for
example because rebates may be provided, offsetting notional terminal charges levied. For
illustrative purposes, assume terminal charges of $1.65 per passenger (at each end, GST
inclusive), as allowed by the ACCC for the multi-user domestic terminal at Melbourne Airport.
In this case, terminal charges would comprise less than 1 per cent of Virgin Blue’s highest full
128 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
not likely to be a high proportion of full economy domestic airfares, they are likely
to be more significant for low-fare carriers.
In the absence of substitution possibilities, the fact that airport charges comprise a
relatively low proportion of airline costs12 and airfares suggests that the price
elasticity of demand for aeronautical services could be relatively low.
airfare on the Melbourne–Perth route (as advertised on its website on 11 December 2001), and
up to almost 4 per cent of its lowest airfare on the Sydney–Melbourne route. The cost for the
‘average’ passenger would include this amount plus a proportion of landing charges. A B737
(as used by Virgin Blue) at typical load factors has around 1.5 passengers per tonne
(MTAA Super Fund, sub. 22). Given this, based on the landing charges in place after the
October changes to price regulation and the increase in charges at Sydney vetted by the ACCC
(chapter 2), landing charges per passenger on the Melbourne–Perth route would be about $8.49
(in total, return, GST inclusive); and on the Sydney–Melbourne route about $9.33 per
passenger (in total, return, GST inclusive). For the average customer on these routes, these
estimates suggest that airport charges (incorporating terminal and landing charges) could
comprise about 1.5 and almost 9 per cent of these fares respectively.
11 Charges levied directly by airports in Australia (that is, airport charges) are only one
component of aeronautical charges. Other aeronautical charges incurred by airlines, such as
terminal navigation and rescue service charges — which are levied in Australia by Airservices
Australia, not airports — may be levied by airports in other countries. In addition, as already
noted, airports do not levy domestic terminal charges on airlines that have domestic terminal
leases. Thus, this figure, based on international estimates, may overstate the proportion of
airport charges in the costs of the domestic operations of airlines in Australia.
12 Though this appears to be low, Ansett (sub. 42) noted that an individual input is considered to
be high cost if its total cost represents more than 1 per cent of an organisation’s total costs.
MARKET POWER OF 129
AIRPORTS
As noted above, new entrant airlines are also likely to be far more price sensitive
than the more established domestic airlines. As a consequence, Melbourne Airport
commented:
… an airport that increases its prices is more likely to lose new entrant volume and,
indeed, if an airport is too aggressive with respect to its prices, new entrants may
bypass it much in the same way that international carriers can … The decision that
airports then face is whether to drop price or not to gain business. (sub. 7, p. 14)
Further, as noted in box 5.2, the relative importance of this factor also depends on
the substitution possibilities available to consumers and airlines (discussed above).
Layard and Walters noted:
… the short-run demand elasticity for any airport’s service is quite low, though in the
longer run, of course, other airports can be substituted, and the number of landings per
trip reduced by larger planes, fewer stopovers, and so on. Proportions are likely to be
variable in the long run. (Layard and Walters 1978, p. 262)
As noted in box 5.2, the maximum price that a particular input provider can receive
(for a given level of production) is limited by the amount that consumers are willing
to pay for the final good, and the price that other input providers require for their
own services. Thus, an increase in the price of one input requires an increase in the
price of the final good and/or a lower price being accepted by other input providers.
The lower the ability of other input suppliers to accept a lower price, the greater is
the required increase in the price of the final good and, hence, the greater is the fall
in quantity demanded.
In other words, the elasticity of demand for airport services will be influenced to
some extent by the elasticity of supply of airline services and other input suppliers
to air travel, such as Airservices Australia (ASA). The Commission has been unable
to find literature discussing the interrelationship between airport pricing and the cost
structures of other input suppliers. Therefore, the discussion in this section is
tentative. Nonetheless, it seems clear that the pricing decision of an airport will tend
to induce a supply and/or price response from other input suppliers. This section
briefly examines airline cost and pricing structures, and the charges of ASA.
Broadly speaking, it appears that airlines have decreasing costs, though some
studies have found this to be driven by economies of scope, networks and density,
rather than economies of scale per se (Reed 1999).
It also appears that the cost of carrying an extra passenger on a flight is minimal
(OECD 2000), assuming there is spare capacity.
To the extent that airlines have decreasing costs, the ability of airports to increase
profits by increasing their charges may be constrained. If the consumption of air
travel falls in response to an increase in airport charges, then the unit costs of
airlines also increase, exacerbating the effect on price (and hence quantity
consumed) of air travel.
To the extent that price discrimination is needed to cover the fixed costs of airlines,
the ability of airports to increase charges (or impose other costs on airlines) may be
constrained somewhat. The entry of Impulse and Virgin Blue appears to highlight
the fact that airlines in Australia recently have operated in a competitive
environment and have not been earning returns greater than those of other
competitive parts of the economy. Thus, the price discrimination undertaken by
airlines may indeed be necessary to cover their fixed costs.
Airservices Australia
The other major input supplier to air travel is ASA, the Government-owned
commercial authority that levies charges such as those for terminal navigation,
rescue services and firefighting services (chapter 2).
ASA determines whether the services for which they charge are provided, so neither
airports nor airlines have discretion about whether they are provided at a particular
airport. In addition, the fact that ASA charges are based on projected passenger
throughput in a period means they are effectively fixed charges for that period.
Therefore, any increase in charges (or other costs) imposed by an airport that leads
to a fall in passenger throughput (below the projected levels) also leads to an
increase in the average ASA charge for air travel to the airport. This suggests that
airport operators, particularly at smaller airports, may be restrained somewhat in
their pricing decisions by the fixed quantum of ASA charges.
Given that barriers to entry are likely to be of similar relevance to all RPT airports
(section 5.2), other factors that influence the elasticity of demand for a particular
airport’s services are likely to be the dominant influence on the extent to which
market power differs across airports. A common view is that the elasticity of
demand for airport services is very low, mainly because airport charges comprise a
relatively small proportion of airline costs and airfares. When combined with
natural monopoly characteristics in the provision of airports, this is seen to give
airports a significant degree of market power.
The above analysis suggests that factors other than the proportion of airport charges
in average airfares or airline costs can also be important in determining the elasticity
of demand. The potential for destination, modal and airport substitution has
ramifications for the potential market power of particular airports.
FINDING 5.2
The price elasticity of demand for the services of a particular airport is influenced
by a number of factors. Although the typically low proportion of airport charges in
airfares and airline costs suggests low price sensitivity, this will be mitigated by any
potential for destination, modal and airport substitution, and the supply responses
of other input providers to changes in airport charges.
Airports that face more significant substitution possibilities will face more
price-sensitive demand (and hence have lower market power).
From this analysis, it appears that Alice Springs, Coolangatta, Hobart, Launceston,
and Townsville airports are likely to possess least market power.
• They all serve predominantly tourist markets that face a high degree of
destination substitution.
• Though all these airports are the only RPT airports in their respective cities,
Alice Springs, Coolangatta, Hobart and Launceston appear to face effective
competition from airports in proximate locations:
- Alice Springs from Yulara;
- Coolangatta from Brisbane; and
- Hobart and Launceston from each other.
• Potential competition from other airports does not appear to be significant for
Townsville. However, there appear to be some modal substitution possibilities.
As noted earlier, this does not imply necessarily that the elasticity is high at the
margin. Nonetheless, the fact that it is predominantly a tourist market suggests
that market power would be relatively low.
It is unclear at this stage whether the increase in charges represents the exercise of
market power. Given airport cost structures (particularly at smaller airports), a
significant fall in traffic would increase unit costs. Most airports that have increased
their charges have indicated that the charges will be reviewed in 2002, in the light
of market developments.
The extent to which the price rises might reflect the exercise of market power can
be assessed only in the medium to longer term, when the response of airlines and
their passengers, and the consequent impact on revenues and profits, become
apparent. Ultimately, assessing whether the price increase is efficient requires
examination of whether another operator, charging lower prices, could efficiently
operate the airport on a continuing long-term basis. This cannot be assessed with the
information that is currently available.
It appears that, although they are not immune to substitution possibilities, Brisbane,
Melbourne, Perth and Sydney airports possess substantial market power. In terms of
the eastern capital cities:
• They have high proportions of business and VFR travellers, who tend to have
more price inelastic (and time-sensitive) demands. Business travellers also tend
to be more significant users of air travel than other groups (table 5.3).
- Nonetheless, a fairly high proportion of interstate visitors to eastern States
travels by modes other than air (table 5.4), indicating that modal competition
is strong for at least some market segments.
• They do not appear to face significant competition for domestic passenger traffic
from other airports.
With respect to Perth Airport, the isolation of Perth (and the fact that most visitors
go there for business or VFR) is a significant source of its market power. This is
highlighted by the fact that a very high proportion of visitors arrives by plane
(table 5.4). Westralia Airports Corporation itself accepted that, on the basis of the
high barriers to entry and limited modal substitutes to Perth, it:
… possesses market power in the provision of aeronautical services, but is strongly of
the view that it does not abuse this market power. (sub. 21, p. 30)
In general, any claims of abuse of market power for these airports have related to
specific services. These issues are addressed in chapter 6. Sydney Airport has been
accused of a more general abuse of market power in relation to its 2000 pricing
proposal and, in particular, the size of the proposed increase in its charges. Of itself,
the magnitude of the proposed increase — 75 per cent of which was approved by
the ACCC in May 2001 — does not indicate an abuse of market power, particularly
given the special circumstances of Sydney Airport. Prior to the increase, landing
charges at Sydney were significantly lower than those at any other core-regulated
airport, despite excess demand for several hours a day (and the convenient location
of the facility) (chapter 8). The price increases also reflected a switch from single-
till to dual-till pricing.
For Brisbane, Perth and Melbourne airports, the changes to price regulation
announced in October 2001 allowed a one-off increase to be passed through the cap
(chapter 3). All three applied the allowed increases. Melbourne Airport, for
example, implemented the price increase by rebalancing charges. While domestic
charges increased, there was no net change to international charges (chapter 2).
Given the different natures of the shocks in the two markets — supply side in the
domestic market, and demand side in the international market — this may be an
efficient price response.
The degree of market power held by Adelaide, Canberra and Darwin airports is less
clear. The ACCC (sub. 36) submitted that all three possess sufficient market power
to warrant continued regulation.
Both Adelaide and Canberra have high proportions of business and VFR travellers.
They also do not face significant potential for airport substitution. Nonetheless,
they, and some others such as Melbourne Airport (trans., p. 177), suggested that
Canberra and Adelaide airports do not hold significant market power. Adelaide
Airport, for example, argued:
… we’re not actually a strategic hub base for at least one national carrier, nor is our city
a major economic or cultural capital for our nation here in Australia. Adelaide is very
much of secondary importance to our largest customer groups. These are very
important drivers of market power in our perception. (trans., p. 181)
It also argued that it faces a high degree of modal substitution. BARA (sub. DR54)
and the ACCC (sub. DR55) disagreed, however. BARA argued that:
… for business travellers such substitution is limited (given the time difference
between air travel and road travel between the cities). For the majority of travel
between Adelaide and other cities the substitution is likely to be even more limited. To
assess the degree of modal substitution for Adelaide Airport requires information on
the origin and destination of persons using Adelaide Airport. (sub. DR54, pp. 30–1)
Tourism data suggest that 75 per cent of interstate overnight visitors to South
Australia were from Victoria and New South Wales in 2000 (SATC 2001).
Adelaide Airport Limited (sub. DR77) also noted that the majority of visitors from
these States arrive by surface transport.
Thus, for the major visitor markets to Adelaide — holiday and VFR from Victoria
and New South Wales — the degree of modal substitution may not be insignificant.
On the other hand, modal substitution for business travellers, and those from other
areas, would be fairly low. On balance, the degree of modal substitution for
Adelaide Airport appears to be moderate, which would tend to constrain the
airport’s overall market power.
Capital Airport Group noted that the Canberra–Sydney route comprises about
50 per cent of the airport’s market (trans., p. 463). Although this is likely to be
predominantly a business market, other modes are likely to provide relatively strong
transport options even for this market segment. As already noted, on this route, the
distance between origin and destination is such that driving may be less time-
consuming than flying (taking into account travel time to and from the airports at
both ends). Thus, even some business travellers may find this a close substitute for
air travel. Capital Airport Group contended that:
… the impact of modal substitution on Canberra Airport is at least as great as that
which results from airport substitution possibilities on airports such as Coolangatta and
Launceston. (sub. DR75, appendix 1, p. 1)
That its major market potentially has strong modal substitutes would act to
moderate somewhat the market power of Canberra Airport. This is so even though
its primary market — business — normally is considered a relatively less elastic
market segment. Nonetheless, the overall market composition of Canberra Airport
suggests that it may have more market power than airports such as Coolangatta and
Launceston, which face strong airport substitution possibilities.
On balance, although the market power of Canberra and Adelaide airports does not
appear to be as significant as Brisbane, Melbourne, Perth or Sydney, both airports
appear to have a moderate degree of market power.
Following the Government’s issue of Revocation No. 28 and Direction No. 26,
which together replaced the price cap with price monitoring for Darwin, Adelaide
and Canberra airports (chapter 3), all three airports increased their aeronautical
charges (chapter 2).
As noted earlier, such increases may not, of themselves, reflect the existence and
exercise of market power. Airport cost structures may justify this response to falling
volumes. Only in the medium to longer term will demand responses provide some
indication of the profitability of the change for airports (and, thus, whether the
changes might reflect an abuse of market power).
FINDING 5.3
Of the core-regulated airports, Sydney, Melbourne, Brisbane and Perth have most
market power. Adelaide Airport is likely to have a moderate degree of market
power. Canberra and Darwin airports also are likely to have a moderate degree of
market power, though they appear to face stronger substitution possibilities than
Adelaide Airport.
Core-regulated airports that do not appear to have significant market power (due
mainly — except for Townsville — to the scope for effective inter-airport
competition) are Alice Springs, Coolangatta, Hobart, Launceston and Townsville.
The focus of the above discussion has been on market power at core-regulated
airports. However, a number of participants discussed market power in relation to
other airports — mainly with reference to regional airports in general, though some
airports have been discussed specifically.
Given the number of non-core-regulated airports that cater for RPT traffic in
Australia, this section will focus on general issues relating to regional airports.
Some particular cases mentioned by participants (Cairns and Yulara) are treated
separately.
Despite these differences, it is possible to make some general comments about the
potential market power of regional airports. Some factors may imply the existence
of market power.
• It is unlikely that there would be more than one airport in any particular regional
centre. Although capital investment requirements at regional airports are
significantly lower than those for airports in the major capital cities, the potential
traffic volume through the airport is unlikely to be high in most cases. There also
may be issues of obtaining approval to construct a new airport.
• Most remote locations depend on air transport. As Australian Airports
(Townsville) noted in the case of Mount Isa: ‘We’re talking about a community
of 19 000 people. It relies on the airport as basically its only means of quick
communication’ (trans., p. 7).
However, a number of factors may mitigate the extent and exercise of market power
by regional airports. The importance of air transport to many regional communities
means that the community is likely to take a great interest in the decisions of the
airport and try to exert its collective influence over those decisions.
In addition, with some exceptions, regional airports do not tend to be critical to the
overall operations of airlines, so competitive pressures are unlikely to compel
airlines to fly to many of these airports. In this situation, it is not clear that it is the
airports that have the market power. As noted by the Department of Industry,
Science and Resources:
Airlines can more easily reduce services at smaller regional airports but the commercial
risks of sacrificing access at major city airports would be much higher. (sub. 40, p. 3)
Finally, many general aviation and regional airports in Australia are local
government-owned (chapter 2). Therefore, the users and (direct or indirect)
beneficiaries of the airport’s services are the residents who also indirectly own and
operate the airport through their elected council representatives. Given the
importance of the local airport in many regional communities, and because the
impacts of airport policy are relatively localised, discipline on the airport operator
— the council — to represent the best interests of users could be provided through
the electoral process.
Concerns also have been raised about the extent to which councils use airport
charges to fund general community projects rather than aeronautical uses. Again,
the Western Australian Government stated:
An area of concern to us — as has been shown in other parts of Australia — is that
airport revenue is being used to fund non-airport related plant and infrastructure.
(trans., p. 389)
140 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
Anecdotal evidence suggests that charges at regional airports vary significantly. No
charges are imposed at some regional airports, while charges can be very high at
others. Ansett suggested that ‘a lot of the regional ports have exceptionally high
charges’ (trans., p. 125). Of themselves, high charges do not necessarily indicate an
abuse of market power. The small traffic volumes of most regional airports suggest
that efficient unit costs may be high.
Given the ownership structure of most regional airports, the variation in charges
also reflects local government objectives, which Professor Forsyth noted can be
diverse:
Some local government owned firms may indulge in monument building. On the other
hand, a local government owner may use its airport to attract visitors to the region; if
this is the objective, it will induce the airport to keep costs low and to keep prices in
line with costs. It is also possible that some local governments will require their airports
to maximise profits, so that they can use these to cross subsidise land rates.
(sub. 5, p. 17)
However, if the airport policy of regional councils does not reflect local community
wishes, then this arguably is more properly a local governance issue, not a market
power issue to be addressed by the national economic regulation of regional
airports.
Objectives other than the exploitation of market power also may explain seemingly
high charges at airports located at resorts, for instance. Scott-Bloxam (sub. 2)
submitted that landing charges at Lizard Island were ‘astronomically high’.
Although acknowledging that the maintenance of the sealed strip would be
substantial, he added: ‘I fail to see where a 3 seat Cessna 172 or 5 seat Cessna 206
can attract such high fees other than to discourage their visit’ (sub. 2, p. 1).
If landing charges reflect the high costs of the strip, an objective to keep visitor
numbers low to cater for a particular market segment, or environmental objectives,
then it is not clear that this constitutes an abuse of market power. Further, although
resorts are differentiated from each other, potential visitors have a variety of resorts
from which to choose. Thus, the resort market can be seen as competitive. In this
case, the overall pricing behaviour of a particular resort, including the charges of its
airport (an input to the resort product), would be constrained somewhat by
competition among resorts.
Given that Cairns is a regional airport, much of the general discussion above is
relevant to it. However, Cairns has unique characteristics that warrant further
discussion. In addition, Ansett and BARA pointed to issues in their dealings with
MARKET POWER OF 141
AIRPORTS
Cairns that they argued resulted from its market power. These issues related to the
level of charges, efficiency and degree of consultation. On the other hand,
Australian Airports (Townsville) (sub. 14) argued that it did not believe that
unregulated Queensland airports, including Cairns, had abused market power.
Cairns potentially may have more market power than most other regional airports. It
is the sixth largest RPT airport in the country in terms of passenger movements
(larger than many core-regulated airports (chapter 2)), and is a designated
international airport, suggesting that it has a significant demand base. Indeed,
Australian Airports (Townsville) noted that Cairns is relatively attractive as a tourist
destination compared with Townsville, for instance, ‘which is not as well developed
as a tourist attraction’ (sub. 14, p. 14).
In this situation, the market power of Cairns does not appear to be significant. As
noted by the Department of Industry, Science and Resources:
Airports which primarily service seasonal tourist destinations such as Cairns and
Maroochydore have the least amount of market power. (sub. 40, p. 3)
Given this, to the extent that charges are higher at Cairns than other airports, they
appear unlikely to reflect an abuse of market power. Since the major airlines incur
domestic terminal charges at Cairns, which they do not incur at the core-regulated
airports where they provide these services themselves, the charges at Cairns could
be expected to be higher than those at core-regulated airports.
Further, the Commission understands that landing and terminal charges at Cairns
Airport (exclusive of GST) have not increased since new charges were negotiated in
1990 (although some new charges, relating to Government-mandated security
requirements, for instance, have been introduced). Including GST, current domestic
landing charges are $3.84 per tonne (based on maximum take-off weight (MTOW),
which is lower than the core-regulated airports (chapter 2)), and domestic terminal
charges are $3.84 per passenger. Though terminal charges are higher than those for
some common-user terminals, a more relevant comparison may be the per
Ansett cited its experiences with Yulara Airport as an example of the fact that
‘smaller non-regulated airports are also not averse to exercising their market power’
(sub. 42, p. 27).
However, it is not clear that Yulara Airport has significant market power.
• It may have an advantage as a tourist destination. However, it competes for
visitors with other ‘unique’ destinations.
• The airport is owned and managed by the owners of the Yulara Resort. It is thus
part of an integrated resort operation. Managers may seek to make profits from
the operation as a whole. However, it is likely that this would be done by
attracting visitors to the resort (subject to capacity constraints). In addition, as
noted above, the resort market can be seen as competitive. Competition would
tend to constrain somewhat the pricing of a particular resort, including the
charges of its airport (an input to the resort product).
• The costs of establishing and running an airport in that location are likely to be
very high, especially given the runway requirements for jet aircraft and
comparatively small volumes of planes and passengers.
• To the extent that there is a type of locational rent associated with its location,
this would have been captured by the owner of the site when the lease was
purchased.
5.4 Summing up
The overall market power of a particular airport is encapsulated in the price
elasticity of demand for its services, which will reflect substitutes available to users,
and the share of airport charges in airline costs and airfares.
In addressing the requirement of the terms of reference that ‘future prices regulation
should be applied to those aeronautical services and those airports where airport
operators have most potential to abuse market power’, chapter 5 examined potential
market power of particular airports in Australia. This chapter considers the extent of
an airport’s market power in particular services provided at airports.
6.1 Introduction
It was found in chapter 5 that Sydney, Melbourne, Brisbane and Perth are likely to
have the highest degree of market power of Australia’s core-regulated airports,
followed by Adelaide, Canberra and Darwin, which appear to have moderate market
power. The others — Townsville, Alice Springs, Hobart, Launceston and
Coolangatta — possess little, if any, market power.
The market power of an airport depends on its market power in providing particular
airport services. Although an airport that has market power in the overall market for
airport services must have market power in some of the individual services, this
does not mean necessarily that it has market power in all services provided at the
airport.
In addition, in assessing any evidence of (the use of) market power in particular
airport services, it is important to distinguish between ‘monopoly profits’ on the one
hand and ‘locational rents’ on the other.
• Monopoly profits are profits in excess of the rates of return required to maintain
supply of the good or service.
• Locational rents are returns accruing to a scarce factor rather than returns
deriving from the exercise of market power as such.
To the extent that profits reflect locational rather than monopoly rents, they do not
involve an efficiency loss through distorted supply and demand (appendix C), but
rather reflect the value placed on scarce resources by consumers and provide signals
for their efficient use.
Different classifications of airport services are possible. Those used below broadly
follow the ACCC (sub. 36) and Department of Transport and Regional Services
(sub. 39) approaches.
These facilities are essential to the operation of the airport. Planes arriving at an
airport need a runway to land, taxiways are needed to move aircraft from the
146 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
runway to aprons or parking areas and so on. Airline discretion over aircraft parking
may be higher than for the other components of aircraft movement facilities, to the
extent that airlines have a choice about where to end their services for the day.
Nonetheless, it is likely to be infeasible for airlines to move empty aircraft and
flight crew to another airport simply to minimise parking charges, given the costs
involved. Aircraft parking charges may, however, influence whether airlines choose
to park on the apron or elsewhere at the airport.
Thus, where an airport has market power, its market power in relation to aircraft
movement facilities is high (and effectively equal to its overall market power).
This section examines in two stages the market power held by airports in passenger
processing facilities. The first part explores general issues relating to terminals and
passenger facilities. The second looks specifically at check-in counters, which, for
the airports subject to the price cap, are not included in the cap but are monitored
(chapter 3).
MARKET POWER IN 147
PARTICULAR
AIRPORT SERVICES
General terminal facilities
For the airlines that hold long-term leases over their domestic terminals (chapter 2),
the airlines, rather than the airports, provide many domestic terminal facilities and
services. In this case, BARA noted:
… the service provided by the airport is access to space adjacent to the runways and
taxiways upon which the terminal is located. (sub. 26, p. 4)
On the other hand, domestic new entrant airlines have relied on airports for direct
provision (and construction) of common-user terminal facilities.
The extent of airport market power in these services will be determined by the
degree of discretion that airlines have over what is to be provided, the ability to
build new facilities, and opportunities for off-airport provision of the services.
Australian Airports (Townsville) argued:
Passenger processing facilities … may be used selectively by the customers and can be
provided to the level of quality to meet the customers and end consumers needs.
(sub. 14, p. 17)
The ability and willingness of airlines to tailor passenger processing facilities to the
needs of their customers has been highlighted in Australia by the domestic new
entrants. Terminals built to accommodate them have been more spartan than those
of the established airlines. In addition, the preference of Virgin Blue not to use
aerobridges shows that some of the facilities do not need to be used at all.1 Airline
discretion about the extent of these facilities will vary depending on the main
market segments they serve.
Where on-site expansion is feasible, issues appear to relate to access to airport land
to build facilities, or disagreements between the airline and the airport about the
type of facilities that should be built. For instance, Impulse Airlines noted that
‘there are issues in terms of what we think should be a standard of terminal
supplied’ (trans., p. 40). Virgin Blue also argued that:
Where new facilities are required, in Virgin Blue’s experience, some airport operators
are not willing to be flexible about the standard of terminal facility which Virgin Blue
is able to access. (sub. 30, p. 9)
1 However, where there is apron congestion, the choice of whether to use aerobridges is limited.
148 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
In addition, Virgin Blue (sub. 30) submitted that it offered to construct a terminal at
Melbourne Airport, and provide access to other entrants, but was refused by
Australia Pacific Airports (Melbourne) (APAM, the operator of Melbourne
Airport), which decided to build its own common-user terminal. Following
negotiation over the terms on which access would be granted to the terminal on a
long-term basis, Virgin Blue made an application for an access determination under
s. 192 of the Airports Act 1996 (chapter 9).
In its report for the ACCC in relation to the Virgin Blue determination, Network
Economics Consulting Group (NECG) commented that:
… the fact that the owner of the existing terminal is also the owner of all the land in the
surrounding vicinity is highly relevant. We believe that Melbourne Airport would have
strong incentives to deter entry by a potential competitor in the market for the provision
of terminal facilities … the new entrant could easily find that it becomes uneconomic to
duplicate the existing terminals. (NECG 2001b, p. 46)
However, it is not clear that the difficulties in the Virgin Blue–Melbourne Airport
negotiation process demonstrate an abuse of market power by the airport. Airports,
including Melbourne, appear to have been eager to attract the business of new
entrant airlines (who have sought new facilities from airports, rather than seek
access to existing terminals operated by other airlines).
The problems that arose in this case seem to have stemmed primarily from a
difference of opinion about what was appropriate and required. This seems to be an
inherent problem of common-user facilities, rather than an issue of market power. It
also must be noted that negotiations with Impulse over the same terminal were
successful. Impulse Airlines noted that:
… we signed a commercial agreement with Melbourne Airport … on a struck
passenger charge, which we thought was fair to get the facility built. (trans., p. 40)
Check-in counters
As already noted, for the airports subject to the price cap, check-in counters are not
included in the cap but are monitored (chapter 3).
The degree of market power held specifically in check-in counters depends on the
degree of discretion airlines have over what is to be provided, the ability to use
other facilities on-airport, and opportunities for off-airport provision of the
facilities.
Sydney Airports Corporation Limited (SACL) argued that airlines have a choice
about the quantity of check-in facilities used, limiting the market power of airports:
If charges for use of check-in counters were considered to be too high, airlines would
choose to manage their passengers through a smaller number of counters. (sub. DR62,
attachment A, p. 1)
Slower passenger processing also could be against the airport’s interests. SACL
noted that the use of fewer check-in counters ‘would clearly also be a concern for
airport operators in managing terminal congestion’ (sub. DR62, attachment A, p. 1).
In addition, slower processing times would decrease the time that passengers have
to shop in airport retail outlets. These factors could, therefore, offset incentives the
airport operator otherwise may have to increase, above efficient levels, the charges
imposed on airlines for check-in counters.
Nonetheless, some participants argued that the potential for off-site check-in
currently is limited in Australia. BARA, for instance, commented that:
It is possible that a few of the larger hotels may establish these facilities. However, they
would only cater for a small proportion of passengers. There is no central point where a
large number of passengers congregate (such as a train station). Electronic check-in is
unlikely to be effective as most international passengers have baggage. The scope for
supply-side substitution is extremely limited. It is highly unlikely that a significant non-
transitory increase in charges for check-in counters would have much effect on the
supply of off-site facilities. (sub. DR54, p. 28)
Lounges are not necessary to airlines or their passengers in the way that aircraft
movement and some passenger processing facilities are. Nonetheless, they are part
of the service offered by many airlines. The degree of market power that airports
hold in the provision of these services depends largely on the extent to which
airlines have discretion over the quantity and quality of lounge space that they use.
The behaviour of new entrants in the domestic market appears to show that lounges
are largely discretionary. Hobart Airport noted that:
… Impulse and Virgin are providing evidence that lounges aren’t necessary in the
scheme of things so I’d argue that we don’t have market power in those areas.
(trans., p. 328)
BARA (sub. DR54) argued that the degree of discretion over lounges is not the
relevant question. Rather, the issue is whether there are substitutes that constrain
airport pricing for that service. As discussed in section 6.1, airport pricing can be
constrained by a range of potential alternatives, including the availability of off-
airport and on-airport substitutes or suppliers, and/or the intensity of demand
preference for that service (that is, the degree to which that service is required by
users).
Given that airports have control over access to areas near the gates, it was argued
that they have market power in the provision of this space, enabling them to extract
monopoly rents from airlines (BARA, trans., pp. 223–4).
Alternatively, the apparent strategic requirement for airlines to have lounge space
could be used by airports as a bargaining tool in trying to resolve other issues with a
particular airline. BARA argued:
… the airport may deny or artificially delay access to space in a terminal required to
provide an airport lounge in order to achieve a commercial advantage in other areas
(for example, to resolve a dispute with the airport user). (sub. 26, p. 3)
Though this is possible (perhaps even likely), it is unlikely that this type of
bargaining strategy is the preserve of airports. In the past, for instance, airlines
apparently have refused to lease space pending resolution of disagreements
elsewhere.
Further, the price of those facilities may just reflect the opportunity cost of that
space for the airport — that is, rentals the airport could earn from any other
competitive activity, such as retailing. According to SACL, ‘airlines generally
prefer windows overlooking the airfield, and locations near departure gates’
(sub. DR62, attachment A, p. 1). Given this preference, and the fact that such space
is scarce, the opportunity cost may be high. Thus, prices for lounges may reflect a
locational (scarcity) rent. Moreover, since the space has a number of uses, it is
unlikely that airports would have an incentive to leave some of it unused
deliberately, except for future operational uses. The key issue, then, would appear to
be whether overall terminal space is constrained — that is, whether expansion is
delayed so that scarcity rents can be earned. According to Hastings Funds
Management:
To date Melbourne Airport has concluded a number of successful negotiations in
relation to international lounges … with no charges of abuse of market power.
(sub. 19, p. 5)
In sum, although certain customer segments may expect business and VIP lounge
space from their airline, and this space must be located at the airport, airlines appear
For present purposes, landside vehicle facilities can be seen as falling into two
broad categories: facilities (such as landside roads) that provide vehicle access to
the airport and its terminals; and vehicle services provided landside (such as car-
parking services and taxi waiting areas).
Airline passengers and other airport users (including staff) obviously require access
to the airport and its terminals. And, ultimately, only the airport operator can
provide such access.
Airline passengers choose the means by which they obtain this access, whether it be
in private vehicles, rental cars, taxis, buses, or trains. The operators of these arrival
modes, such as taxi drivers and rental car operators, have a choice about whether
they operate at the airport at all. However, the importance of airport-related
business to their overall business influences to a large extent the degree to which
airports have, and could exercise, market power in their dealings with them. In this
regard, the Australian Taxi Industry Association noted that airports are the largest
single market for the taxi industry (sub. DR61), while the Victorian Hire Car
Association (VHCA, sub. DR68) noted that airport transfers accounted for at least
80–90 per cent of the gross income of hire car operators.
Melbourne Airport also accepted that ‘it has a degree of market power with respect
to the kerb in front of the terminal complex’ (sub. 7, p. 72) and noted the
The mere fact that there are charges for competing services does not necessarily
justify charges for kerb use. Charges on competing services may reflect the exercise
of market power. Nonetheless, pricing access to ease congestion may be efficient,
assuming the airport operator does not constrain artificially the availability of kerb-
side roads.
That said, an airport operator may want to shift demand for vehicle facilities to
services provided more directly by the airport, such as car parking (as discussed
below).
Capital Airport Group (sub. DR75) denied that airports have this incentive. It
suggested that, on the contrary, it has tried to improve, not limit, the access of
transport modes to Canberra Airport. It pointed to its negotiations with the ACT
Government for the removal of Government restrictions on independent (non-
Government) bus operators and a second taxi cooperative servicing the airport.
Given this, it submitted that it:
… rejects the suggestion that it would attempt to limit access for land transport
operators under reasonable terms and conditions in order to prop up car parking
revenue. (sub. DR75, p. 6)
Nonetheless, to the extent that an increase in access charges for competing modes
shifts demand (and raises the airport’s overall revenue), there may be an incentive
for an airport operator to set excessive access charges. Thus, airports have, and may
exercise, market power in the provision of vehicle access facilities.
Car parking
Two forms of car parking are provided at airports: facilities for passengers or those
meeting passengers, and facilities for staff parking.
The ACCC (sub. 36) argued that all travellers require land access to the airport and,
although several arrival modes are available, airport market power in relation to
those alternatives gives airports market power in the provision of car parks. It also
noted that it had found evidence in its assessment of Sydney Airport’s pricing
proposal that car parking is a service ‘in which airport operators have a significant
degree of market power’ (sub. 36, p. 87).
MARKET POWER IN 155
PARTICULAR
AIRPORT SERVICES
However, other participants — such as BAC (sub. 8) and the Australian Council for
Infrastructure Development (sub. 28) — argued that airports do not have market
power in the provision of car-parking services. They cited competition from other
modes and off-airport facilities as effective constraints on any potential airport
market power. Melbourne Airport noted:
Less than 20 per cent of passengers using Melbourne Airport use car parks provided by
Melbourne Airport. In addition to the three public car parks provided by Melbourne
Airport, Qantas and Ansett provide valet parking and there are at least 6 off airport car
park operators. Thus in relation to car parks, airports have little market power …
(sub. 7, p. 72)
Examples of rates charged for on- and off-airport car parking at and near Melbourne
Airport are provided in box 6.1.
The direct supply-side substitution possibilities for short-term car parking appear to
be more limited because proximity to terminals is likely to be more important for
those using short-term than for those using long-term parking. Nonetheless, other
providers may emerge — for instance, Delta operated short-term parking near
Melbourne Airport (chapter 9), and some other off-airport operators advertise that
they provide short- and long-term parking (box 6.1). Further, rates for short-term
parking will be constrained to some degree by those set in the more directly
competitive long-term parking market. The influence of long-term rates on short-
term rates is likely to be strongest for the longer periods in the short-term car park.
Nonetheless, there also is likely to be some (if more limited) flow-through to shorter
stays.
In addition, unlike long-term parking, many of the users of short-term parking are
not airline passengers, but those meeting passengers or driving them to the airport.
They have some options about whether to use airport car parks — dropping people
off without parking, or arranging to pick them up outside terminals, for instance.
The latter has become more viable with the increasing use of mobile phones,
allowing passengers to call ‘greeters’ to pick them up as soon as planes land.
Melbourne and Perth airports, for example, note on their websites the possibility of
setting down and picking up passengers kerb-side. Airports tend to impose
conditions on this, such as limiting the time allowed, or stating that cars must be
attended at all times (for security as well as operational reasons). In addition, Perth
Airport has free five-minute parking in its car park, which would seem to be
designed to encourage the dropping off and setting down of passengers.
Nonetheless, to the extent that airports have market power in car parking, it is likely
to be higher in short-term parking. Indeed, a study of parking at San Francisco
Airport (Kanafani and Lan 1988) found that demand for short-term parking was
inelastic, with elasticities higher for long-term parking. Although the authors noted
that these results may not hold generally, the study suggests that the market power
of airports may be higher in short-term than long-term parking.
Has the behaviour of airports indicated or reflected market power in car parking?
Participants cited high airport car-park prices and profits as potential indicators of
the exercise of market power — for example, the ability of Sydney Airport to levy
and sustain charges in excess of potential competitors (ACCC, sub. 36). However, it
is not clear that the Sydney Airport charges cited by the ACCC — around $13 per
day for long-term car parking, compared with off-airport charges of $10 per day —
reflect market power. It is more likely that the charges largely reflect the greater
convenience of parking closer to the airport. In other words, they may reflect
locational more than monopoly rents — that is, the value placed on the scarce
resource by consumers, not scarcity created by the airport operator (appendix C).
Further, it appears that providers of long-term car parking offer somewhat
differentiated products (in terms of rate structures and services offered (box 6.1)),
complicating comparisons of on- and off-airport car parking rates.
At a more general level, high short-term parking rates sometimes are cited as an
indication of abuse of market power. As noted above, airports are likely to have
more market power in short-term parking than in long-term parking. Thus, these
parking rates could partially reflect the exercise of market power.
However, there also are likely to be locational rents associated with the provision of
space close to terminals. In addition, the opportunity costs of having to maintain
space that may only be used for intermittent periods may be relatively high.
Although this car space may be used later in the day, there may be periods when it
is not used, and this opportunity cost would be reflected in the price. This may
explain, to an extent, the relatively high hourly rates in short-term parking, not only
at the airport but also at most CBD car parks.
Some airports (such as Sydney and Melbourne) have indicated that their car-parking
rates are based on benchmarks, such as CBD parking rates. Some participants
suggested that using such benchmarks is indicative of the use of market power.
Professor Forsyth argued (and the ACCC (sub. 36) agreed):
If rents are true locational rents, the seller does not set the price with reference to
benchmarks (of questionable relevance); rather, the seller takes what the market offers.
(sub. 5, pp. 30–1)
However, the use of benchmarks does not, of itself, indicate an abuse of market
power. First, it is unlikely that a true monopolist would need to use a benchmark at
all. Second, in practice, the discovery of the ‘market price’ is an iterative process
that may be assisted by the use of a benchmark.
One crucial issue is whether airport operators have restricted investment in car
parking to increase prices. Since privatisation, several major airports have
undertaken and/or plan major car-park expansion. Melbourne Airport, for instance,
plans to expand car parks during 2001-02 (chapter 2). To the extent that significant
expansion of car-parking space occurs, this would not appear to be consistent with
monopoly pricing behaviour, unless demand were expanding more rapidly.2
Although expansion could coexist with ‘monopoly pricing’, this does not appear to
have been the case.
BARA (subs 26 and 41) noted that staff car-parking charges at Sydney Airport
recently increased significantly. BARA questioned whether these increases were
justified though it acknowledged that, of itself, an increase of such proportions does
not necessarily represent an abuse of market power. Prices could be expected to
reflect the opportunity cost of the land, as well as operating costs. It may be that
starting prices were inefficiently low.
• Some of the former staff car-parking area was converted to aprons, suggesting
that the opportunity cost of the space was high and, hence, that initial prices
might have been low.
2 As noted above, car parks do not appear to be natural monopolies (the costs of establishing car
parks appear to be modest). Therefore, it is unlikely that an airport operator would increase
capacity strategically to stymie competition from other potential providers.
MARKET POWER IN 159
PARTICULAR
AIRPORT SERVICES
• SACL argued that even the new prices do not allow full cost recovery (SACL,
pers. comm., 25 July 2001). If this were the case, this would suggest that the
prices do not reflect an abuse of market power. The ACCC does not appear to
have raised concerns about the price increases under its monitoring function.
Further, the market power of Sydney Airport in staff car parking may be reduced by
off-airport parking that is of comparable convenience to the SACL facility (SACL,
pers. comm., 25 July 2001). In addition, at the time of the price increase, the train
link to Sydney Airport might have provided a potential substitute for driving to, and
parking at, the airport for workers.
Some participants also suggested that airport market power in car parking could be
exercised by limiting access to the airport by companies that provide competing
services. As BARA commented:
… although an airport may lease the management of on-airport car parking facilities,
the airport nevertheless has an incentive to deny or limit access to the airport of off-
airport parking companies (such as valet parking companies). Such a strategy will
increase the demand for the on-airport parking services and increase the value of the
car park lease. (sub. 26, p. 3)
As noted above, because the airport operator has sole control over access to the
airport, there may be an issue relating to access by competing modes.
The changes to price regulation did not alter the regulatory treatment of car parking,
which remained monitored, for these airports. This does not mean necessarily that
the price changes did not reflect the exercise of market power, simply that changes
to price regulation did not alter the ability of airport operators to exercise it. Costs
also are unlikely to have changed immediately after the regulation was revised, so
cost changes would not appear to have driven the changes in rates.
The significant decrease in some long-term parking rates at Perth Airport generally
would not be seen as an abuse of market power. Very low prices — if they were
significantly below the costs of providing the service — could sometimes be seen as
predatory pricing. Testing for predatory pricing is not easy. Although a number of
rules have been suggested in the literature, they can be difficult to apply and there
does not appear to be one test that is applicable in all cases (Ordover and Saloner
1989). Nonetheless, in general:
Markets in which predatory conduct is rational are characterized by imperfect and
asymmetric information, scale economies, intertemporal and intermarket cost and
revenue linkages, barriers to entry and reentry, etc. (Ordover and Saloner 1989, p. 591)
These conditions do not appear to characterise the market for airport car parking.
The nature of the restructure at Perth may suggest a form of price discrimination.
Where market power is likely to be more significant — short-term parking — rates
increased. Rates fell where competition is likely to have the most significant effect
— long-term parking and long periods in short-term parking.
Overall, airports appear unlikely to have significant market power in long-term car
parking. The market power of airports in car parking is likely to be higher for short-
term and possibly staff parking, but there also are factors mitigating the extent of
market power in these facilities. For example, because many of the users of short-
term car parks tend not to be passengers, alternatives to using the car park are
available.
To the extent that airports have market power in car parking, it is likely to be
constrained as long as landside access for competing operators (of other travel
modes, such as taxis, and competing off-site parking services) is available on
reasonable terms and conditions.
Airports provide a number of facilities for taxi services — such as parking areas for
waiting taxis and, in some cases, queue management systems (although taxi
companies operate these at some airports). Airports also provide areas for taxi ranks
for arriving and departing passengers.
Travellers and taxi drivers have some discretion over their use of these facilities.
Passengers can choose to travel to and from the airport using modes other than
taxis. Taxi drivers who transport passengers to the airport need to use designated
sites. However, they have a choice about whether they pick up passengers from the
airport. Anecdotal evidence suggests that many drivers who take people to an
airport then move on to other nearby areas rather than wait to collect another airline
passenger. In this case, they do not need to use queue management or taxi parking
services.
Nonetheless, to the extent that taxis and passengers use taxi services, there are no
on-site alternatives to the airport-provided (or approved) queue management
system. Viable off-site alternatives also appear limited, although it may be possible
to provide holding bays adjacent to, but off, the airport site. In addition, as already
noted, there may be issues as to whether an airport may wish to use its control over
landside access to shift demand to airport-provided car parks etc. There may,
therefore, be some access issues related to the provision and pricing of these
facilities.
Since privatisation, four core-regulated airports have levied some form of taxi
charge. Of these, only Melbourne linked the charge to a necessary new investment
proposal (submitted after the Federal Court ruled ground access fees at Canberra
Much of the debate over the charges has surrounded the issue of whether they
should be included in the price cap. This rests primarily on the question of whether
they should be considered charges for access to ‘landside roads’. Discussion of this
issue is contained in appendix E. In this section, consideration is given to the issue
of the extent to which the levies charged may reflect an abuse of market power.
Because the precise nature of the levies has differed across airports, it is difficult to
make a general judgement about whether their imposition reflects an abuse of
market power. Nonetheless, some general issues can be noted.
As discussed above, airports have control over the provision of landside access. To
the extent that the charges can be considered access charges, they are charges for
services for which airports have market power.
The Federal Court decided that the charges imposed by Capital Airport Group were
charges for access to landside roads.3 However, this decision was made in the
specific context of charges imposed by Canberra Airport, and the definitions
contained in the regulation of the time.
Airports have argued that taxi charges should be seen as charges for facilities
provided, or concession charges such as those for retail space. WAC, for instance,
argued that:
… the ground facilities fee is not a levy on taxis or any other commercial vehicles for
access to the airport. The fee puts in place an equitable system of charges at the airport
for all businesses that derive revenue from the airport market, and is consistent with
charges levied on car rental operators that are in place and not regulated. Ground
facilities fees are commonplace at airports elsewhere in the world, reflecting the
principle that those who benefit from the airport’s growth, should contribute to its
revenue base. (sub. 21, p. 23)
3 The Federal Court found in a ‘line ball’ decision that the ground access charges at Canberra
related to landside roads. An appeal by the Capital Airport Group subsequently was dismissed
(appendix E).
MARKET POWER IN 163
PARTICULAR
AIRPORT SERVICES
That airports in other countries impose these fees does not, of itself, mean that their
imposition is not an abuse of market power. There are other reasons, however, that
may suggest that these charges are not entirely charges for landside access.
The charges tend not to be levied on taxis setting down passengers, so they are not
levied for all taxi access to the airport.
Thus, charging for these services does not, of itself, reflect an exercise of market
power. Indeed, Melbourne Airport contended that it was subsidising taxi services by
not imposing charges:
We deliberately took the decision, unlike many other airports, not to impose a taxi
charge; to keep on wearing that subsidy ourselves for as long as we possibly could.
(trans., p. 170)
Given that both parties benefit in some way from the taxi management system, it
may be optimal for some sort of cost sharing to occur. What is an optimal
proportion of costs to be shared by each party may change over time.
Hence, even if there is no increase in costs (for example, due to new investment),
imposing a new charge, or increasing an old charge, does not reflect necessarily an
abuse of market power.
The ACCC (sub. DR55) argued that, for passengers leaving the airport, access to
the kerb-side is, of itself, insufficient since taxi parking/waiting areas are required
for departing passengers. However, this is not necessarily the case at all airports. At
Canberra Airport, for example, if there are no taxis in the feeder ranks, a taxi that
has set down a passenger can pick up others directly at the rank, without incurring a
charge (Capital Airport Group, sub. DR75, appendix 5). Though not currently used
as an option, it also may be possible to have taxi waiting areas outside the airport,
with passengers able to call for a taxi when their plane arrives.
The Victorian Hire Car Association (VHCA, sub. DR68) suggested that Melbourne
Airport has significant market power in the provision of access to its members. It
cited in particular its experience in relation to the imposition of the annual ‘Vehicle
Driver Authority’ fee and charges for hire car parking (and the way in which these
were implemented).
It also noted changes to the configuration of feeder ranks (which took place under
the Federal Airports Corporation (FAC) in 1992) as a demonstration of:
… Melbourne Airport’s ability to effectively control the nature of the hire car
operators’ physical access. (sub. DR68, p. 5)
The VHCA added that the airport operator reduced physical access for its members,
and that there is a:
… strong incentive for Melbourne Airport, in the absence of restraints, to increase
charges and promote more revenue positive suppliers to service this market.
(sub. DR68, p. 11)
The importance to hire car operators of revenue from the airport may make them
less able to oppose price increases. However, the fact that they are operating on
small margins and the apparent price sensitivity of their customers (VHCA,
sub. DR68) also mean the operators will be very sensitive to price increases. The
VHCA itself acknowledged that ‘hire car operators are … sensitive to minor cost
changes’ (sub. DR68, p. 8). This could diminish the market power of airports. That
the VHCA was successful in modifying Melbourne Airport’s original fee proposal
to one more palatable to its members appears to illustrate this.
Aircraft obviously need fuel but airlines do not necessarily need to refuel each time
they land. For larger jets on domestic short-haul flights, airlines may have some
discretion over where they refuel. The ACCC noted that ‘to minimise airlines’
running costs, aircraft generally do not carry more fuel than necessary. As such,
aircraft often refuel upon each landing’ (sub. 36, p. 82). Nonetheless, some
discretion remains.
Over longer distances, including long-haul international flights, on the other hand,
refuelling must take place at each landing. In this case, discretion over refuelling at
a location is limited to the decision of whether to fly to a particular airport at all.
Therefore, the market power an airport holds in these facilities depends on whether
there are off-airport alternatives and the degree to which refuelling can take place at
other airports can be substituted for refuelling.
For larger airports, there appear to be limited off-airport alternatives for refuelling.
• Trucking fuel from off-site to refuel aircraft at large, and often busy, airports
will be considerably more costly to airlines.
• Safety requirements may preclude trucking as a practical option.
• The alternative of aircraft taxiing to the airport boundary to refuel from an off-
site facility would not be an economic or practical option. As the ACCC noted,
‘This effectively limits the extent to which potential entrants can compete
against the airport for the provision of refuelling services’ (sub. 36, p. 82).
The viability of airport substitution for refuelling varies according to the airport and
route being considered. If, for example, an aircraft operates Sydney–Melbourne–
Canberra–Sydney, it may be possible to choose not to refuel at one of those airports.
On the other hand, for aircraft flying between Perth and the eastern seaboard, it is
4 At smaller airports, where the volume of fuel throughput is lower, arrangements may differ. At
Hobart, for example, the trucking of fuel to the aircraft is the means by which refuelling takes
place. However, the airports where this occurs are those assessed in chapter 5 as not having
market power, so this method of refuelling does not apply to the airports assessed in this
chapter.
166 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
uneconomic not to refuel at each port. Likewise, for international flights, aircraft
must be refuelled at each landing. Qantas, in its submission to the ACCC review of
fuel throughput levies, noted in respect to Brisbane and Perth airports:
The only alternative to purchasing fuel from those oil companies is to bring fuel on to
the airport by land transport or refuel at other airports and carry the additional fuel to
Brisbane or Perth. Either alternative is uneconomic and would increase the cost of fuel
to Qantas by 1 to 2 cents per litre and the cost of flying to those ports even more.
(sub. to ACCC 1998b, p. 6)
The other airports may have a less significant degree of market power in the
provision of domestic refuelling facilities. For Melbourne Airport, the proportion of
its traffic generated from shorter routes, particularly Sydney–Melbourne, is far more
significant than from longer routes such as Melbourne–Perth and Melbourne–
Brisbane (chapter 2). Darwin would have a relatively high proportion of longer haul
traffic, so is likely to have market power in refuelling equal to its overall market
power. Apart from having a lower degree of market power overall (chapter 5), most
traffic through Canberra Airport is generated from short-haul routes, further
diminishing its degree of market power in refuelling. Adelaide also is likely to have
a lower degree of market power in refuelling, given its lower market power overall.
That said, airports that have market power are likely to have at least a moderate
degree of market power in the provision of aircraft refuelling services. Indeed,
Melbourne Airport noted that ‘a case can be made that there is market power with
At larger airports, oil companies pay licence fees and rent to the airport operator for
use of the land. A fuel throughput levy has been imposed, in addition to the land
rental, at Brisbane and Perth airports.5 The imposition of the fuel throughput levies
has generated a significant amount of debate, particularly about the extent to which
they reflect an abuse of market power and hence should be considered
‘aeronautical’. The International Air Transport Association noted that:
… airlines recognise, and accept, that charges and/or fees may be levied for the fuel
services required and used to support their operations, but believe that such activities
should be treated as ‘aeronautical’ in nature. (sub. DR56, p. 9)
The issues are outlined briefly in this section and in more detail in appendix E.
The airports involved contended that the fact that they were simply exercising a
contractual right to impose the levy meant that they had not abused market power.
BAC, for example, argued:
BACL strongly refutes any suggestion that it has abused its market power because it
‘activated’ a fee covered by an existing contractual arrangement and determined as
reasonable by an independent expert. (sub. to ACCC 1998b, p. 5)
Neither BAC nor WAC, in their submissions to the ACCC, attempted to justify the
fuel throughput levies on the grounds of increased costs, the provision of additional
services or offsetting reductions in other charges. Thus, the ACCC concluded:
When considered in light of the lack of any cost related justification for the levies, or
offsetting reduction in charges, there is a strong case that the imposition of a fuel
throughput levy is taking advantage of market power. (ACCC 1998b, p. 7)
If the imposition of the levies had been justified on cost grounds, claims of abuse of
market power would have been more difficult to substantiate. Nonetheless, a lack of
cost justification does not, of itself, indicate an abuse of market power, either. It
may be that the previous charges were at inefficiently low levels, in which case,
there did not need to be an increase in costs to justify an increase in charges.
The critical issue, then, relates to whether the charges — of 0.4 and 0.5 cents per
litre for Brisbane and Perth respectively — were above efficient levels. On the basis
of the evidence provided to the ACCC review, it is difficult to ascertain whether the
charges exceeded an efficient level. The levies resulted in an increase in total
revenues derived from refuelling services, but the review presented no information
on expected normal rates of return from refuelling facilities. BAC contended that
the charge was a ‘reasonable market rate’ with reference to fuel throughput levies at
airports in other countries. This was supported by the determination of the
‘independent expert’, a Queen’s Counsel jointly appointed by the parties (BAC,
sub. to ACCC 1998b). Of course, the fact that fuel throughput levies are charged in
other countries may simply reflect the exercise of market power by airports in those
countries.
In its submission to the ACCC review (quoted above), Qantas implied that it would
not be economic to switch to refuelling at airports other than Brisbane and Perth
unless the levy increased to above 1–2 cents per litre. A monopolist maximising
profits may, therefore, be expected to charge a fuel throughput levy of up to 1–2
cents per litre without losing business. The fact that airport operators are charging
considerably less than this amount could indicate that there are economic, political
and/or legal constraints on their ability to maximise profits by abusing market
power, or that a more gradual approach to changing charges is preferred given the
sensitivity of the issue.
On balance, the extent to which airport operators have abused their market power is
unclear. Contractual rights are not evidence one way or the other, and the lack of
MARKET POWER IN 169
PARTICULAR
AIRPORT SERVICES
cost justification for imposing fuel throughput levies does not necessarily indicate
an abuse of market power. Moreover, the extent to which the levies are in lieu of the
rent component and/or exceed, if at all, an efficient price is not known. That said,
because these airports do have fairly high degrees of market power in the provision
of refuelling, the potential for abuse remains.
Nonetheless, the Department of Transport and Regional Services (sub. 39) argued
that airport market power in the provision of light maintenance is low since airlines
and third parties, rather than the airport itself, provide the services on a contract or
fee for service basis.
If this is the case, any market power of airports would relate to the provision of
access to the third parties who directly provide the service. Qantas submitted that:
In order to provide these services, maintenance workers require access to land within
the airport, and aircraft parking space on which to conduct the maintenance. The airport
is a monopoly provider of these access rights and aircraft parking locations.
(sub. 48, p. 16)
It also is feasible for these facilities to be located off the airport site or at nearby
‘secondary’ airports. Melbourne Airport, for example, noted that Ansett had
‘significant maintenance facilities located just beyond the airport boundary’
(sub. 7, p. 68). And the ACCC commented:
It may be feasible for such facilities to be located near the airport site, as long as
aircraft operators have access on reasonable terms to a road or tarmac suitable for
moving aircraft from the airport to the off-site heavy maintenance facility. For
example, Avalon Airport has heavy maintenance facilities which service Qantas
aircraft. (sub. 36, p. 82)
Ansett noted that competition between locations for heavy maintenance facilities is
driven mainly by competition between governments, not airports:
In Ansett’s Australian experience, whilst airports may offer some incentives to base
facilities such as these at their airport, generally, the greatest source of competition and
MARKET POWER IN 171
PARTICULAR
AIRPORT SERVICES
incentive packages is between State Governments (due to the employment and state
based investment generated etc) rather than the airports in question. (sub. 42, p. 17)
This, in the short term, may give the airport at which the facilities are located some
market power. Nonetheless, when negotiating the contract for heavy maintenance
facilities, airlines also could negotiate long-term pricing and service agreements for
other airport services to cover a period that would allow them to recoup heavy
maintenance establishment costs. This would reduce the market power of the
airport. Overall, it appears that the market power of individual airports for heavy
maintenance facilities is negligible.
Even where they are required, there appear to be viable supply-side substitution
possibilities. As the ACCC (sub. 36) noted, the required infrastructure does not have
high sunk costs, nor do all airports need to have flight catering facilities. Further,
meal preparation can occur off-site, with food transported to the airport. Melbourne
Airport noted that:
Sites for catering facilities may also be provided by the airport but in the case of Gate
Gourmet, the largest independent caterer operating at Melbourne Airport, their kitchens
are located at a location near to but off the airport. (sub. 7, p. 68)
172 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
In this case, the market power of airports appears to be negligible, as long as access
to the airport is provided.
The ACCC suggested that access for food transport has been an issue in one case
since privatisation. It submitted that:
In 1999 the Hyatt Hotel complained to the ACCC about Canberra Airport’s imposition
of an increase in their licence fee of some 800 per cent to transport food prepared in an
off-site facility to Qantas aircraft. The charges are now substantial. (sub. DR55,
attachment D, p. 4)
The Capital Airport Group (sub. DR75), however, argued that this was not an issue
of airport market power. It noted that the structure of the fees changed at this time.
Initially, the charge, as levied by the FAC, was applied on a fixed fee plus
percentage of turnover basis. In 1999, as a result of negotiation between the airport
and the Hyatt, the percentage of turnover component was removed, and the fixed
component increased by 250 per cent. However, as a result of the change to the fee
structure, the total charges incurred by the Hyatt Hotel fell. The licence fee
increased again, when ownership of the caterer changed. This second rise meant
that the total increase in the fixed licence fee between 1999 and 2001-02 was about
700 per cent (Capital Airport Group, pers. comm., 26 November 2001). The total
charges for the new caterer, however, also appear to be lower than they would have
been under the former fee structure.
Although airport operators could limit access, it does not appear that access for
flight catering facilities has been an issue to date.
Ground service and freight handling equipment are used frequently, and their
storage is essential to airlines. Storage sites require some area of pavement (with
flood lighting), and could include freight or passenger aprons or hard stands.
Determining the market power of airports for these storage sites requires an
assessment of the extent to which they can be located off-airport, and the extent to
In assessing the Australian Cargo Terminal Operators access case (chapter 9), the
National Competition Council (NCC 1997) argued that off-airport storage of freight
handling equipment is technically possible but commercially infeasible, given the
additional costs it would impose on users. Off-airport storage also would reduce
operator efficiency and flexibility.
On the other hand, in submissions to this inquiry, airports argued that they do not
exercise market power in storage sites, and that economic barriers to entry are not
significant. Melbourne Airport, for instance, noted that:
Terminal operators, handling agents and airlines store a good proportion of this
equipment on their leased premises. The remainder is stored in common ‘GSE’ areas
on or adjoining aircraft parking aprons free of charge … some users have approached
Melbourne Airport seeking to pay for dedicated sites … There is currently no abuse of
market power here and little likelihood as long as land for leased sites remains
available. (sub. 7, p. 73)
WAC argued that, though it charges for these sites, these charges comprise a small
portion of its aeronautical revenues, and furthermore:
The adequate supply of airside land at PIA [Perth International Airport] provides
incentives for WAC to encourage take-up of these facilities. (sub. 21, p. 31)
Overall, it appears that issues in relation to freight handling and ground service
equipment storage sites are predominantly access related. The ACCC (sub. DR55,
attachment D) suggested that airports may inhibit access to these facilities. It based
this on the Australian Competition Tribunal’s finding that:
In the present matter SACL does want to deny access, or at least regulate access,
because it appears to want to control and decide itself who shall operate ramp handling
services at the airport. (ACT 2000, para. 12)
It seems reasonable, however, that airport operators would want to regulate access
to their site, particularly for safety reasons. It does not appear that they currently
have an incentive to exercise market power per se in providing access to these
facilities.
In its assessment of the Australian Cargo Terminal Operators case, the National
Competition Council also concluded that it was economic to duplicate a site off-
airport, as long as there was vehicle access to the airport. Indeed, the ACCC noted
that off-airport duplication ‘freely occurs’ (sub. 36, p. 84).
Therefore, it appears that airport market power in the provision of freight facility
sites and buildings is negligible.
Technically, as with the provision of other services that require access to the airport
site, the airport operator could exercise market power by restricting access to the
airport. The airport operator is unlikely to do so in the case of waste disposal
facilities (although it could award contracts for waste disposal to a monopoly
provider).
Participants (airlines, airports and the ACCC) agreed that airlines need some form
of office space at airports. There was, however, disagreement as to the discretion
There also has been disagreement over the extent to which office rentals at airports
reflect abuse of market power. Hastings Funds Management, for instance, argued
that office rents at Melbourne Airport have not been increased since privatisation
‘despite the capacity to do so’ (sub. 19, p. 5). In contrast, Virgin Blue argued that
‘APAM’s [Melbourne Airport’s] charges for … office space rental … are
substantially above commercial market rates’ (sub. 30, p. 17).
Even if office rentals appear significant, the question is whether these reflect
locational or monopoly rents. BARA (trans., p. 224) argued that they reflect
monopoly pricing, not just locational rents. Professor Forsyth noted that:
… if airports are setting rents for terminal space with reference to benchmarks such as
rents in the CBD, this is symptomatic of use of market power. (sub. 5, p. 30)
However, as noted above in relation to car parking, to the extent that benchmarking
is used, this does not imply necessarily that market power is being abused.
Melbourne Airport (sub. 7) commented that users compete for terminal space that
has alternative operational or commercial uses. On the other hand, Qantas noted:
… offices for airlines … tend to be in areas which by and large the alternate use is not
retail. They tend to be right up the top in the gods, rather than areas sitting out on the
finger where you would be competing with retail. (trans., p. 264)
On balance, it appears that, although airlines require some office space, discretion
over the amount procured at airports is fairly high, and airport market power is
moderate at most.
Several factors appear to constrain the market power of airports in the provision of
retail and commercial space. First, apart from some last-minute purchases, in most
cases, visitors to an airport do not have to make retail purchases there.
Second, when leasing space to businesses, airports compete with other providers of
retail space, such as shopping centres. With regard to commercial space outside the
terminal, for example, a discount store announced in October 2001 that it was
relocating its premises to Brisbane Airport. One of its directors noted that other
developers wanted to provide them with the space they needed, but that BAC
offered the ‘quality product they needed for the long-term expansion of their
operations’ (Sommerfeld 2001).
Competition in product markets would put a ceiling on the rent a tenant can afford
to pay, while remaining viable. Some airports have retail pricing policies to ensure
that prices charged at airports are not higher than at equivalent locations. The retail
pricing policy at Melbourne Airport, for example, specifies that tenants must
charge: no more than the lower of the manufacturer’s recommended retail price, or
the price charged by comparable retail outlets; or no more than the off-airport store,
if the concessionaire operates an outlet off-airport (sub. 7, appendix 4).
Thus, retail rents at airports would reflect locational, but not monopoly, rents
(appendix C). Melbourne Airport argued that:
… expansions of space must — quite obviously — be carefully planned and integrated
into the logistics of the airport. When licensing to our concessionaires, no undertaking
is made not to build more retail space.
Accordingly it seems reasonable to conclude not that commercially imposed limitations
on space drive up prices at the airport, but rather that the location drives up the value of
sizes that can be hosted there. In this sense, as Kahn reminds us, prices determine the
rents that can be charged — not rents prices. (sub. 7, p. 3)
The Commission has not received evidence to indicate that retail rents at airports
reflect monopoly pricing.
Overall, it appears that airports have little, if any, market power in the provision of
retail space. They compete with other providers of retail space, they do not appear
178 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
to restrict retail space, and consumer purchases at airports are largely discretionary.
Retail rentals at airports appear to reflect locational rather than monopoly rents.
6.14 Summary
The degree of market power held by airports differs depending on the service being
considered. The results of the analysis in sections 6.2 to 6.13 are summarised in
table 6.1.
The highest degree of market power is held in facilities that are necessary to users
and for which the supply-side substitution possibilities are limited. Thus, where
airports have market power, that power is most significant in aircraft movement
facilities, vehicle access, some forms of passenger processing facilities and aircraft
refuelling. With respect to aircraft refuelling, market power is most significant at
those airports, such as Perth, that have a high proportion of long-haul flights.
Market power is least significant in facilities or services for which users have
discretion over the quantity or quality purchased and/or there are significant supply-
side substitution possibilities. These include aircraft heavy maintenance facilities,
flight catering facilities, freight and ground equipment storage sites, freight facility
sites and buildings, waste disposal facilities, administrative office space, and
commercial and retail activities.
FINDING 6.1
For those airports with a moderate to high degree of market power, the extent of
market power varies across the services provided. It appears to be most significant
in aircraft movement facilities, vehicle access, some forms of passenger processing
facility and aircraft refuelling. With respect to aircraft refuelling, market power
appears to be most significant at Brisbane, Perth and Sydney airports.
Where other providers potentially compete with the airport in the provision of
services, access may be an issue if these providers require access to the airport site.
Revenues from duty-free shopping and other retailing, car parking and property
developments are a large and increasing part of airport revenues. Table 7.1
CONDUCT OF 181
UNREGULATED
AIRPORTS
compares average earnings per passenger movement1 (profit before abnormals,
interest, tax, depreciation and amortisation (EBITDA)) from non-aeronautical
activities and aeronautical activities at core-regulated airports for 1999-00.2 As
noted in chapter 2, some differences across airports reflect different organisational
arrangements, and non-aeronautical revenue for all core-regulated airports includes
lease payments received for domestic terminals operated by airlines.
4 That is, provided airports do not constrain artificially the provision of space for non-
aeronautical facilities, profits earned from providing such space will reflect the inherent
scarcity of land proximate to airside activities.
5 To the extent that profits from non-aeronautical activities derive from the exercise of market
power, the efficiency loss arising from monopoly pricing in these activities must be balanced
against any efficiency gain from reducing aeronautical charges. However, as discussed in
chapter 6, evidence suggests, for most activities classified as non-aeronautical, that the degree
of market power held by the airport is likely to be low. It should also be noted that, because
economic efficiency can be enhanced by complementary pricing of aeronautical services, this
does not imply that single-till regulation (which, at the limit, involves a transfer of all locational
rents) must promote efficiency further (appendix C).
CONDUCT OF 183
UNREGULATED
AIRPORTS
downward pressure on profits that arises when increased air traffic volumes are at the
expense of lower prices for the use of runways and terminals … In other words,
airports have good reason to limit the extent to which they exploit market power.
(Starkie 2001a)
While the data in table 7.1 indicate the overall significance of non-aeronautical
earnings to airport operators, to gauge possible implications for unregulated
aeronautical pricing, several qualifications are in order.
• The earnings per passenger reported are average, rather than marginal net
earnings. Though some non-aeronautical revenues are raised in a way that is
directly related to additional passenger throughput (for example, retail
concession fees), some are not. Hence, average non-aeronautical earnings may
overestimate earnings per additional passenger.
• The classification of earnings into aeronautical and non-aeronautical in part
reflects current regulatory arrangements. Estimates of non-aeronautical earnings,
for example, include lease payments for the space occupied by domestic
terminals operated by airlines. If these terminals were operated by the airports,
then terminal charges would be classified as aeronautical revenues. (Offsetting
this, however, the airport would then directly earn revenue from any non-
aeronautical activities conducted within the terminal.) In addition, some
aeronautical-related revenues included in these non-aeronautical estimates may
contain elements of monopoly rents though, as discussed in chapter 6, market
power in most non-aeronautical activities appears to be low.
• Some fixed costs may be included in cost estimates. This would mean that
reported average earnings will tend to underestimate marginal earnings. On the
other hand, some costs excluded from EBITDA calculations may be marginal
costs (for example, some depreciation).
On the other hand, Virgin Blue passengers, on average, are also likely to be far
more responsive to airport charges, as noted in chapter 5. This means that even if
Virgin Blue passengers do spend relatively small amounts at airports, airports could
still increase their profits by targeting reductions in aeronautical charges.
Airports will have an incentive to target aeronautical price reductions to the more
profitable passenger groups. (Tretheway (1996) noted that Vancouver Airport
linked into airline loyalty programs, awarding frequent flier points to car parkers.)
An airport also will have an incentive to offer price discounts only to marginal
flights/passengers to retain infra-marginal profits from aeronautical services.6
Where an airport faces capacity constraints, or the price sensitivity of demand for
aeronautical services is very low, it will have little incentive to reduce aeronautical
charges because this would merely serve to reduce profits. Sydney Airport (at least
until the events of September 2001) appeared to have excess demand for slots for
several hours a day. Sydney Airport is unlikely to offer incentives at peak times. It
6 Network Economics Consulting Group (ACCC, sub. DR55, attachment C) commented that, if
airports were effective price discriminators, then the scope for non-aeronautical profits to
temper aeronautical prices would be weakened. This would not appear to the case, however.
Scope for non-aeronautical profits at the margin would increase incentives for the airport to
price discriminate and thus expand throughput further. At any rate, if airports can price
discriminate effectively, the efficiency effects of monopoly pricing are reduced or eliminated
by the price discrimination.
CONDUCT OF 185
UNREGULATED
AIRPORTS
does, however, offer substantial discounts to ‘new’ off-peak services (Sydney
Airports Corporation Limited (SACL), sub. 27).
If passengers are relatively more sensitive to quality than price, then an airport may
attempt to attract passengers (and airlines) by improving quality. They may use, for
example, non-aeronautical earnings to finance capacity- and quality-enhancing
aeronautical investments (which, in turn, generate more non-aeronautical revenues).
Melbourne Airport commented that ‘high levels of customer satisfaction drive
greater turnover of discretionary expenditure in airports and this is highly
profitable’ (sub. 7, p. 9).
Apart from off-peak discounts at Sydney Airport, the Commission understands that
several core-regulated airports have offered assistance (pecuniary and non-
pecuniary) to both domestic and international carriers to increase scheduled flights.
Kuala Lumpur International Airport is reported to have waived landing and take-off
fees for flights with more than a 25 per cent load factor, in order to boost traffic
(Cheesman 2001).
However, given price caps on aeronautical prices (under which prices have
continued to a significant extent to reflect the Federal Airport Corporation’s (FAC)
single-till pricing), scope for general aeronautical price reductions is likely to have
been limited. Airports also may be disinclined to reveal discounts because of:
• the impact on their commercial relations with other airlines;
• a concern that being seen to be pricing below the cap for some users may lead a
regulator to set a lower cap in subsequent regulatory periods; and
• commitments regarding non-discrimination between international carriers.
BARA (sub. 41) commented that even with the influence of non-aeronautical
revenues, in the absence of price regulation, aeronautical prices are likely to be
significantly higher than current levels.
Taking the second point first, as noted above and in appendix C, the Commission
acknowledges that non-aeronautical profits will moderate stand-alone profit-
maximising aeronautical prices only if such profits are strongly linked to
aeronautical throughput and if such throughput is responsive to (effective) price
reductions. In the Commission’s assessment, evidence of incentives being offered
by airports to encourage additional services at the margin (with and without price
caps) suggests that most airports consider that airlines are responsive to such
incentives. This fact, combined with evidence that a substantial proportion of non-
aeronautical revenue is linked directly to passenger throughput, suggests that
airports will have an additional incentive to encourage passenger growth by offering
price reductions and other incentives.
As to the magnitude of the effect of such incentives on prices, the absolute size of
any price reduction will be a function of the absolute size of the marginal profits
from non-aeronautical services. The effect in percentage terms on aeronautical
prices will depend on the (unconstrained) market power of the airport in
aeronautical services. This, in turn, will depend on the elasticity of the demand
function for aeronautical services at that airport.
NECG suggested that non-aeronautical profits will have only a modest effect on
profit-maximising aeronautical prices because non-aeronautical profits are likely to
be small relative to potential monopoly profits in aeronautical services. In addition
to an apparent assumption that demand for aeronautical services is unresponsive to
price changes over a wide range, this assessment appears also to be premised on a
view that non-aeronautical profits will be low because non-aeronautical services are
subject to competition.
Even for those airports that the Commission has found to have significant market
power (chapter 5), demand is unlikely to be ‘extremely insensitive to price’ as
asserted by NECG (ACCC, sub. DR55, attachment C, p. 11). Though the major
market segments for these airports are likely to have relatively inelastic demands,
CONDUCT OF 187
UNREGULATED
AIRPORTS
even consumers in these market segments have substitution possibilities. Elasticities
could increase significantly as prices increase, constraining the scope for any large
changes in airport prices. Put another way, the demand curve facing airports may
not be very steep over the entire range.
The Commission agrees with NECG that most non-aeronautical services (car
parking, retailing and so on) are supplied under reasonably competitive conditions
(chapter 6). However, the airport derives rents from these activities not by
restricting their supply to raise the price of the relevant services, but because airport
land suitable for these potentially valuable activities is inherently scarce. Evidence
suggests that associated locational rents, linked to passenger volume, are substantial
in total and at the margin at the major Australian airports.
FINDING 7.1
Demand for a particular airport’s services is derived from the demand for air travel
to that destination. The demand for air travel, in turn, is derived from the demand
for business meetings, holidays, family visits and so on to that destination/region.
Airports therefore are susceptible to changes in the relative attractiveness of the
community and region they serve. Thus, though airports’ market power, to a large
extent, relies on the relatively small effect of an increase in airport charges on ticket
prices, as small links in a very long supply chain, airports may have some incentives
to cooperate with other providers (for example, in the tourism and aviation
industries), especially when this cooperation is likely to reduce demand uncertainty.
For airports that serve very large population centres and a variety of market
segments (for example, business, domestic and international air travel), the effects
of a downturn in one market segment may be cushioned by other, more resilient,
segments. Nonetheless, as discussed above, large capital city airports appear to
derive particular profit from spending on non-aeronautical services by international
To the extent that airports seek to cooperate with others in the supply chain, and
governments, to encourage increased tourism and air travel, it is unlikely they
would undermine this medium- to long-term growth strategy by setting very high
airport charges. The Motor Trades Association of Australia Superannuation Fund
(MTAA Super Fund) observed that:
A catch-phrase might be ‘airports do not compete, destinations compete’. A city such
as Brisbane, bidding to host a major conference or event is pitting its package of
airport, hotels, conference facilities and entertainment against the packages from
competing destinations, not only in Australia but around the globe. The airport, as a
facilitator of tourism and trade must remain competitive to ensure success.
(sub. 22, p. 36)
It also is interesting to note that several State Governments submitted that they had
developed cooperative relationships with capital city and regional airports in order
to develop air services to their regions.
CONDUCT OF 189
UNREGULATED
AIRPORTS
The Queensland Department of Tourism, Racing and Fair Trading (DTRFT) noted
that:
There is active realisation amongst most operators that airports are derived demand
assets and are not an end in themselves, but rather an access point to a region or
destination …
DTRFT is an active partner with a number of these airports in Queensland and jointly
develop detailed business cases to develop air services to these and other regional ports.
(sub. 6, p. 4)
That privatised airports have sought and maintain such relationships does not sit
well with them exploiting whatever market power they may have.7 Of course, some
airports may consider factors affecting their long-term growth potential to be
outside their sphere of influence. In these circumstances, whether the outlook is
optimistic or pessimistic, they may have little incentive to cooperate with other
providers or to temper their pricing today with a view to longer-term pay-offs.
This issue has elicited diverging views from inquiry participants. On the one hand,
several airport operators argued that airlines possess significant market buying
power. On the other hand, airlines submitted that the absence of alternatives has
meant that they have little ability to influence prices of aeronautical services.
According to Adelaide Airport Limited (AAL):
Adelaide Airport Limited is not able to abuse any market power that it may have in the
domestic market as AAL’s main customers, Qantas and Ansett, hold significant
7 It is feasible that an airport with market power could cooperate with other providers and
organisations to increase demand in order to charge higher prices and earn higher monopoly
profits. But once that strategy became apparent, it is unlikely that the cooperation would
continue.
190 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
countervailing market power. Put simply, Qantas and Ansett are much more important
for Adelaide Airport than Adelaide Airport is for Qantas and Ansett. (sub. 20, p. 1)
Similarly, Capital Airport Group (trans., pp. 299–301) cited its difficulties in
negotiating agreements with Ansett and Qantas at Canberra Airport to illustrate the
airlines’ countervailing power.
Airlines presented a contrary view. BARA argued that ‘airlines have little or no
economic countervailing power when negotiating over airport charges’ (sub. 41,
p. 16):
The primary determinant of the relative bargaining strengths of the parties is the value
of their outside options. That is, the difference between the profits each party will
achieve with and without the transaction being completed.
International airlines make significant investments in developing international routes. A
decision by an international airline to commence services to and from Australia and to
and from a particular city in Australia involves significant investments. For example,
airlines incur costs in identifying a new market opportunity and establishing the
business case to fly there, dealing with regulatory requirements, establishing a physical
presence which involves establishing offices and recruiting and deploying staff,
establishing a sales and distribution network, and promoting the new route. Airlines
usually incur losses in the early period of the new route’s existence, in the expectation
that these costs will be recouped as the route’s popularity grows. Many of these costs
are unrecoverable if the airline decides to discontinue the service. (sub. 41, p. 16)
Qantas Airways (trans., p. 262 and sub. 48) and Ansett (sub. 42) made similar
claims, with which Professor Forsyth agreed:
Essentially, to run the countervailing power argument, the user has to have a good
alternative to the product on offer, so if Ansett wants to fly into Melbourne, to have
countervailing power it has to have a very good alternative that it can switch to fairly
readily and that’s usually not the case in Australia. It can be the case in Europe or in
parts of the US but not in most parts of Australia. (trans., p. 59)
There are several means by which large airport users may influence airport pricing
decisions. The main economic weapon for large buyers is the withdrawal or threat
of withdrawal of part or all of their demand for the seller’s product. Exercising
CONDUCT OF 191
UNREGULATED
AIRPORTS
countervailing power essentially involves game playing between the protagonists
and requires the ability to undertake or threaten behaviour that in the short term is
not profit-maximising (that is, profits are forgone by not engaging in potentially
profitable trades) in the expectation that this will deliver a more profitable, long-
term outcome (a better price or service).
Aeronautical services, the area in which airports are most likely to have potential
market power, are also the activities where airports face the most concentrated and
financially-powerful users. Nonetheless, as noted by Professor King:
The existence of a single significant buyer does not automatically create countervailing
power … To determine if countervailing power is relevant, the analyst needs to
consider the bargaining position of buyers and sellers. In particular, it is important to
consider which parties will lose most from any failure to reach an agreement to trade
the relevant product. For countervailing power to exist in a market that otherwise is
deficient in competition, any losses from a break-down in bargaining need to be
predominantly borne by the seller. (ACCC, sub. 36, attachment C, p. 13).
There are several indicators of the relative strengths of the bargaining positions of
airlines and particular airports. They include the following.
• The options available to airlines and airports in a particular situation. If there
are other airlines ready to enter routes that become vacant, then the
countervailing power of airlines will be weak. If there are few alternative airlines
One difficulty in assessing the extent of airlines’ countervailing power is that there
is no history, under private ownership, of unregulated operation of major Australian
airports and there are few lightly-regulated private, overseas airports. The
experience of regulation of airports in New Zealand — a regime that was in part
predicated on a view that airlines possess countervailing power sufficient to offset
market power of airports — provides some insights (chapter 11 and appendix G).
Notwithstanding some deficiencies in that system, major airports and airlines have
agreed on price changes and airlines ‘have demonstrated a willingness to withhold
airport payments and to consider court action’ (CC 2001b, p. 76).
CONDUCT OF 193
UNREGULATED
AIRPORTS
opposing increases in aeronautical prices, airlines generally have operated within
this framework rather than exercising any countervailing buying power that they
may possess. The form of commercial relationships between airports and airlines is
evolving slowly from the earlier model of a government authority dealing with a
protected domestic airline duopoly.
Some inquiry participants (for example, Forsyth, sub. 5) suggested that significant
price rises at Sydney Airport (‘not disapproved’ by the ACCC in April 2001)
confirmed the absence of airline countervailing power. However:
• these price increases were coming off the very low base of FAC single-till prices
(chapter 8); and
• the price increases were ‘not disapproved’ by the regulator after a lengthy
consultation process. This regulatory process — if not all its outcomes —
generally is supported by airlines.
8 Demand pressures on Sydney Airport have eased as a result of international events and the
withdrawal of many Ansett services. This reduction in demand for airport services, especially
in the domestic market, is expected to be short term, however.
194 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
switch some services to another airport. Such substitution possibilities also will be
reflected in demand for an airport’s services, but an airline that is a dominant airport
customer may be able to do even better by threatening to withdraw a bloc of
services.
Smaller airports reliant on one or two major airlines also may be in a relatively
weak bargaining position if an airline threatened to withhold payment for a period.
While an airport could take legal action and, after meeting certain requirements
under the terms of their leases (chapter 3), eventually refuse access to a debtor
airline, it could experience a severe cash-flow crisis in the meantime, as well as
incur substantial legal costs. On this point, Professor King noted that:
… [countervailing] power may be increased if the airport itself cannot credibly reduce
its output; for example, if the airport is credit constrained and potentially faces cash-
flow problems. (ACCC, sub. 36, attachment C, p. 13)
In the international market, the scope for airlines to shift some of their traffic
between Australian airports may provide them with a degree of bargaining power.
The growing importance of airline alliances and code-sharing agreements may also
enhance airline bargaining power. SACL suggested that large airports are
vulnerable to the group buying power of airlines:
… individually, and through representative bodies and alliances, airlines have a
significant degree of countervailing power. Airports derive a substantial degree of their
revenues from [a] comparatively small number of airline customers, who, individually
and collectively, are sophisticated and well organised. (sub. DR62, p. 4)
While these alliances are likely to increase airline countervailing power, member
airlines often compete within alliances, and alliances compete with each other,
which will tend to undermine their bargaining power.
As for the potential impact on profitability, a decline in some services at the larger
airports may be more easily offset because of the range of market segments served
and services offered. Melbourne Airport (sub. 37) presented analysis to demonstrate
that a hypothetical 10 per cent reduction in services to Melbourne Airport by Qantas
would reduce the airport’s operating profit by around 10 per cent, but the airline’s
by a mere 0.4 per cent. However, this ignores scope for other airlines to replace
some or all of the services withdrawn by Qantas, overstating Melbourne Airport’s
potential losses, at least in the aviation market that existed prior to September 2001.
CONDUCT OF 195
UNREGULATED
AIRPORTS
The larger airports rely heavily on non-aeronautical revenues, however, and airlines
feasibly could threaten to withdraw marginal flights that delivered high profits to
airports to obtain lower across-the-board charges. This may be assisted by airline
knowledge of airport revenues. Melbourne Airport commented that:
This is also a game in which there is significant information asymmetry. The airline
will have a good idea about how much it contributes to the airport in terms of direct
income and may even have some knowledge about the passenger based income derived
from retailing, car parks and so on and can be confident that marginal airport costs are
low … On the other hand, airports have little information about the economics of
individual airline routes. Indeed, it is unlikely that an airport would even know what the
next most profitable route was, let alone its profitability. (sub. 37, p. 11)
Airlines also could use the threat to locate discretionary infrastructure (such as
engineering and maintenance facilities) elsewhere as a bargaining chip to extract
lower aeronautical charges. However, as noted by BARA (sub. 41) and Qantas
(sub. 48), this strategy can be used only occasionally, and then only on an ex ante
basis. Once a facility has been built, the airline is locked in to using that facility at
the airport and relative bargaining positions can reverse. However, an airline could
lock in lower aeronautical charges via a long-term contract.
Larger airports are also likely to be better able to withstand reduced cash flows from
non-payment of fees, for example.
The reduction in Ansett services since that airline was placed in administration,
coupled with rationalisation of several international carrier services to Australia, has
left Australian airports generally more reliant on the custom of Qantas. Over time,
Qantas’s dominant position in the domestic market is expected to diminish
somewhat as other operators build up their capacity. In the short to medium term,
however, Qantas’s bargaining position with many airports appears to have been
enhanced, at least in relation to the airline’s decisions about allocation of aircraft
capacity at the margin.
The countervailing power of airlines in their dealings with major capital city
airports appears limited. However, airlines may have a degree of countervailing
power even at those airports where there is scope for airport substitution (for
example, entry ports for international flights), where airlines form alliances and
bargain as a group, or where selective threats can be made to reduce services that
are highly profitable to airports.
For smaller core-regulated airports, airline countervailing power is likely to be
stronger, due to the commercial strength of major airlines relative to smaller
airports, the market segments served by those airports and greater scope for airport
competition.
Apart from airlines, there are other users of airports who may possess some
countervailing power. Airport operators lease rental space to specialist retailers who
then provide retail services (including food and beverages) to airline passengers and
others visiting the airport. The large number of individual retailers and retail chains
that may seek these leases suggests there would be little countervailing power in
this sector. That said, it is possible that some retail chains may offer goods and
services that passengers value highly. In this case, the airport may seek out these
retailers, in which case the latter may have some negotiating power.
At any rate, as discussed in chapter 6, airports appear to possess little market power
in retail services. A broadly similar situation applies to car parking. Melbourne
Airport argued that:
… airports are unlikely to have significant market power in relation to services
provided to non-airline users and as such, a discussion of countervailing power is not
particularly relevant. (sub. 7, p. 16)
Several airports have introduced charges for taxi operators picking up passengers at
airports (appendix E). As taxi drivers are organised at the State and national level
and operate under the auspices of a few large companies, they would seem to have a
degree of economic and political power to countervail market power that airports
may have with regard to taxi charges. However, the Australian Taxi Industry
Association did not accept this proposition:
We must note that, while there are driver organisations operating within the taxi
industry, the extent of their representation of taxi drivers is relatively low and so
consequently, is their ability to develop ‘countervailing power’ in negotiations with
airports.
CONDUCT OF 197
UNREGULATED
AIRPORTS
Similarly, while there are a limited number of large organisations that provide ‘taxi
brands’, these networks have no effective control over the individual taxi operators
providing services under that brand. (sub. DR61, p. 2)
FINDING 7.3
If airports with market power effectively could charge different prices for different
customers, then the efficiency effects of exercising market power would be reduced
because the quantity supplied would increase and may even approach the efficient
level. Furthermore, an airport will have a strong incentive to discriminate in its
pricing because price discrimination brings higher profits.
As with countervailing power, this issue has brought forth contradictory evidence.
The ACCC concluded that:
… if airports are in a position to price discriminate between different customers, the
allocative efficiency losses resulting from monopoly pricing might be mitigated. At the
limit, if they were able to perfectly price discriminate, the deadweight welfare losses to
society could be eliminated altogether.
However, the Commission [ACCC] considers this irrelevant given practical realities.
The evidence to date suggests that airlines and airports have little capacity to price
9 Perfect price discrimination, in the sense that all consumer surplus is captured, is not required
for efficiency. Efficiency requires that marginal sales are not forgone.
198 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
discriminate in relation to aeronautical services … Furthermore even if they could, the
information requirements to enable such pricing behaviour are likely to be extremely
high. (sub. 36, p. 7)
Traditionally, airports have levied landing charges on the basis of maximum take-
off weight (MTOW) of aircraft. This means that a heavier aircraft pays more to land
than a lighter one. Aircraft weight per passenger tends to increase with plane
gauge — for example, according to the MTAA Super Fund ‘a B737 or an A320 has
around 1.5 passengers per tonne (at an 80 per cent load factor), whereas a B767 has
around 1.0 passenger per tonne at similar loads’ (sub. 22, p. 26). Thus average
airport charges per passenger tend to be higher for larger planes. To some extent
this may reflect the higher costs imposed on the airport by larger planes, though
Doganis (1992) concludes that the relationship between weight-based charges and
airport costs is indirect at best.
This is not to suggest that such price discrimination will be perfect; larger planes
(for example, Boeing 747s) may fly relatively low-fare, short routes. The ACCC
also commented that weight-based charges do not discriminate among passengers
on given flights or among airlines with varying capacities to pay (sub. DR55).
While the Commission agrees with the ACCC that weight-based charging will not
deliver perfect price discrimination, such pricing can discriminate effectively in
certain circumstances. It is interesting to note that the ACCC rejected a proposal by
SACL to introduce passenger-based charging for domestic services because it:
… was concerned that it may adversely impact on competition in the domestic aviation
10 All else given, the greater the airfare, the smaller will be airport charges as a proportion of that
fare, and hence the smaller the price elasticity of demand for airport services (chapter 5).
CONDUCT OF 199
UNREGULATED
AIRPORTS
market, particularly in relation to new entrants … The concern is that the proposal
could reduce competition by disadvantaging low-cost new entrant airlines who carry
more passengers per aircraft. (ACCC 2001n)
Though the ACCC is right to observe that weight-based charges cannot discriminate
among passengers on particular flights, that task is likely to be performed
reasonably efficiently by airlines. A landing charge levied per aircraft will be
treated as a fixed cost by airlines (given a decision to make the flight), to be
allocated across passengers in a way that reduces the (discouraging) effect on the
marginal fare-paying passenger. Thus, as observed by the MTAA Super Fund:
Airlines’ pricing strategies, and their pattern of recovery of fixed costs, mean airport
charges are a similar percentage for each fare class and a smaller absolute amount in
discount economy fares. It is therefore incorrect to depict changes in airport charges as
applying uniformly across all passengers, implying a greater proportional impact on
lower fares … Aeronautical charges also have more of the characteristics of fixed costs
than variable costs, and any changes will therefore likely be passed on more to higher
fare paying passengers. The proportional impact on discount airfares will be smaller as
a consequence. (sub. 22, p. 31)
Passenger-based charges
One rationale for the introduction of passenger-based charging for terminal use is
that terminal costs are more directly related to passenger numbers than aircraft
weight. Thus, passenger charges may provide better price signals to users and
providers of terminals about the need for new investment. The shift also may reflect
the increasing importance of non-aeronautical revenues to airports based on
passenger throughput. A passenger charge provides airports with data on passenger
As discussed above, many airports also offer low entry prices and/or direct
assistance (in cash or kind) to new airlines and new services offered by incumbent
airlines. Such deals cannot be attributed to current regulatory arrangements and they
suggest that an airport has both the incentive and a reasonable ability to target
marginal airline services, subject to the need to prevent ‘churning’ of existing
services as new services.11
It is noteworthy that Melbourne and Perth airports, in applying the recent one-off
price increases allowed under price caps, have elected to impose the entire
allowable increase on domestic movements, with no net increase in charges for
international flights (chapter 2). This restructuring presumably reflects the nature of
the shocks that affected the two markets in September 2001. The domestic market
was hit by a reduction in the supply of aviation services that has required an
increase in average domestic fares to ration available capacity. In contrast, demand
in the international market slumped, placing downward pressure on fares and
threatening viability of several international carriers. These two airports are
11 While the ACCC correctly observed that international agreements prevent discriminatory
airport charges among international airlines, there is evidence that airports instead offer other
incentives (for example, marketing assistance). Moreover, these incentives often are available
for marginal services of all airlines.
CONDUCT OF 201
UNREGULATED
AIRPORTS
restructuring prices in a way that will favour what, in current circumstances, is the
more vulnerable, and presumably more price-sensitive market. (This does not mean
that the domestic market will always be less price sensitive than the international
market.) At the very least, the recent pricing outcomes suggest that airports are alert
to changes in price responsiveness at the margin and, moreover, consider that their
charging policies can affect demand.
FINDING 7.4
Thus, when capacity is constrained, efficiency is served by allowing those with the
highest valuations to access the facility and effectively denying access to those with
12 What constitutes the peak can be a difficult question, however (SACL, sub. 27).
Some participants (for example, ACCC, sub. 36) disputed whether price rationing
of excess demand for slots at Sydney Airport would promote efficiency, because
slots are already being allocated under a quantity rationing scheme. However, as
discussed in appendix H, leaving aside the issues of the regional ring fence (which
guarantees certain slot allocations to regional airlines — see chapter 3, box 3.4) and
possible protection of other regional users (outside the ring fence), there is no
expectation, under the current rationing scheme, that airlines with the highest slot
valuations (potentially carrying customers with the highest valuations) obtain
rationed slots.13 Indeed, such an outcome is unlikely.
Thus, even if airport prices still fall short of efficient, market-clearing levels, a
move towards those levels is likely to promote a more efficient allocation of slots
because some flights will be replaced by others with higher pay loads (for example,
through the substitution of larger for smaller planes and the withdrawal of marginal
flights). Nonetheless, this is unlikely to lead to significantly higher passenger
airfares at peak times because average fares to Sydney Airport at these times will
already largely reflect the scarcity value of slots, with the rents accruing to airlines
holding those slots. However, some passengers travelling on services that are
withdrawn or rescheduled to off-peak periods may be worse off. The transfer of
scarcity rents from airlines to airports also could have repercussions for an airline’s
operations if such scarcity rents are used to cover the fixed costs of services on
other routes.
13 For a given slot allocation, however, an airline will ensure that customers with the highest
valuations obtain seats by not offering discounted fares on those flights. While this promotes
efficiency, the airlines, rather than the airport or passengers, capture scarcity rents under a slot
allocation scheme. It also is possible that an airline will provide some flights to obtain/retain a
valuable slot (eg by flying smaller planes more frequently). Though the full current value of
slots used in this way will not be realised by the airline, such a strategy will reduce slots
available to competitors and ‘babysit’ them for higher-value use in the future.
CONDUCT OF 203
UNREGULATED
AIRPORTS
FINDING 7.5
Major Australian airports appear to have a high degree of market power in core
aeronautical services. In the absence of constraints on airport pricing discussed in
preceding sections, there will be an incentive for an airport to use this market
power. If it cannot discriminate in pricing, an airport will have an incentive to
increase prices above marginal (and average) costs, to the point that marginal
revenue and marginal cost are equal.
Any such increase in price will reduce consumption of the airport’s services,
resulting in the familiar monopoly, deadweight efficiency loss (chapter 4,
figures 4.1 and 4.2). Airlines and their passengers will pay more for use of the
airport’s facilities, allowing the airport to earn monopoly profits. (For a capacity-
constrained airport, so long as the restricted capacity is fully used, the profits will
reflect the scarcity of capacity, not monopoly profits.)
However, in the Commission’s view, for reasons discussed in section 7.1, the
‘traditional’ full monopoly pricing is unlikely to occur, even for those airports with
significant market power. These influences will temper aeronautical price increases.
Further, price discrimination, to the extent that it can be exercised, will moderate
any adverse efficiency effects.
Though care must be taken in comparing airports, the fact that increased charges of
the order of 100 per cent at Sydney Airport (to implement replacement cost, dual-
till pricing) were not disallowed by the ACCC suggests that there may be a need for
significant price increases at other airports to reach ‘efficient’ average price
levels.14 How far beyond these levels or, indeed, whether aeronautical prices at
airports with market power would increase in the absence of any airport-specific
price regulation, no-one can say with certainty. However, for reasons outlined
above, the Commission considers that any price increases would be constrained by a
range of market forces, including commercial interests of the airports themselves.
The New Zealand Commerce Commission (CC) estimated that Auckland Airport
earned an average annual nominal rate of return on aeronautical assets of just under
13.5 per cent between 1989 and 2000 (CC 2001b). Using this estimated rate of
return as a benchmark for pricing by unregulated Australian airports, the ACCC
suggested that the four largest airports in Australia would increase revenues by
$1.4 billion over five years (ACCC, sub. DR55). In rough terms, this implies a
doubling of aeronautical charges and revenues. Several comments are in order.
• First, the accuracy of the CC’s rate-of-return calculation has been challenged by
Auckland Airport on numerous grounds, including that the CC’s removal of land
bought for a second runway from the allowable asset base is inappropriate
14 Sydney’s landing charges were considerably lower than those at other major airports (albeit
offset by a higher international terminal charge). Sydney’s costs and asset valuations also may
be higher (especially land valuation). Melbourne Airport observed that it ‘would not consider a
step increase of the magnitude achieved by Sydney Airport appropriate [for Melbourne
Airport]’ (sub. DR66, p. 19).
CONDUCT OF 205
UNREGULATED
AIRPORTS
(chapter 11). Auckland Airport estimates that its true rate of return is around
8 per cent.
• Second, even on the CC’s own estimates, aeronautical prices at Auckland
Airport in 2000 were less than 3 per cent above the estimated efficient
benchmark price. Given scope for measurement error (and particularly given the
problems in valuing airport land), this gap would seem insignificant. Since then,
Auckland Airport has negotiated a 12.5 per cent price increase with airlines.
• Third, a critical issue in assessing likely price outcomes in Australia is whether
current prices at Australian airports are efficient. Efficiency (and consumers in
the medium to long term) may be best served by somewhat higher prices than at
present, to facilitate appropriate investment. It is noteworthy that the CC
suggested that an efficient target rate of return on aeronautical assets at
Auckland Airport was just under 10 per cent (somewhat higher than suggested
by the airport itself). This is well above reported rates of return on aeronautical
assets at the major privatised Australian airports, which in 1999-00 were
reported to range from zero to 3.7 per cent (chapter 2, table 2.4).
Since removal of their price caps on 5 October 2001, several Australian airports
(Adelaide, Alice Springs, Canberra, Coolangatta, Darwin, and Townsville) have
increased their charges, some by substantial amounts (chapter 2). Coolangatta, for
example, announced an increase of 170 per cent. Launceston and Hobart have not
increased their charges. Without any knowledge of the impact on airport revenues
and profits, it is difficult to say whether these announced price increases represent
an abuse of market power, in the sense of being unjustified by costs. Most airports
that have increased their charges have said they will still incur losses and that the
charges will be reviewed in early 2002. While Capital Airport Group (sub. DR75)
announced a price increase, it simultaneously introduced substantial rebates in a bid
to encourage additional services.
Though the Commission does not consider that it is possible to forecast with any
certainty possible increases in unregulated airport charges that would occur without
price caps, the ACCC’s suggestion (sub. DR55) that profit-maximising prices at
Sydney Airport are in the order of $500 per international passenger and $120 per
domestic passenger seems implausible. In particular, the calculations do not appear
to admit any scope for destination or modal substitution (box 7.1). Sydney Airport,
even acting as an unconstrained profit-maximising entity — and any political
pressure aside — is unlikely to charge prices at the levels suggested by the ACCC.
Nonetheless, it is acknowledged that efficient peak-period charges could be high at
Sydney Airport, reflecting the impact of slot constraints.
As noted above, if the price at the margin exceeds the efficient level, then
consumption will be curtailed. This efficiency loss will measure the economy-wide
loss provided private costs and benefits equate with social values. If the use of
airports generated negative external effects, then a higher price that deters use could
bring net social benefits rather than losses. On the other hand, if a user industry
generated external benefits that were not captured fully in the private demand for
output of that industry, the negative effect of excessive airport charges would be
amplified. (In either case, however, the optimal policy may not be to raise or lower
airport charges but rather to target the externality directly. For example, appropriate
levies could be imposed on aircraft according to noise levels.)
Several participants seemed to imply that low airport charges are justified by the
assistance this renders to the Australian tourism industry (chapter 4). In this vein,
BARA (sub. DR54) criticised the Commission for failing to assess economy-wide
effects of airport price increases, suggesting that more than 4000 jobs could be lost
in the tourism industry if airport prices were not regulated. This figure assumes that
international airfares would rise by roughly 2 per cent on average if all core-
regulated airports approximately doubled their charges and that a 1 per cent increase
CONDUCT OF 207
UNREGULATED
AIRPORTS
in international airfares would result in the loss of roughly 2000 jobs in the tourism
industry.15
The calculations also assume that airports do not, or cannot, discriminate among
airlines and their passengers in a way that would mitigate any efficiency effects of
higher airport charges. Yet there is substantial evidence that they do discriminate in
their pricing in a manner that would reduce the effect of any average price increase
on marginal users.
Moreover, the modelled rise in airfares is based on estimates prepared by the ACCC
in relation to proposed fee increases at Sydney Airport. These increases occurred
within the current regulatory regime. In addition, given excess demand for slots at
Sydney Airport, it is unlikely that the rise in airport charges will have much effect
on fares to and from Sydney at peak times. At any rate, the estimates fail to take
into account the effect on fares of yield management by the airlines, which would
tend to reduce the impact of higher airport charges on the more price-sensitive users
(see MTAA Super Fund, sub. 22). At the very least, the interplay between airport
charges and airfares needs to be analysed before modelling an assumed across-the-
board fare ‘shock’.
15 The assumed relationship between higher airfares and job losses in the tourism sector appears
to be derived from the MONASH model of the Australian economy.
208 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
shed any light on the question of whether the price changes promote, or detract
from, efficiency. Even if it were considered desirable to subsidise the tourism
sector, it is difficult to conceive of a situation where holding airport charges
below efficient levels would be the most appropriate means of achieving this.
Overall, the Commission does not consider that general equilibrium modelling
would assist in answering the key questions that need to be answered in this inquiry,
at least without much more information than is currently available. Any modelling
of an assumed price change would beg the question of why that particular shock
was chosen. If the Commission modelled a scenario in which prices were increased
to an ‘efficient’ level, or if it modelled a scenario in which consumption of airport
services did not change because of price discrimination, it would be open to
criticism for contriving the result. Moreover, such an exercise would not shed any
light on what might happen to airport prices. In other words, the real debate in this
inquiry is about the likely ‘shock’, namely the extent and nature of any price change
at airports and whether such a change would be efficient or inefficient.
BARA (sub. DR54) also suggested, because core-regulated airports no longer are
owned and operated on a network basis, that additional efficiency losses would arise
due to ‘double marginalisation’. Double marginalisation typically refers to the
separation of a vertically-integrated production process, where each firm in the
chain possesses and exploits market power. Each firm in the production chain takes
the price charged by the input supplier as given (including the price mark-up) and
then itself prices according to its market power. The result of the cascading effect of
higher costs is consumer prices that are higher (and efficiency losses that are larger)
than would occur if the production process were integrated. What BARA could
have in mind here is, say, flights between Melbourne and Sydney, where both
airports separately exploit their market power.
Where demands for different airports with market power are complementary (that
is, where a ‘pair’ of airports must be used for domestic flights), at issue is whether
separation of airport ownership is likely to lead to higher prices for (and lower
consumption of) such pairs. It is possible, in this situation, that airports compete for
profits by independently raising their charges. The net effect could be a higher price
being charged for using the pair of airports than would be charged by a single
operator, but the joint profits would be lower than the single-owner case. The
combined profits of the two airports would be maximised if their combined price
CONDUCT OF 209
UNREGULATED
AIRPORTS
(for using a pair of airports) was the same as for a single owner. For this reason,
BARA (trans., p. 535) suggested that airlines could be better off if all airports in
Australia were owned by a single monopolist than by several, though they
acknowledged that there were other factors involved.
Distributional effects
Aeronautical price increases (at airports with excess capacity) would redistribute
surplus from passengers and possibly airlines to airport owners. Any monopoly
airport profits would accrue to airport shareholders, some of whom are non-
residents. (Most privatised core-regulated airports are partially foreign-owned, the
maximum level being 49 per cent — chapter 3, box 3.3.) Airport shareholders also
comprise Australian residents, including superannuation funds investing on behalf
of Australian contributors (for example, the MTAA Super Fund investments in
Adelaide and Brisbane airports (sub. 22), AMP Henderson’s 49.9 per cent
ownership of Australia Pacific Airports Corporation (sub. 10),16 and Uni Super’s
stake in Adelaide and Coolangatta airports (sub. 20)). The ‘losers’ from higher
airport charges would be airline shareholders (comprising residents and non-
residents) and airline passengers (both resident and non-resident). Professor Forsyth
observed that:
In the airport regulation situation, it is not a matter of having some specified
distributional trade-offs between the different groups. There is little by way of
identifying who the gainers and losers are, and what their circumstances are.
(sub. 5, p. 11)
The estimate that 10 per cent of passengers using Australian airports are foreign
residents would appear to underestimate significantly the impact of higher airport
charges on non-residents. This figure accounts for arrivals and departures of non-
residents on international flights only. Data for non-residents who take domestic
and regional flights are unavailable. If, on average, international visitors take just
one domestic or regional flight while in Australia, then non-residents would account
16 APAC operates Melbourne and Launceston airports (through its subsidiaries Australia Pacific
Airports (Melbourne) and Australia Pacific Airports (Launceston) respectively).
210 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
for 20 per cent of total passenger movements.17 Moreover, non-resident
international passenger movements at core-regulated airports assessed as having
most market power and therefore most capacity to raise charges (Sydney,
Melbourne, Brisbane and Perth), accounted for around 15 per cent of total
passenger movements at these four airports in 1999. International visitors accounted
for 58 per cent of all international passenger movements.
FINDING 7.6
17 This assumes two movements (arrival and departure) per non-resident passenger on each
international and local service.
CONDUCT OF 211
UNREGULATED
AIRPORTS
Productive efficiency of airports with market power
BARA argued that airports with market power, if unregulated, are likely to operate
inefficiently in not watching costs:
It [monopoly pricing] will also weaken the imperatives for airports to be vigilant over
their costs resulting in further economic waste. (sub. 41, p. 1)
BARA continued:
Competition provides benchmarks enabling owners to more accurately gauge the
performance of management. More importantly, competition disciplines poor
performance in terms of low returns and exit from the market. In the absence of
competition there is scope for productive inefficiencies. Effective regulation, through
acting as a surrogate for some of the cost pressures on a firm facing effective
competition, can reduce these costs. (sub. 41, p. 30)
Given the nature of airport supply and demand, there is no competitive benchmark
against which to assess an airport’s performance. (Indeed, competitive supply — in
the sense of many providers — would be a highly inefficient way of providing
airport services.)
At issue is the extent to which airport managers will be able to operate inefficiently
(and thus reduce potential profits to owners). The airport manager has an incentive
to pursue such a strategy to the extent that it delivers non-pecuniary benefits,
including excessive ‘perks’ and a lower level of effort. Several factors seem
relevant.
• Given the competitive sale of core-regulated airports, owners will expect
managers to deliver at least the returns factored into the bid price. Indeed these
performance levels could have been factored into incentive-based contracts with
managers. That said, scope for additional profits not factored into the bid price
may make the manager’s task somewhat easier.
• Owners can benchmark an airport’s costs and performance against other airports
in Australia and overseas.
• Despite limited privatisation of airports internationally, specialist airport
management companies have emerged (for example, Aer Rianta, BAA plc and
Hochtief) that offer their expertise worldwide. Such companies could identify an
inefficient airport and sell their services to airport owners (several of which are
very large fund managers). In other words, there appears to be reasonable
competition in the supply of airport management services.
FINDING 7.7
Managers of privatised airports with market power are unlikely to have much scope
to allow inefficiencies in production.
CONDUCT OF 213
UNREGULATED
AIRPORTS
Rather than seeking to delay investment, Qantas argued that:
Airport operators, on the other hand, have an incentive to overbuild and goldplate
airport assets, as their primary business is land and infrastructure construction and
management. It is therefore vital that regulatory oversight of capital expenditure is
maintained. (sub. 48, p. 22)
However, it is difficult to see why a private airport operator (not subject to price
regulation but subject to capital market constraints) would incur unnecessary
investment expenditure. If increased investment allows an airport with market
power to increase its prices, this must reflect increased willingness to pay of at least
some users; otherwise, prices could have been raised without incurring the extra
investment outlay.
Some participants also expressed concern that airports not subject to price
regulation would allow quality levels to deteriorate. Qantas observed:
Left unregulated, airport operators can be expected to use their market power through
monopoly pricing, diminishing service quality and the imposition of unreasonable
terms and conditions of access to the airport. (sub. 48, p. 29)
An unregulated airport with market power may be cautious about allowing service
quality to diminish below levels desired by users. At least some passengers and
airlines are prepared to pay for quality, particularly for aeronautical services with a
safety dimension.18 Provided those who value quality can be charged for its
provision, an airport with market power is likely to provide that quality.
The link between quality (for example, quick processing and attractive terminal
spaces) and non-aeronautical revenues will also play a role. As noted above,
Melbourne Airport noted a direct causation between overall airport quality and
increased non-aeronautical earnings. With respect to the likely investment and
quality performance of unregulated airports, Professor Forsyth concluded that:
Private monopolies do not necessarily achieve a perfect optimum in their choice on
quality level, but there are good reasons to expect that they will choose about the right
quality … This will be so because they can convert an increase in quality into
18 Under the terms of their leases and the Airports Act 1996, airports are required to meet certain
safety and other standards.
214 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
additional revenue, since users are prepared to pay higher prices for higher quality. The
private airport will be willing to make investments which improve the service to users;
such as an extension to a runway which lowers the costs faced by users, because these
users will be prepared to pay higher prices. (sub. 5, pp. 17–18)
FINDING 7.8
In principle, airports with market power may have some incentive to delay
investment or to allow quality to deteriorate, in order to maximise their profits.
However, in practice, to the extent that airports with market power can discriminate
in pricing or differentiate products for different users, those incentives will be
weakened. The scope to earn additional non-aeronautical profits from higher
quality or expanded aeronautical capacity and passenger throughput, will also
encourage the provision of appropriate quality and investment levels.
CONDUCT OF 215
UNREGULATED
AIRPORTS
Thirdly, if the airport service is suffering a degree of congestion, the airport may
simply find it easier to deny access rather than establish mechanisms to deal with
congestion and scheduling problems. In other words, the airport would prefer a ‘quiet
life’. (sub. 48, p. 25)
The ability of an airport to earn excess profits in any activity at the airport depends
on the alternatives available to buyers. An airport, therefore, may have an incentive
to restrict access to its facilities to limit competition in the supply of those services
where some competition otherwise is feasible. As observed by Qantas, this could
occur whether the airport operates in the market in question directly or indirectly by
selling rights to others to operate a business on the airport. However, some of the
examples cited by Qantas do not appear to relate to denial of access as such.
In the Commission’s view, there are three broad scenarios in which an airport
operator may seek to deny access.
• Where an airport can earn more by ‘selling’ monopoly access rights to an
airline than providing access to all airline entrants at a lower cost. In effect, the
airport and the airline would collude to monopolise the aviation market (or at
least a particular route). In the absence of any scope for monopoly rents to be
earned in the aviation market (sufficient to compensate the airport for lost sales),
the airport will prefer an open aviation market.
• Where an airport can earn more by selling a monopoly right to an on-airport
service provider (such as a cargo handler) rather than allowing competition in
provision of such services. This scenario also requires the service provider to
earn monopoly rents in the relevant market, sufficient to compensate the airport.
• Where an airport provides services directly (or via a licensee), earning
monopoly profits by denying access (for example, to the airport’s ‘front door’)
to potential competitors in that market. For example, an airport may deny or
frustrate access to an off-airport car-park provider to earn monopoly profits from
its own car-parking operations.
In practice, the first scenario appears less likely to occur than the other two. It relies
on the earning of substantial monopoly profits in the aviation market but,
notwithstanding recent events, that market appears competitive — or, at least,
contestable — over the longer term. Therefore, it is unlikely that an airport would
see any benefit in an exclusive deal with one airline. Indeed, the evidence shows
that airports have actively encouraged services from new carriers (section 7.1). A
variant of the first scenario is that a large incumbent airline could threaten to
withdraw some of its business from an airport if the latter offered a discriminatory
(low) entry price to a new entrant. In this case, the airport would not be willingly
denying access. This scenario also requires the airline, rather than the airport, to
With regard to the second scenario, though it may be possible to create a monopoly
in the supply of cargo-handling services at a particular airport, for example, this will
be limited by the scope for airport substitution (which, in the case of dedicated
freight, may be substantial). Nonetheless, there has been an access dispute involving
access for freight handling at Sydney and Melbourne airports (chapters 9 and 11).
Other ground-handling services also require access to the airport. Apart from this
case, however, the Commission has received no evidence that airports have sought
to frustrate competition in these services. Indeed, Capital Airport Group
(sub. DR75) submitted that it actively promoted competition in such services.
The third set of circumstances perhaps describes the most likely access scenario
because the airport effectively competes with off-airport providers in certain
activities and controls access to the airport. Charging an access fee in excess of
costs could allow the airport to raise prices for these potentially competing services.
As noted in chapter 6, the conclusion that airport market power in the provision of
car parking is likely to be low is robust only if the airport does not use its control
over airport access to stifle competition from off-airport car-park providers or
providers of competing transport modes. Denial (or frustration) of access to
potential competitors may arise from imposing unacceptable terms of access rather
than a prohibitive access price (for example, an inconvenient location for the set-
down/pick-up point).
In this vein, there has been one access case in which Delta Car Rentals applied
successfully for declaration of landside roads at Melbourne Airport under s. 192 of
the Airports Act 1996. The dispute concerned the location of the ‘designated
meeting point’ for its shuttle-bus service, not the access charge (chapter 9).
Arbitration was never sought. Some participants also raised concerns about landside
access charges (for example, Victorian Hire Car Association, sub. DR68). As
discussed in chapter 6, though airports do have market power in relation to front-
door vehicle access, it also seems reasonable that the airport will want to regulate
the way access to its terminals occurs, for operational and safety reasons. Apart
from the Delta case, there has been no other application for ‘front-door’ access.
FINDING 7.9
An airport with market power has little incentive to deny or frustrate access to its
major customers, the airlines.
An airport with market power may have an incentive to restrict ‘front-door’ access
to off-airport providers of competing services such as car parking, or providers of
competing transport modes, though there is little evidence of this occurring.
CONDUCT OF 217
UNREGULATED
AIRPORTS
8 Review of airport price regulation:
price-cap and prices-notification
arrangements
8.1 Introduction
Following privatisation, the same economic regulation framework was imposed on
all 11 privatised core-regulated airports. It comprised several inter-related elements
aimed at preventing abuse of any market power available to airport operators, while
encouraging efficient levels of service quality and new investment. If an airport
possesses and may use significant market power then the incentives provided by the
regulatory framework, if appropriate, can bring forth improved economic outcomes.
However, if the regulation were poorly framed or administered it might detract from
the performance of an airport with market power or indeed impede the performance
of an airport without market power.
The various elements of the price regulation framework after privatisation need to
be considered as an integrated package. It is also important to recognise that the
initial regulatory framework explicitly was intended to be a transitional one, aimed
at facilitating the change from airport ownership by a government-owned
corporation to the more commercially-focused environment of private airport
ownership.
Chapter 4 has outlined some principles for efficient pricing and good regulation. For
price regulation of airports the Commonwealth Government has stressed the dual
objectives of protecting users from abuse of market power and the importance of
moving towards price determination by commercial negotiation between airports
and their customers with minimum regulatory involvement (chapter 3).
The objectives of not only preventing the abuse of market power, but also
minimising regulatory costs, encouraging commercially-negotiated outcomes and
facilitating the access of new airlines have been reaffirmed in the terms of reference
for this inquiry.
Box 3.1 (chapter 3) outlines the services included in the aeronautical basket.
Aeronautical-related services subject to price monitoring are discussed in chapter 9.
In January 1997, the Federal Airports Corporation (FAC) set new aeronautical
prices, to which the ACCC did not object, at its five largest airports, leaving prices
at the others unchanged. These charges became the aeronautical prices operating
when 11 of the core-regulated airports were privatised in 1997 and 1998. For the
five years following sale, the price cap was to set maximum annual weighted
average prices, determined by the underlying national CPI, less a discount
factor (X) specific for each airport (chapter 3). Low underlying CPI growth has
meant that, for most airports, the price-cap formula has resulted in falling maximum
average aeronautical charges in nominal as well as real terms.
Aeronautical prices could differ from the allowed maxima but any over-recoveries
needed to be made up by the imposition of lower than maximum allowable prices in
a later year or years.2 Within the cap, aeronautical prices could be set by the airport,
although any increases were to be notified to the ACCC. This offered some
opportunity for airports to adjust their pricing regimes, although changes under
price caps have been limited.
1 The Prices Surveillance Act 1983 does not provide for legal enforcement of price reductions
under the cap. Melbourne Airport (sub. 7) has indicated that, in any event, it considered that
compliance with the cap was a condition of sale of the airport lease which it is bound to
observe, a view supported by the Motor Trades Association of Australia Superannuation Fund
(sub. 22).
2 Some airports have elected to make rebates to users for prices in excess of the cap rather than
charge less than the cap in future years. Under-recoveries (that is, prices below the cap) may
also be made up in later years.
REVIEW OF AIRPORT 221
PRICE REGULATION
An important rationale for choosing the CPI-X approach was that, while
constraining prices, it provided airport operators with an incentive to improve
efficiency, as they are allowed to retain any productivity gains in producing
aeronautical services, above those implied in the X factors.3 In addition, it is
potentially a low cost and low intervention approach once the parameters of the
pricing formula have been established. As noted, a safety valve was incorporated by
allowing under- and over-recoveries of revenue to be rectified in later years.
When the FAC took control of 17 federal airports in January 1988,4 it reviewed
airport charges (aeronautical and non-aeronautical) on a network-wide basis, with
the objective of covering network costs, including capital costs. This led to an
increase in landing charges (which then provided around 90 per cent of aeronautical
revenue) of about 6 per cent in July 1988, together with significant increases in
non-aeronautical commercial lease charges. Over the next three years to April 1991,
annual increases in landing charges (incorporating some restructuring of charges)
cumulated to a further 23 per cent.5 In April 1991, the FAC’s landing charges were
declared for surveillance under the Prices Surveillance Act 1983 (PS Act).
Landing charges remained constant from April 1991 until January 1997, although
there were some increases in other aeronautical charges over that period. In
January 1997, aeronautical charges were increased by an average (on a network
3 The rate of increase in CPI also embodies productivity increases across the economy.
4 The FAC purchased a further six airports from the Commonwealth Government in 1989 but
sold Cambridge Airport to a private buyer in 1993.
5 This compared to CPI growth between June 1988 and June 1991 of 19.8 per cent and Average
Weekly Earnings (ordinary time earnings of full-time adult males) increases of 20.5 per cent
over the same period.
222 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
basis) of 10.8 per cent — this was not objected to by the ACCC.6 However, the
1997 price increases were confined to the five major airports — Sydney,
Melbourne, Brisbane, Adelaide and Perth — representing an average 12.1 per cent
increase for those airports.
The ACCC (1996) observed that, even with the average 13.8 per cent increase
originally sought, the FAC believed that the five airports concerned would only just
recover all aeronautical operating costs (including depreciation based on 1991-92
asset valuations but no returns to capital) from aeronautical revenues. In its draft
decision on Sydney Airports Corporation Limited’s (SACL) pricing proposal, the
ACCC observed the impact on returns to aeronautical assets of the FAC’s pricing
policy:
In the past airport prices were set by the FAC on a single till basis. The FAC adopted a
rate of return target for the airport as a whole, and set aeronautical charges at the level
required to meet the rate of return target. Since profitability on non-aeronautical
services was high, and typically well above the target rate of return for the airport as a
whole, this meant that returns on the aeronautical side of the business were low, often
negative. (ACCC 2001h, p. 75)
The differential price increases between airports were designed as a first step to
more appropriate airport-specific pricing that had been recommended by the Prices
Surveillance Authority (PSA 1993). In not objecting to the FAC’s January 1997
price increases, the ACCC (1996) also indicated its preference for further location-
and service-specific pricing adjustments to improve the efficiency of pricing.
Until the January 1997 increases, landing charges and, where they existed, terminal
charges, were uniform across the FAC network. While some airports made losses,
these were more than offset by profits from the larger airports. Of the original FAC
airports, over time, the number of loss-making units declined from ten (of fourteen)
in 1988-89 to three in 1996-97.7
The FAC network landing charges in place before the airports were leased were
essentially cost-based prices using a single till on a largely network-wide basis. A
6 These increases were in fees for use of airport terminals, but were charged on the same
maximum take-off weight basis as landing fees. The average 10.8 per cent rise compared to an
average 13.8 per cent applied for by the FAC (a 15.2 per cent average increase for the five
airports for which price increases were sought) and a CPI increase of 13 per cent between the
June quarter 1991 and June quarter 1996. There had also been some relatively minor increases
in terminal charges between 1991 and 1996.
7 Of the airports controlled by the FAC, Hobart and Cambridge were managed as a single unit, as
were Bankstown, Camden and Hoxton Park. Of the five further airport units (Alice Springs and
Tennant Creek being treated as a single unit for reporting purposes) the FAC purchased from
the Government in 1989, four were still making losses in 1996-97. Profits and losses were
before interest charges.
REVIEW OF AIRPORT 223
PRICE REGULATION
network-wide real rate of return on revalued assets of around 8 per cent had been
earned consistently over a number of years.8 As a percentage of airport revenue, the
cross subsidies that existed between airports were proportionately much greater for
the smaller loss-making airports than for the larger airports providing the subsidies.
Hence, any additional profits made by the larger airports in order to make up for
low or negative returns at other airports would have been only a small part of the
large airports’ revenue.9
The Industry Commission (IC 1992) also recommended that individual airports
should, over time, recover all costs and meet a real rate-of-return target.
The breaking up of the FAC network as part of airport privatisation means that
individual airports now operate on a stand-alone basis. Hence, consideration of the
likely adequacy of the inherited FAC prices as a starting point for future
aeronautical investment decisions at individual airports, needs to be assessed on this
basis.
There were also significant cross subsidies between airport services, although the
PSA (1993) indicated that the FAC’s basis for cost allocation made it difficult to
determine their exact extent. However, the general direction of subsidisation was
from non-aeronautical to aeronautical.
Westralia Airports Corporation (WAC, sub. 21) stated that the starting aeronautical
prices at Perth Airport did not cover operating costs and hence provided no
8 In its 1996 revaluation of assets, the FAC valued land at market value for alternate use (capped
at light industrial) and other assets at written down replacement cost (FAC 1996).
9 In 1996-97 the total losses of the loss-making airports represented 0.5 per cent of the revenue
of the five largest FAC airports. Earning an 8 per cent return on the assets of the loss-making
airports would have represented around 5.5 per cent of the revenue of the five largest airports.
224 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
contribution to capital costs or a return on capital.10 Similarly, Capital Airport
Group (sub. 32) stated that the return on aeronautical assets at Canberra Airport was
negative. The ACCC (1998h) report on FAC price restructuring proposals for
Sydney Airport indicated that returns on aeronautical assets were estimated to be
negative in 1998-99. Alice Springs, Darwin and Townsville airports made losses on
their total operations in 1997-98, their final year of operation under the FAC.
The Department of Transport and Regional Services (DoTRS) indicated that leaving
these distortions in the starting prices was a conscious policy:
It was, however, neither practicable nor feasible to attempt to unwind these distortions
prior to privatisation — which was intended to accelerate the micro economic reform in
the aviation industry. Hence an important feature in the sales process was a requirement
that the efficiency gains potentially available at the major regular public transport
airports be shared with airport users. In effect, the Commonwealth chose to forego
value in the sale by requiring real price declines in aeronautical charges. The prices
oversight framework, and in particular the application of a CPI-X cap, was the vehicle
used to deliver these short term gains to aviation users. (sub. 39, p. 8)
The DoTRD Pricing Policy Paper (1996) indicated that these arrangements were to
be reviewed after five years. (However the significant downturn in Australian and
world aviation precipitated changes in October 2001.)
BARA (sub. DR54) noted that establishing the existence of genuine cross subsidies
at airports is complicated by the presence of common costs and demand
interdependencies between aeronautical and non-aeronautical services. With regard
to common costs, aeronautical revenues would need to be below the avoidable costs
of providing those services before an economic cross subsidy is established.
In the short term a significant portion of airport costs would remain even if
aeronautical operations ceased. However, the above evidence concerning FAC
aeronautical prices and revenues strongly suggests that aeronautical services at a
number of FAC airports would not have been covering their long-run incremental
costs. This is important for assessing whether existing prices are likely to justify
new investment.
10 In the last year of FAC operation (1996-97), Perth Airport made a profit of $27 million and had
a return (before interest expenses) of 12 per cent on total assets. In view of this, the failure of
starting prices to cover aeronautical costs suggests that Perth Airport earned significant non-
aeronautical returns.
REVIEW OF AIRPORT 225
PRICE REGULATION
profits earned on non-aeronautical activities to contribute to returns on aeronautical
services, without representing a cross subsidy. However, this incentive will not
extend to a full single-till system as operated by the FAC and to this extent the FAC
pricing system provided cross subsidies from non-aeronautical to aeronautical
activities.
Importantly with regard to cross subsidies, the starting prices for the price caps were
not adjusted by the FAC or the regulator to remove economically inefficient cross
subsidies and hence are unlikely to be a good basis for efficient pricing. The PSA
inquiry into the FAC’s charges concluded:
The current approach where the pricing of aeronautical services (as defined in the Act)
are largely determined on a residual basis will contribute to inefficient use of existing
aeronautical and non-aeronautical activities and distort signals for investment.
(PSA 1993, p. 170)
Both the PSA (1993) and ACCC (1996) recognised significant inefficiencies in the
FAC’s aeronautical charges.
The Xs
As part of the airport sale process, the Government announced real weighted
average annual aeronautical price reduction factors (the Xs) which were to apply for
five years and varied between airports. The Xs were determined by the Government
using advice from the ACCC. The ACCC stated:
The ACCC’s advice was based on its analyses of the airports’ projected demand, costs,
expected productivity improvements and economic performance. The cap is based on
the prices charged by the FAC before the airports’ privatisation. (ACCC 2000a, p. 10)
In addition, the ACCC (1998a) indicated that one of the factors considered was a
modest level of capital expenditure based on expected investment requirements over
the five years of the initial regulatory framework. It also indicated that Adelaide and
Coolangatta airports were exceptions with no amounts included for new investment.
Direction No. 2411 to the ACCC from the Minister for Financial Services and
Regulation stated that the value of each airport’s X reflected productivity
improvements that the Government considered could be made in the provision of
aeronautical services at each airport. However, a weakness in the application of the
price cap has been the failure to enunciate clearly how the Xs for each airport were
determined. Transparency and certainty are both attributes of good regulation that
are absent in the application of the X values.
11 Direction No. 24, October 2001, replaced previous Directions (chapter 3).
While all lessees were aware of the starting aeronautical prices and Xs, in order to
estimate allowable aeronautical prices under the cap, they also had to form their
own expectations of likely CPI movements.12 Many costs of aeronautical services
are likely to move independently of the factors determining the CPI. For example, it
has been argued by some airports that the low increases in the underlying CPI since
1997 have been unfavourable to airport operators. WAC observed:
We have also seen CPI work very much against us. Now, we realise that that’s an
external fact, but the reality is that the average rate of CPI in the lead-up to the
privatisation of the airport — and we would think that was in some way taken into
account in the CPI-X determination — has certainly deteriorated from our point of
view quite significantly, and CPI is in fact the largest single-value driver of our
business. (trans., p. 321)
WAC continued that many of its costs are fixed and not related to the CPI while
some of its non-aeronautical revenue, such as property rents, were adversely
affected by low CPI growth (trans., p. 321). However, consistently low underlying
CPI growth appears to have been an important factor in the decline in interest rates
12 In addition, bidders would have needed some view about likely price movements that would be
allowed outside the cap for necessary new investment and other cost pass-throughs.
REVIEW OF AIRPORT 227
PRICE REGULATION
in recent years and hence may have indirectly provided airports with savings in the
servicing of debt and equity capital.
While the implementation of the CPI-X formula has been relatively routine, the
price outcome is likely to be crucial to future profitability and investment at
airports. The ACCC observed:
The current prices are a carry over from the prices charged by the FAC before
privatisation. These charges were determined on a network basis. They were also
determined on a single-till basis. This means that the current charges are unlikely to
closely correlate to aeronautical costs. (sub. 36, p. 109)
FINDING 8.1
The single-till basis of the starting prices (also incorporating some cross subsidies
between airports), and the real declines in aeronautical prices at most airports
under the price cap suggest that, for many airports, aeronautical prices by the end
of 2000-01 may have been below the level necessary to justify future aeronautical
investment.
Of course, at least for the first five years, buyers of privatised airports would have
factored in their expectations of the price effects of the CPI-X cap, coupled with
scope for price increases for necessary new investment (NNI). However, while the
X values were known, there was a lack of transparency regarding the types of
investments that were or were not included in the Xs, as well as (as discussed
below) a lack of initial definition of allowable investment for cost pass-through to
prices.
The possibility of obtaining increased prices to compensate for NNI (section 8.3)
has created scope for ameliorating adverse effects the CPI-X cap might have on
investment undertaken to expand or improve aeronautical capacity. However,
incentives for replacement and maintenance investment would still remain low if
the price cap has generated low aeronautical prices. Chapter 10 discusses possible
approaches to resetting these parameters if a CPI-X approach were to be continued
or reintroduced for any airports.
Implementation issues
Because CPI-X is a formula approach to price setting, there is limited scope for
regulatory discretion once the starting prices and Xs have been established. For the
life of the initial regime, these parameters were established by the Government
First, there has been dispute between the ACCC and a number of airports regarding
whether charges on taxi operators collecting passengers at an airport are part of the
definition of aeronautical services (landside roads) and, hence, part of the basket
under the cap. Second, as part of its monitoring of aeronautical-related prices, the
ACCC (1998b) recommended that fuel throughput levies, which have been
introduced at two core-regulated airports, should be transferred from price
monitoring to be included in the price-cap basket because it considered there was a
strong case that their implementation represented an abuse of market power. To
date, the Government has not responded to the ACCC recommendation and fuel
throughput levies remain subject to price monitoring.
Whatever the degree of market power in refuelling (chapter 6), airports appear to be
able to extract charges greater than the costs of these services. Whether the
implemented charges represent an abuse of market power cannot really be assessed
fully without considering the constraint placed on aeronautical returns by the price
cap.
13 Melbourne Airport has sought a taxi levy through the NNI provisions, based on the costs of
building improved services for taxi operators. The ACCC did not object to a charge of $0.66
per taxi, compared to the $1.40 originally proposed by Melbourne Airport (appendix E).
REVIEW OF AIRPORT 229
PRICE REGULATION
this interpretation in a case involving Canberra Airport, at least for the particular
facts of that case (appendix E).
Such alleged contradictions between the sale process and the regulatory framework
increase the risk premium bidders will place on future sales, thereby decreasing
returns to taxpayers and adding to the costs of implementing regulation. In
undertaking sales of their assets, governments need to balance the objectives of high
sale value and the efficient subsequent regulation of the activity concerned.
The taxi issue arose because of a lack of detail in the guidelines and legislative
instruments regarding the extent of services covered by the term ‘landside roads’.
Capital Airport Group (sub. 32) and WAC (sub. 21), amongst others, claimed that
airport bidders were promised that ground transport charges could be introduced
outside the cap. The ACCC argued that:
The Commission’s concern is that the matter of taxis could easily have been addressed
in the regulatory instruments. The failure to explicitly address the issue has resulted in
unnecessary uncertainty for airport operators and airport users. It has also resulted in
substantial costs to the various parties because of the litigation process.
(sub. 36, p. 112)
For companies declared under the PS Act, the requirement to notify proposed price
increases is the usual mechanism through which the ACCC examines the firm’s
prices. However, for the privatised core-regulated airports, the main regulatory
constraint on prices for aeronautical services has been the price cap. While airports
are required to notify proposed increases in prices of such services, the ACCC is not
expected to object to notified price increases that do not result in an airport
breaching its price cap. DoTRD observed:
The ACCC will not object to price changes to aeronautical charges unless they breach
the price cap. This leaves scope for airport operators to continue to rebalance charges
within the overall price cap on aeronautical charges set for the airport.
(DoTRD 1996, p. 4)
Hence there is limited scope for the notification process to affect pricing other than
applications made under the NNI test and other cost pass-through provisions. The
In addition, low CPI increases in recent years have meant that the CPI-X formula
has, for most airports, generated average nominal price declines for notified
services. Hence notifications of proposed price increases have been unnecessary for
most airports unless restructuring of prices within the cap was undertaken. Some
airports have exceeded the cap in individual years, but because this has not involved
price increases, the notification process has not been invoked. Canberra and
Townsville airports, each with X values of 1 per cent, have both been permitted
increases in average aeronautical prices under the price cap — 0.5 per cent in
1998-99, 0.7 per cent in 1999-00 and 1.8 per cent in 2000-01, while the cap
permitted increases of 0.3 per cent at Launceston Airport (X of 2.5 per cent) in
2000-01.
The most significant exception to the price cap related to recouping costs of NNI in
aeronautical assets.14 For the 11 privatised core-regulated airports, the NNI
provisions were formalised in directions under the PS Act (chapter 3) and
implemented by the ACCC using the PS Act legislative criteria for performing
prices oversight (section 17(3)) and the criteria in Direction No. 20 (chapter 3,
box 3.2).
14 The removal of the price cap for the eight Phase 2 core-regulated airports means that NNI
provisions now only apply to the three Phase 1 airports plus Sydney Airport.
REVIEW OF AIRPORT 231
PRICE REGULATION
The NNI provisions were one of a number of instruments designed to encourage
appropriate aeronautical investment by airport operators. These include clauses in
airport sale agreements and leases specifying minimum levels of investment over
each of the first two five-year periods following privatisation, and requirements for
ongoing maintenance of airport structures and maintenance, to at least current
standards, of those parts of the airport needed for aircraft access (chapter 3). Also,
the lessee must provide for the use of the airport site as an airport. In addition, the
quality monitoring provisions of the Airports Act should assist in encouraging
investment in facilities to maintain quality of service, although airports are likely to
have sufficient market incentives to maintain quality (chapter 9).
Since privatisation there have been 18 proposals for NNI cost pass-throughs
involving total expenditure of over $200 million. The major expansion of airport
infrastructure that occurred under the FAC has reduced somewhat the immediate
need for new aeronautical investment at a number of airports.15 The key issues in
assessing NNI are whether it is an efficient and effective means for obtaining the
prices needed to generate efficient levels of aeronautical investment, for facilitating
access to airports for new airlines, and for fostering the commercial relationships
that will engender dynamic efficiency in airports and their users.
The NNI process establishes incentives for airport operators and users that are
important in determining whether efficient levels of new aeronautical investment
are achieved.
In return for undertaking new investment, current NNI provisions offer airports
aeronautical price increases either agreed to by users or determined by the ACCC.
The ACCC still has the power to object to price increases negotiated between the
parties.
15 From 1988-89 to 1996-97, the FAC invested $1.6 billion in airport infrastructure (including
non-aeronautical facilities).
232 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
• given scope for cost pass-through under NNI provisions (essentially rate-of-
return regulation for NNI), there need to be appropriate checks on airport
investment proposals, including majority user support for such proposals.
On the first point, as discussed above, evidence suggests that the CPI-X framework,
applied to FAC starting prices, has resulted in aeronautical prices that may not, of
themselves, justify new aeronautical investment. Therefore the NNI test is
important in allowing efficient new investment to achieve appropriate returns.
Airport operators bid for the leases on the basis of the CPI-X and NNI procedures
operating for at least the first five years of the lease.
However, even for investments that replace or expand capacity (and hence maintain
or increase revenue), if aeronautical prices are too low, an airport is not likely to
proceed with them. Melbourne Airport observed:
The necessary new investment arrangements exist, in our view, solely because without
them airports would not invest because airports require a price increase across the cost
base as a whole to justify investment, because at the current prices you would not
invest at all. So the necessary new investment arrangements, in our view, have to be
seen very clearly as a fix for the problem of prices being below what you might call
efficient investment prices. (trans., p. 167)
The potential for the airport to earn non-aeronautical revenues from capacity-
expanding or quality-enhancing investments may ameliorate such a problem
somewhat. In addition, some new investments may be undertaken based on the cost
savings they deliver to the airport operator, rather than the revenue they generate.
The ACCC does not allow price increases for cost-saving investments
(ACCC 2000b).
On the second point, it is not clear that airports have an incentive, either with or
without the current price regulation, to undertake extravagant investment — so-
called gold plating. Only if they consider that regulators will grant prices that will
provide above normal returns on assets — prices that they believe can be realised in
the market — are airports likely to over-invest. Capital market pressures on
privatised airports — many of which are dominated by sophisticated shareholders
such as fund managers and large corporations — should discourage unproductive
expenditure (chapter 7).
However, NNI provisions could encourage inefficient substitution of new capital for
other inputs, given the scope to receive price increases for new investment. WAC
considered that the ACCC’s interpretation of the term ‘investment’ was too
restrictive:
… the narrow definition suggested provides an incentive to airport lessee companies to
select more costly solutions that unquestionably qualify as capital rather than what may
The ACCC (2000a) indicated that it considered each NNI proposal on its merits and
could allow pass-through into higher prices of incremental operating and
maintenance expenditure flowing from new investment. Appropriately applied, this
approach could avoid biasing expenditure choices between alternative methods of
undertaking a proposal which qualified as new investment. However, it would not
deal with distortions to the choice between an option that would not qualify as new
investment and an alternative approach that would.
Airport operators also may have an incentive to try to convince regulators to allow
them inefficiently high prices for new investment. While for firms in competitive
markets charging inefficiently high prices would result in lower profits, a firm with
market power could increase profits if allowed to follow such a strategy.16 Of
course, there is an incentive to submit ambit claims if the regulatory arbitration
process involves determinations that fall somewhere between the competing claims
of airports and users.
If the airline market were competitive (that is, if airlines had negligible market
power), and if they were targeting similar parts of the market, the interests of
airlines should lead to their agreement to required investment at efficient prices at
the appropriate time. Delays in approving efficient NNI prices would not be in the
airlines’ interests. Hence, the requirement in the pricing guidelines that users with a
significant interest support the new investment and associated charges would seem a
potentially useful criterion for assessing new investment proposals. BARA argued:
The interests of BARA members are promoted by encouraging airports to invest when
it is efficient to do so. No one stands to lose more than the airlines if necessary new
investment is not delivered in a timely manner. It would make no sense for airlines to
support a regulatory system that ultimately failed to deliver an adequate stream of
investment in airport services. (sub. 41, p. 38)
However, there are several reasons why airlines, particularly incumbent airlines,
might have incentives that conflict with efficient provision and pricing of new
investment. If an investment in increasing aeronautical capacity provides benefits to
new entrants, existing airlines will have an incentive to delay that investment. Even
if the existing airlines expect to receive net benefits in a direct sense from such an
16 As noted in chapter 7 there are various other incentives (such as the potential to earn non-
aeronautical revenue) and constraints which will lessen the extent to which airports seek to
maximise aeronautical profits.
234 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
investment, the total impact on them may be negative because of the facilitation of
increased competition. The significant reductions in airfares that have occurred on
routes with new entrants indicate the size of these potential costs for incumbent
operators.
Qantas Airways (sub. 48, p. 21) stated that airport operators’ claims that it had been
involved in gaming were ‘entirely without merit’. It argued that access to terminal
facilities was the only airport barrier to the entry of new airlines and observed that
Qantas had not participated in regulatory decisions regarding investment and
pricing for new domestic terminals. Impulse’s view (sub. 18), discussed below, was
that incumbent airlines had frustrated some airport investment in order to inhibit
new entry.
The ACCC (sub. 36, appendix D) pointed out that the shared nature of airport
terminals has encouraged strategic behaviour by potential tenants trying to minimise
their share of the terminal costs. Such behaviour has been observed in negotiations
regarding the new terminals at Melbourne and Adelaide airports. It is difficult for a
regulator (or an airport) to disentangle the genuine from the strategic aspects of such
claims. Different airlines do have different requirements for terminal and other
facilities, but they are likely to exaggerate these when negotiating airport charges —
even in the absence of a regulator.
The ACCC also noted that there can be incentives for higher-cost operators to try to
raise the costs of low-cost competitors, even if this means increasing their own
costs.17 Virgin Blue observed:
The Adelaide terminal is one which is considerably out of whack with the operating
strategy of Virgin Blue and is significantly higher cost, and that is a very real concern,
17 The higher-cost operator may not be less efficient but may simply offer a higher level of
service as part of its business strategy.
REVIEW OF AIRPORT 235
PRICE REGULATION
where a major incumbent airline actually might have the capacity to impose a
significant increase in the operating costs of a new entrant airline. (trans., p. 354)
In addition, the incumbent airlines have had a long history of dealing with an airport
operator pricing on a single-till basis. Switching to an NNI regime predicated on
new aeronautical facilities covering their full cost through aeronautical price
increases is a significant shift in approach which might be expected to encounter
some resistance.
SACL suggested that this problem was compounded by conflicting objectives of the
regulator.
Under the existing regulatory structure, airlines do not have an incentive to reach a
compromise position during negotiations, as the ACCC’s assessment process of price
notifications may achieve a better outcome for them because of the conflict between the
ACCC’s consumer advocacy and efficiency considerations. (sub. DR62, p. ii)
Such behaviour may have been sensible for airlines in the case of some investments
if they saw airport operators as effectively captured in their financial investment in
an airport, and constrained by current lease and safety requirements to undertake
certain capital expenditures, even if the investments are not financially viable at
current aeronautical prices. For example, WAC (sub. 21) indicated that due to
safety, security, environmental or regulatory requirements, it had undertaken capital
investments that were not approved for NNI pass-through and did not provide an
adequate return at current aeronautical prices.
The DoTRD Pricing Policy Paper (1996), and the PS Act criteria (s. 17(3)) and
associated Ministerial Directions, provide limited guidance for applying the NNI
provisions. NNI was not defined and the extent of investment expenditure included
in the X factors generally has not been forthcoming. Finalised ACCC guidelines
were not published until April 2000 — nearly three years after the first leases
commenced. These guidelines included the threshold matters of defining
‘necessary’, ‘new’ and ‘investment’ and, in applying a cost-based regulation
approach, a variety of other issues, such as cost of capital and common cost
allocations between aeronautical and non-aeronautical services. Hence, while initial
uncertainty was to be expected in applying the new system, this has been
heightened by the lack of guidelines on important parameters.
This may not have been a problem if the intention underlying the DoTRD Pricing
Policy Paper (1996) — that commercial relationships between airports and their
immediate customers would generate negotiated outcomes — had been achieved.
However, in general, successful negotiations on major issues have not been the rule
and regulatory intervention has been continually required.
The ACCC (2000b) indicated that user support would be an important determinant
in its assessment of whether a particular project should be classed as new
investment. If such support were not forthcoming, the ACCC defined new
investment as a change in fixed durable inputs that does not simply seek to replace
natural degradation of capital. WAC (sub. 21) claimed that airport buyers when
bidding for leases assumed that NNI provisions included replacement investment.
However, ACCC (2000b) cited DoTRS in (April 1999) correspondence to the
industry as expecting essential and on-going investment to be funded from ongoing
revenue streams.
On the other hand, Qantas (sub. 48) considered that current prices already contained
a component for depreciation of existing assets that would allow for re-investment.
However, while existing aeronautical prices may provide some return on
replacement investment, the important issue for generating efficient levels of
investment is the sufficiency of that expected return in the future.18
The application of NNI procedures also has suffered from a lack of clarity in the
original pricing guidelines and subsequent legislative instruments. The pricing
guidelines have no legislative effect and, in applying the NNI regime, the ACCC
has had to operate under the PS Act and related Directions. These Directions do not
refer to certain of the objectives and policy intentions of the prices-oversight
regime, such as encouraging commercial negotiations. However, the ACCC
(sub. 36) expressed concern regarding the deterministic nature of existing
Ministerial Directions for airports and considered that this sat uneasily with the
discretion given to the ACCC under the PS Act.
18 Because it followed a network-wide single-till approach, the FAC undertook significant new
and replacement aeronautical investment even though aeronautical prices may not have
provided the revenue needed to justify them. Profits from non-aeronautical activities made up
the shortfall and enabled the FAC to achieve the accounting rate-of-return objectives imposed
by the Commonwealth Government.
238 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
The problems in using the PS Act also are highlighted by the Commission in its
review of the PS Act (PC 2001c). It observes that the PS Act has many deficiencies
as a means for prices oversight and argues that there is little justification for it as a
generic price-oversight mechanism. Thus, in the few cases where any price control
might be deemed necessary, it argued that this would be best implemented via
industry-specific legislation.
Participants’ views
Airlines’ views
The DoTRD Pricing Policy Paper (1996) placed emphasis on user support for new
investment and charges. Among airlines, incumbents and new entrants had
conflicting judgements. BARA stated:
In BARA’s view the current regulation of the privatised airports in Australia has acted
to constrain, to some extent, the market power of the airports while encouraging
efficient investment in airport expansion. (sub. 26, p. 1)
Ansett considered that the regulatory regime provided some incentive for airlines to
oppose excessive prices that otherwise would be lacking.
In the case of the regulated Australian airports, the current economic regulatory regime
provides the Ansett/Air New Zealand Group with an incentive to scrutinise the costs
and prices of airports. This is because the regime allows the airlines to have sufficient
influence over these costs to justify the resources required to scrutinise them …
(sub. 42, p. 38)
Qantas (sub. 48) considered that there was some room for improvement in the
administrative approach to assessing NNI applications, but that airports’ complaints
of the process retarding investment, or of airlines ‘gaming’ the system, were invalid.
Impulse Airlines, then a new entrant into domestic trunk routes, was critical:
Impulse’s introduction in the Canberra marketplace also affords an interesting example
of lack of support for infrastructure development. Canberra International Airport had
tried for 2 ½ years before the arrival of Impulse to gain support from both Qantas and
Ansett to re-develop apron space which had been in its current state for 28 years. It was
not until the introduction of Impulse that CIA felt able to take their case to the ACCC.
Impulse (sub. 18) also felt that the price cap had meant that infrastructure quality
had to be compromised at the new Melbourne and Sydney express terminals.
Virgin Blue (sub. 30) (a new low-fare carrier) contended that NNI pass-throughs
outside the price cap should be allowed only for investments that would not be
undertaken without the pass-through. It considered that incremental non-
aeronautical revenues should be considered when examining NNI proposals such as
Melbourne Airport’s domestic express terminal.
Such differing views of two new airlines regarding pricing of the same investment,
indicate the difficulty for the regulator in identifying facts, the targeting of different
market segments, and gaming behaviour. Impulse and Virgin Blue had different
business strategies which may have led to their divergent attitudes to the Melbourne
express terminal, but they may also have attempted to use the regulatory framework
to their advantage. Similar issues arose regarding Virgin Blue’s use of the proposed
Adelaide multi-user terminal.
However, the ACCC argued that its involvement had not deterred investment:
The investments undertaken by airport operators to date suggest that the Commission’s
[ACCC] pricing decisions have not deterred investment in airports. In particular the
experience suggests that the Commission [ACCC] has adequately allowed for the risks
facing airport operators. (sub. 36, p. 29)
In varying degrees, all airport operators have been critical of the NNI regime, in
particular the way in which it has been implemented. Northern Territory Airports
submitted:
We find the ACCC’s comments about its own supervision of new investment at
Australia’s airports at odds with the reality we have had to go through. (sub. 50, p. 17)
It indicated (sub. 50) that because of the cost, delays and uncertainty of the
application of the NNI process, it had deferred a number of investment projects
indefinitely. These included projects approved for price increases by the ACCC but
for which costs (and hence the necessary price increase) had risen during the
extended regulatory process. Because of significant reductions in traffic, these
investments have still not proceeded despite the October 2001 regulatory changes
(which removed the price cap from Darwin Airport).
BAC (trans., p. 206) indicated that it was following a similar approach, while Gold
Coast Airport stated:
There is no certainty that commercial terms agreed with users will be endorsed by the
ACCC …
Because of this uncertainty GCAL [Gold Coast Airport Limited] has deferred initiating
any necessary new investment until the process becomes more clearly defined. This
decision will mean additional maintenance costs are incurred in the short to medium
term as current pavements are showing signs of stress due to increasing use of heavier
aircraft by both Qantas and Ansett. (sub. 16, p. 12)
Ansett (sub. 42) stated that despite some initial problems, the relationships between
airlines and airports under the current regulatory arrangements were improving and
are better than those in New Zealand under a less intrusive regime.
Professor Forsyth (sub. 5) argued that negotiated agreements where users are
willing to pay the costs of investments are preferable to regulatory intervention.
Negotiated agreements use the greater knowledge of the participants rather than the
often imperfect information available to the regulator. However, evidence suggests
that, in the current regulatory framework, the relatively easy recourse to the ACCC
The Commission’s review of the National Access Regime (PC 2001a) analyses the
potential disincentives that regulation can have on investment in infrastructure. In
particular, it observes that additional risk is created by the uncertainty about
regulatory decisions and future changes in the regulatory framework, both of which
can have significant impacts on the profitability of long-lived investment.
Compliance costs
There has also been concern, particularly among smaller airports, regarding the cost
to airport operators of the NNI process. Airport operators have also complained of
the expense of even minor projects needing to go through the full NNI process.
Because of concern about setting national precedents, domestic airlines may oppose
even small NNI increases at small airports. Possible international precedents might
give incentives for international airlines (through BARA) to take a similar
approach. Melbourne Airport submitted:
It must also be added that airlines (we suspect at the urging of IATA) often see any
regulatory decision as having the potential to be a global precedent, and therefore often
argue points that they privately concede, have no merit. (sub. 7, p. 33)
The requirement for even small investments to be subject to full NNI reviews if cost
pass-throughs are sought, appears to have added to the regulatory costs and
detracted from the quality of outcomes of the regime. WAC (sub. 21) argued that all
projects were considered equally under the regulatory guidelines regardless of size.
Capital Airport Group (sub. 32) indicated that in its experience even small NNI
projects had been subject to excessively detailed scrutiny.
The potential benefit of the NNI process of preventing inappropriate price increases
while encouraging appropriate new investments to be undertaken, needs to be
balanced against the direct and other costs of the regulation process. In the case of
small investments, potential benefits are very small while the direct regulatory costs
may be relatively high. This is particularly so for smaller airports that are less likely
to be able to group a range of small projects to reduce the size of direct regulatory
costs relative to the investment concerned.
Melbourne Airport (sub. 7) stated that a conservative estimate of the combined cost
of Melbourne and Launceston airports complying with the price-regulation regime
(including quality monitoring) was $500 000 per annum.
For aeronautical services as a whole, the NNI regime has moved prices somewhat
above the single-till approach to pricing used by the FAC. The broad thrust of the X
factors in the CPI-X formula would appear to have been to generate aeronautical
prices that essentially maintained the extent of single-till cross subsidies between
services contained in the FAC prices existing at the start of privatisation. Increases
in non-aeronautical profits gained since then were not factored into the Xs. Price
increases obtained under NNI would have further ameliorated this situation, but
only for the expansion in the capital base involved.
To the extent that the single-till starting prices of the current regime did not allow
for a sufficient return on replacement investment, the exclusion of replacement
investment from the interpretation of new investment means that the current NNI
process could never generate aeronautical prices that covered full aeronautical costs.
If lessees bid on the basis that NNI provisions excluded replacement investment, the
bid prices should have reflected this and, at least for the five years of the initial
regulatory framework, necessary replacement investment should have been
undertaken at existing aeronautical prices. However, in the absence of clear and
transparent statements of what was included in the Xs and the lack of initial detailed
guidelines on the application of the NNI process, it is difficult to determine what
should be expected of airport lessees in regard to undertaking replacement
investment.
As the key interface between airports, airlines and the regulator, the NNI provisions
have not generated the commercial relationships and light-handed regulation
envisaged by the DoTRD Pricing Policy Paper (1996). No doubt some of these
problems reflect teething difficulties of a new regulatory system. Definitions and
procedural guidelines needed to be developed and experience had to be obtained in
working with the new system. The parties needed to adjust to the new environment
— the airports from the FAC network framework and the airlines (operating in a
rapidly changing airline industry) to dealing with fellow private companies rather
than a government enterprise.
Because of the short period in which it has been in operation, whether the NNI
process has stimulated efficient levels of new investment is not clear. Complaints
from most airlines have concerned the aeronautical prices sought to cover new
investment rather than a failure by airports to invest. The observed level of new
investment may still have been forthcoming if base aeronautical prices initially were
set high enough to justify new investment rather than relying on pass-through
provisions to increase prices selectively in return for approved new investment.
Market incentives for airport operators not to restrict output and investment
artificially are discussed in chapter 7. Certainly the NNI approach has generated
significant regulatory intervention with its associated costs and increased regulatory
risk. Given the apparently inefficiently low starting prices, a major area of concern
for investment expenditure is the combined impact of the CPI-X and NNI
provisions on returns for replacement investment.
The combination of the price cap and NNI rules would seem to have avoided any
exploitation of market power that airport operators might have attempted in the
absence of such regulations. However, in the short period in which the regulation
has been operating, the NNI process appears to have created significant regulatory
hurdles for aeronautical investments.
FINDING 8.2
The necessary new investment provisions have not promoted the commercially-
negotiated outcomes that were envisaged by the architects of the regime. This has
been partly due to the need to develop criteria and procedures for necessary new
investment after purchase and for participants to adapt to the very different
business environment following airport privatisation.
However, the observed difficulties also point to some fundamental problems. In
particular:
• the lack of transparency regarding what investment was considered to be
included in the base aeronautical prices and what was to be covered by
necessary new investment, with resultant effects on incentives to invest;
• the incentives for some participants to approach the regulator rather than
achieve commercially-negotiated solutions;
• the high costs of complying with the regime; and
• the regulatory risk due to the uncertainty and delays introduced by the need to
have every investment-related price increase vetted by the regulator.
In December 1998, DoTRS made changes to security regulations that placed the
responsibility for international passenger and baggage screening at international
terminals on airport operators. WAC claimed that the ACCC’s initial decision on
allowable rates of return on the capital investment required had created inefficient
results:
The ACCC initially refused to allow airports to earn a return on capital invested to
purchase security equipment of greater than the cost of debt. This created a
dis-incentive for airport operators to invest in the required capital equipment, thus
allowing the security contractors to supply and charge for the equipment at rates which,
presumably did allow for an equity return. (sub. 21, p. 25)
WAC indicated that the ACCC later allowed somewhat higher rates of return.
However, by then a number of airports had committed to external security
contractors to provide the equipment as the return on contractor’s capital embedded
in their charges was fully recoverable in higher aeronautical prices.
The Government directed the ACCC to allow the three Phase 1 airports still
remaining under the current price cap (due to expire in June 2002) increases in
aeronautical charges above the levels currently allowed by the cap. These increases
— treated as one-off pass-throughs under the cap — were 6.7 per cent for Brisbane
Airport, 6.2 per cent for Melbourne Airport and 7.2 per cent for Perth Airport.19
Price monitoring remains for aeronautical-related services at these airports.
For all of the Phase 2 airports, the price cap on aeronautical services previously
scheduled to operate until June 2003 has been removed. For three of these,
Adelaide, Canberra and Darwin, the cap has been replaced by price monitoring of
aeronautical services by the ACCC. This is discussed further in chapter 9.
While the effects of the new regulatory environment will take some time to work
themselves out, there have been some immediate effects on prices under the price
cap which are discussed below. A proper evaluation of the new arrangements will
require a considerably longer period of operation.
Melbourne Airport has utilised the additional 6.2 per cent price cap pass-through
allowed to it under the October regulatory changes to rebalance charges between
domestic and international services. Landing charges will increase by around
11 per cent from the start of 2002. However, for international services, the terminal
charge has been reduced by an equivalent amount meaning there will be no net
increase in aeronautical charges for international flights. The difficult international
aviation climate and the opportunity to increase Melbourne’s and Australia’s share
of the international aviation market were cited (Barlow 2001) as the rationale for
this price discrimination.
Perth Airport also increased aeronautical charges by the full 7.2 per cent of base
period prices allowed by Direction No. 24. Like Melbourne Airport it made no
increase in the charges for international services but increased landing fees for
domestic regular public transport services by around 19 per cent from November
2001.
19 The ACCC has interpreted the percentage price increases allowed by Direction No. 24 to refer
to the prices applying when the airports were privatised in July 1997 and has deemed that the
resultant dollar amount increases include GST. As a result the price increases expressed as a
percentage of current prices have been less than the percentages in Direction No. 24.
REVIEW OF AIRPORT 247
PRICE REGULATION
WAC indicated that the adjustment to charges allowed by Direction No. 24 made
up only a small portion of the revenue lost due to recent declines in aeronautical
traffic:
It merely reflects the fact that there has been an extraordinary drop in airport volumes,
and provides a small pricing adjustment as a partial compensation for that.
(trans., p. 574)
Melbourne Airport was critical of the manner in which the new regulatory
arrangements were introduced:
In our view in particular the Treasury should make clear the reasons and the
methodology used to arrive at this situation, because otherwise we’re just going to end
up with another situation which is exactly analogous to that debate around what’s in the
value of X … Indeed, all that’s happened really is that regulatory uncertainty has been
increased … (trans., p. 403)
The basis for the one-off price increases above the cap has not been revealed and
this presents similar concerns to those raised above for the determination of the Xs
in the price-cap formula. This may increase unnecessarily regulatory uncertainty for
both airports and their users. Also, establishing good commercial relations between
the parties may be made more difficult if there is lack of transparency in important
elements of the regulatory framework.
Since it took over the operation of Sydney Airport, SACL has been subject to prices
notification for aeronautical services and monitoring for aeronautical-related
services under the PS Act for the same groups of services as the privatised airports
(chapter 3). It has not had a price cap imposed but, like all declared companies, it
must inform the ACCC of proposed price increases for notified aeronautical
services. This regime is more extensive than the price regulation that applied to the
FAC. Additional elements include the introduction of price monitoring for some
services, the inclusion of necessary new investment as a justification for price
increases and the monitoring of service quality under the Airports Act.
As mentioned above, in January 1997 the FAC (with ACCC approval) increased
aeronautical charges at Sydney and three other major airports (chapter 2). These
were the last price increases before the FAC was disbanded. In the case of Sydney
Airport, the FAC made a further price notification which resulted in a large
restructuring of aeronautical charges from October 1998, but one that did not lead to
an overall increase in revenue. Landing fees were cut by around 50 per cent but
international terminal charges were increased by up to 30 per cent, leading to a net
increase in aeronautical charges for international services and significantly lower
charges for domestic flights. In addition, the peak-period landing surcharge of $250
(applicable to all aircraft) was abolished amid Government concerns about its
impact on regional airlines.
The major objective of this restructuring was for charges to international aircraft to
reflect more closely the cost of terminal facilities used by them. However, the
resultant landing charge of $2.92 per tonne (MTOW) was only a little over half of
those at the other core-regulated airports. Hence, while the price restructuring
resulted in reasonable returns on investment in the international terminal, it also
created very low returns from aeronautical revenue on other aeronautical
investment.
The SACL proposal was based on the ACCC’s cost building-block approach to
determining allowable prices. This involves establishing the efficient projected level
of various cost components (for example, operating costs, depreciation and return
on capital) and then determining prices which, based on projected volumes, would
provide the revenue needed to cover these costs.
Hence, while for the first five years of operation aeronautical price regulation at the
other core-regulated airports is being based on incremental changes (determined by
the price cap and cost pass-through provisions) to FAC prices, Sydney Airport
regulation has now moved to a complete rebasing of prices. In particular, its
aeronautical prices are now freed from the inter-service subsidies that were part of
the FAC approach to pricing. Because non-aeronautical revenue traditionally had
provided significant profits at Sydney Airport, large aeronautical price increases
were required to generate adequate profits on aeronautical activities on a stand-
alone basis.21
20 SACL made further adjustments to various cost components of its proposal during the ACCC’s
consultation process.
21 ACCC (1998h) indicated that, in 1998-99, Sydney Airport was forecast to recover only
88.6 per cent of aeronautical costs, excluding a rate of return on capital. Higher depreciation
charges on significant quality-enhancing capital investment undertaken between 1998 and 2000
also required higher prices.
250 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
In determining allowable aeronautical prices for SACL, the ACCC modelled
allowable revenue over a five-year period.22 It then generated a constant nominal
price for five years which was forecast to provide SACL with a net present value of
cash flows equivalent to this projected allowable revenue stream. The ACCC stated:
The Commission [ACCC] considers that — in the event that the current regulatory
arrangements remain in place — it would be appropriate for prices of aeronautical
services at Sydney Airport to be subject to further review at the end of five years
following the introduction of the new charges. (ACCC 2001i, p. 203)
The current regulatory framework allows for applications for NNI cost pass-
throughs into prices during this period.
While the Commission does not see the need for a detailed commentary on the
ACCC decision in this report, some aspects of the decision and related issues are of
particular relevance to future price regulation at Sydney Airport and any other core-
regulated airports for which ongoing price declarations or monitoring might be
considered appropriate. These are discussed below and in appendix F (land
valuation).
SACL’s aeronautical price proposal, in arguing for an average 130 per cent increase
in aeronautical charges, moved to a dual-till approach. Costs and revenues of non-
aeronautical services (including aeronautical-related services) were not considered
when justifying the proposed prices. The ACCC draft report (ACCC 2001h) largely
accepted the SACL approach but did take into account returns on certain
aeronautical-related services in determining aeronautical prices to which it would
22 In undertaking this exercise the ACCC used projections of traffic volumes and productivity
growth and made some allowance for increases in SACL’s input prices.
23 Partly reflecting its high land values, Sydney Airport tended only to achieve rates of return on
assets similar to the network average. Hence its charges were not cross subsidising other
airports. The January 1997 price increases, which applied only to the five major airports, lifted
Sydney’s rate of return by around 1 per cent.
REVIEW OF AIRPORT 251
PRICE REGULATION
not object. Following a Government Direction (No. 22, April 2001) not to take any
non-aeronautical services into account, the ACCC final report (ACCC 2001i)
adopted the conventionally accepted dual-till approach proposed by SACL.
In its draft report, the ACCC argued that SACL possessed market power in the
provision of certain non-aeronautical activities, such as car parking, and that
above-normal returns in these activities should be subtracted from allowable
revenue in calculating aeronautical prices. In response to Direction No. 22, the
ACCC reversed this approach in its final decision.
The Commission has several concerns with the ACCC’s draft report approach. First,
it is important to establish that any above-normal returns in non-aeronautical
services reflect the exercise of market power and not just locational rents (transitory
or long-term) or short-term capacity shortages. If it is the latter, then confiscating
the returns is likely to cause inefficient investment and operating decisions,
particularly where a facility, such as Sydney Airport, is capacity-constrained.
24 Under a dual-till system, to the extent that aeronautical investment has complementary impacts
on non-aeronautical profits, the airport operator would take these into account when assessing
whether to undertake this investment.
252 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
The ACCC (sub. DR55) contended that its draft SACL decision was for discussion
by participants and not part of its final decision and, hence, was not relevant to the
current inquiry. However, in reaching its final decision based on giving special
weight to the Government’s policy set out in Direction No. 22, the ACCC argued:
The Commission [ACCC] considers that this policy may differ from the approach that
would be appropriate in order to give effect to the objectives set out in chapter 2 [of
ACCC (2001i)]. (ACCC 2001i, p. 94)
This suggests that the ACCC still considers that inclusion of certain non-
aeronautical revenue in determining aeronautical prices has merit.
The implementation of dual-till pricing at Sydney Airport means that the outcome
of price regulation now differs markedly from that at the privatised airports. The
dual till removes the constraints on new or replacement aeronautical investment that
may occur under a pure single till or the current legacy of the FAC’s single till.
These issues are discussed further in chapter 10 and appendix C.
Cost of capital
Particularly for an airport with high asset values like Sydney, returns on capital are
a significant component of costs. The quantum of returns to capital allowed in the
building block approach is a function of asset values and the allowable rate of
return. There are a number of complex and strongly debated theoretical and
empirical issues to be resolved in estimating appropriate rates of return. This
potentially makes for a significant range of possible rates to be applied by the
regulator.
In the Sydney Airport decision, the ACCC’s assessment of SACL’s real weighted
average cost of capital was 6.8 per cent compared to SACL’s proposal of
7.75 per cent — resulting in a reduction in allowable annual revenue (on the
ACCC’s assessed asset base) of a little over $13 million, leading to aeronautical
prices about 6 per cent lower than sought by SACL.
Land valuation
BARA (2000) argued that because the airport would continue to operate as an
airport regardless of the return on land, its existing land should be valued at an
opportunity cost of zero (although any new land acquisitions should be included at
purchase price).25 On the other hand, SACL (2000) argued that, being a
non-specialised asset, the relevant valuation of aeronautical land for cost-based
price setting was market value. Efficiency and distributional arguments have been
presented for and against these approaches (appendix F).
The ACCC (2001i) considered SACL to be highly constrained in its land use, both
in regard to sale of the airport and within airport use. It argued that this limited the
relevance of alternate use land values in setting regulated prices. In addition, it
identified a number of complications in determining the opportunity cost of land for
setting efficient aeronautical prices (appendix F).
As a result, the ACCC adopted an approach of establishing the historical cost of the
various purchases of land that went into making up Sydney Airport and then
25 A similar view regarding the appropriate valuation of land at all airports was put by IATA
(sub. DR56). It argued that land should be treated as a non-interest bearing investment with no
cost being borne by aeronautical users.
254 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
indexing these costs to the present day using the CPI. In effect, the value of land
purchases dating back as far as 80 years was maintained relative to an average
consumer goods basket. Any new acquisitions and switches between uses of airport
land will be valued at current prices at the time of purchase and then indexed by the
CPI. The ACCC considered that this approach would provide appropriate signals
for efficient use of the existing site and for new aeronautical investment. However,
while this is an arithmetically deterministic approach, it essentially provides an
‘arbitrated’ solution to land values which lies somewhere between the competing
claims.
The ACCC (sub. DR55) argued that the indexed historical cost approach was based
on economic principles, in particular, that it provided appropriate incentives for new
investment. For marginal land purchases, historical cost initially will equate to
opportunity cost but, over time, that link will be lost if land prices move
differentially from the CPI. Moreover, historical cost will not reflect opportunity
cost for transfers of existing land between aeronautical and non-aeronautical uses
nor will it represent the economic value of the current site. For the existing site, the
use of indexed historical cost to value land for price regulation renders false
precision to an inherently arbitrary valuation. As noted by Dr Gannon for the
ACCC:
Without a satisfactory empirical methodology for estimating opportunity cost,
alternative bases of valuation (such as indexed historical cost) are obliged to be adopted
by default. These are poor surrogates as they are unlikely to bear a reliable relationship
to the underlying opportunity cost. (sub. DR55, attachment B, p. 1)
In the case of Sydney Airport, the paucity of data on the purchase price of the
airport site makes indexed historical-cost-based estimates particularly problematic.
The ACCC (2001h) claimed that an important advantage of historical cost was that
it was readily identifiable. However, SACL (2001) observed that the prices paid for
a significant portion of the airport site were not known. As a result, the ACCC
(2001i) had to apply price data available for a portion of the site to estimate the
historical cost of the remaining land.
The ACCC also was critical that the Commission did not provide a more detailed
examination of implementing the opportunity cost principle. Dr Gannon argued:
… there are also formidable methodological difficulties in practical empirical
application of the principle to estimation of the value of the total land at a major capital
city airport site. Unfortunately, these practical difficulties are not discussed in the PC
Draft Report. (sub. DR55, attachment B, p. 1)
The Commission considers that, realistically, the current inquiry can examine only
the broad principles of price setting and regulation rather than undertake detailed
analysis of the numerous individual elements such as land valuation. If detailed
In addition, other activities in the economy are typically priced and operated on the
basis of obtaining returns on the opportunity cost of the land they use. If pricing of
aeronautical services fails to take account of such returns, then demand for those
services (and demand for other inputs used to produce them) will be inefficiently
raised relative to other activities.
Valuation of Sydney Airport land also raises distributional issues. As the airport is
owned by the Commonwealth Government, if land is under-valued and this is
reflected in pricing, there will be a redistribution (particularly of peak-period rents)
Given that the Government is in the process of selling Sydney Airport, it would
seem preferable for aeronautical prices to reflect appropriate land values now and
hence be fully incorporated in the sale price received by the community, rather than
be adjusted later and possibly provide windfall profits to the private operator.
FINDING 8.3
Price restructuring
In its 1996 and 1998 price notifications for Sydney Airport, the FAC made some
restructuring of aeronautical charges in an effort to align more closely revenue from
particular aeronautical services with the costs of those services. These changes were
relatively simple and involved increases in charges for use of the international
terminal while (in 1998) making offsetting large reductions in landing charges. In
not objecting to these restructurings, the ACCC strongly supported the move
towards user-pays pricing in order to provide appropriate signals for efficient use of
airport services and for new investment decisions.27 BARA, Ansett and Qantas did
not oppose the 1998 changes to price structures.
In its October 2000 price proposal, SACL (2000) made further changes aimed at
aligning prices with costs and also to improve the efficiency of use of congested
facilities. The Commission considers that such developments in pricing offer
important improvements in the efficiency of use of airport facilities, particularly at
an often congested facility like Sydney Airport. More flexibility in pricing and
operations should help bring forth the greater efficiency benefits from privatisation.
26 Some of the peak period rents that accrue to airlines may have supported flights between other
cities on which yields may cover marginal, but not average, costs.
27 The ACCC objected to the quantum of the proposed 1996 FAC price increases but not the
concept of restructuring prices.
REVIEW OF AIRPORT 257
PRICE REGULATION
Specific charges for use of facilities, such as aerobridges, provide airport users with
the appropriate information for making efficient decisions about consuming
particular services. Time-based charges for use of scarce capacity, such as apron
space, dissuade excessive use of the facility and encourage more efficient methods
of operation, ration existing capacity to those who value it most and provide
appropriate investment signals to the airport operator to expand capacity where
possible.
SACL also changed the basis of the international terminal charge from a per tonne
(maximum take-off weight (MTOW)) per landing charge to a per passenger levy,
and the runway charge from per tonne (MTOW) per landing to a per tonne
(MTOW) per movement (landing and take-off). The switch to a per passenger
charge reflected the view that terminal costs were more directly related to passenger
numbers. As noted below, with airline agreement, other charges for international
airlines have also been switched to a per passenger basis. By moving to per
passenger charges, SACL effectively has transformed the terminal charge to a short-
term marginal cost to airlines when considering attracting additional passengers. In
turn, this may affect the extent of airlines’ price discrimination aimed at attracting
marginal passengers as the relevant charges now vary directly with passenger
numbers rather than being fixed imposts per aircraft of a particular size.
The ACCC did not object to any of SACL’s proposals aimed at improving the
efficiency of the price structure.
In August 2001, the ACCC did not object to a revenue neutral proposal by SACL to
institute a per passenger service charge for international passengers to replace a
series of existing MTOW-based charges covering landing and take off, terminal use
and security services. However, for domestic services, the ACCC did object to a
proposal to replace the existing aircraft weight-based charges for aircraft
movements and security services with a per passenger fee. It considered there were
concerns regarding the impact of the change on new airlines which currently had
more passengers per unit of aircraft weight than the incumbent operator. However,
the ACCC indicated that it was not able to address these concerns adequately in the
21-day statutory period available for considering pricing proposals under the PS
Act.
SACL (2000) has also indicated that it is considering the possibility of introducing
time-of-day charges and the ACCC has encouraged the development of peak-period
pricing for Sydney Airport.28 However, in the absence of peak pricing, the ACCC’s
28 Under its conditions of use of Sydney Airport, SACL has, at its discretion, introduced discounts
for airlines introducing new services during off-peak periods and for rescheduling services
from a peak to an off-peak period.
258 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
discounting of SACL’s proposed prices exacerbates the problem of excess demand.
To the extent that there already is excess demand for peak-period slots, the resultant
smaller increase in charges is likely to benefit airlines holding those slots rather than
be passed on to passengers travelling at those times.
FINDING 8.4
The aeronautical price increases implemented at Sydney Airport place its pricing
on a fundamentally different and more appropriate (dual-till) basis than that at
other core-regulated airports. The significant range of possible outcomes for a
number of cost parameters (for example, land values, cost of capital etc) indicates
the imprecision of regulatory price setting and the potential for inefficient prices
being established by regulation.
If significant excess demand returns at Sydney Airport at peak times,
production cost-related or rate-of-return based regulation would be likely to
constrain the setting of efficient aeronautical charges for those times.
Airport services are subject to access regulation and general competition law.
Although access regulation does not directly regulate prices of airport services, it
does provide for the regulation of terms and conditions, including prices, of access
to airport services. This chapter also analyses the application of these provisions to
core-regulated airports. General competition law has not been applied to airports to
date (see chapter 11 for further discussion of these provisions).
The criteria for efficient regulation (outlined in chapter 4) are used to evaluate price
monitoring, monitoring of service provision quality, and access regulation.
Since October, all three of the above airports have increased their airport charges
(chapter 2). As noted in chapter 5 in relation to the exercise of market power, the
effects of these changes will take some time to become fully apparent.
Under current monitoring provisions of the Prices Surveillance Act 1983 (PS Act),
the ACCC could respond to price changes by, for example, investigating some price
increases. The relevant Commonwealth Minister could then direct the ACCC to
undertake an inquiry. However, as noted in chapter 3, the Commonwealth
Government has said that it will take into account price changes, together with the
Productivity Commission’s final report, when considering future airport prices
oversight arrangements.
As noted above, the ACCC, in its monitoring role, has identified no particular
monopoly pricing problems apart from the imposition of fuel throughput levies. The
ACCC claimed that such levies represented an abuse of market power on the part of
airport operators, although this was disputed by airport operators. It recommended
that refuelling services be subject to greater prices oversight (appendix E). Although
not raised in its regulatory reports, the ACCC (sub. 36) also expressed concern
about another monitored aeronautical-related service provided by airport operators
— car-parking charges.
The preparation of standard information on prices, costs and profits (as set out in the
ACCC guidelines) does not appear to have been particularly costly for airport
operators, because the information requirements are not large. Nonetheless, Sydney
Airports Corporation Limited (SACL), operator of Sydney Airport, commented:
While the impact of prices monitoring is far less troublesome when compared to the
price approval process, it nevertheless does entail compliance costs for both airport
operators and the ACCC and experience to date suggests that such cost has generated
no net public benefit. (sub. 27, p. 49)
Compliance costs are likely to have been higher where airport operators have been
required to comply with additional information requests from the ACCC for its
public review of fuel throughput levies. Costs have also been incurred by the ACCC
in administering the price monitoring process, particularly when undertaking its
public review of fuel throughput levies.
One contentious issue arising from the current price monitoring process is the
potential for regulatory creep, that is, the potential for transferring aeronautical-
related services from outside the price cap to within it. Regardless of whether
additional regulation was warranted (chapter 6), uncertainty has been created for
airport operators in not knowing whether monitored services would remain outside
the price-cap basket. Moreover, any changes in Commonwealth Government policy
relating to the price-cap basket that result in direct adverse consequences for
particular parties raise issues of sovereign risk.
The issue of the imposition of fuel throughput levies by airport operators illustrates
the potential for such effects and its ramifications (appendix E). The ACCC, in
exercising its monitoring power under the PS Act, and bearing in mind the
Treasurer’s 1998 press release (Costello 1998), undertook a review of the
imposition of fuel throughput levies by two airport operators. A discussion paper
was released, submissions were sought, additional information was requested from
the relevant airport operators, a report was prepared with conclusions and
recommendations, and the report was released to the public and submitted to the
relevant Minister. Thus the review met many of the requirements for an inquiry as
set out in the PS Act, although the ACCC did not conduct a formal ‘inquiry’ under
the Act.
The ACCC approach to car parking and other price monitored aeronautical-related
services at Sydney Airport, in its draft response to SACL’s proposal to increase
aeronautical prices, also illustrates the potential for services subject to price
monitoring to become subject to stricter price regulation. Although the ACCC did
not recommend that any of these services become subject to prices notification, it
noted that, in the absence of a detailed analysis of aeronautical-related services at
Sydney Airport, ‘above normal’ revenues from aeronautical-related services should
be taken into account in determining allowable revenue from notified aeronautical
services (ACCC 2001h).2 However, the ACCC did not present evidence of abuse of
market power on the part of SACL in relation to any of these services, despite the
Treasurer having specified that abuse of market power would be the trigger for
stricter price regulation (see above). The ACCC moved away from this draft
decision in its final decision, following a Commonwealth Government Direction
that revenues from these aeronautical-related services should not be taken into
account (chapter 3).
The ACCC has reported on the quality of services provided by airport operators at
Melbourne, Brisbane and Perth airports (Phase 1) since 1997-98, and Sydney
Airport since 1998-99. Phase 2 airports were not required under the Airports
Regulations 1997 to provide quality of service information to the ACCC until the
end of 2000-01. The ACCC report is yet to be published.
According to the ACCC, in 1999-00 quality of service for the three Phase 1 airports
and Sydney Airport was ‘generally satisfactory’. Brisbane Airport appeared to rate
highest, with airport users (including airlines and passengers) ‘very satisfied’ with
most of the services and facilities provided. For example, passengers rated waiting
time at check-in facilities as ‘good’ to ‘excellent’, and airlines rated the quality of
runways, aprons and taxiways as ‘satisfactory’ to ‘excellent’. Quality remained
comparable to previous monitoring periods (ACCC 2001b).
The ACCC reported that Perth Airport users were satisfied with most of the services
and facilities provided. However, the ratings varied substantially for some services.
For example, the standard of runways was rated from ‘very poor’ to ‘good’. There
were marginal declines in the ratings from 1998-99 (ACCC 2001d).
At Melbourne Airport, users were also satisfied although there was a decline in
airline satisfaction, for example, with regard to gate allocation (ACCC 2001c). The
report for Sydney Airport was similar — users generally were satisfied although
airlines were dissatisfied with some services and facilities. Six airlines using
Sydney Airport rated gate availability as ‘very poor’ to ‘poor’, and seven rated
availability of aerobridges as ‘very poor’ to ‘poor’. The ACCC was unable to reach
a conclusion on whether service quality had declined from the previous reporting
period (ACCC 2001e).
Participants to this inquiry have also commented on the quality of services provided
by airport operators. Melbourne Airport noted that it had won a number of awards
3 The same services and facilities as were quality monitored prior to the regulatory changes of
October 2001.
266 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
each year from 1997 (sub. 7). SACL stated that it ‘provides high levels of quality of
service for passengers and airline customers’ (sub. 27, p. 33) and recently had
completed major improvements, including an upgrade of the international terminal,
that had significantly increased service quality. Brisbane Airport was named 2001
‘Airport of the Year — for Aviation Excellence’ by the Australian Airports
Association.
Qantas, on the other hand, commented that there had been a reduction in the quality
of services at some airports, and cited Westralia Airports Corporation, operator of
Perth Airport, as an example (trans., p. 262). The airline was also critical of the
quality of some services at Sydney Airport, as was BARA, which noted that the
baggage-handling system at Sydney Airport (international terminal) was
considerably worse than that at airports in other countries. BARA was also critical
of the quality of particular services at Melbourne Airport (trans., pp. 228–9).
However, BARA also noted that anecdotal evidence from members suggested that
the quality of services provided by privatised airports had improved (sub. 41).
First, airport operators do not have direct control of many of the services provided
at airports. For example, check-in, customs and immigration, cargo processing and
on-time airline services are not the sole responsibility of airport operators. Other
organisations involved, such as Airservices Australia and Australian Customs
Service, are noted in chapter 3. Yet the services they provide can affect the services
provided by airport operators. For example, aircraft delays can be affected by
factors beyond the control of airport operators, and passenger perceptions of delays
can be influenced by customs processing. This issue is recognised by the ACCC in
its regulatory reports.
Second, to date ACCC reports on quality appear to have placed emphasis on survey
results rather than on the objective indicators (described in chapter 3), perhaps
because there have been few significant changes in the objective indicators for
4 See, for example, CAA (2000d) and related submissions, and Betancor and Rendeiro (1999).
REVIEW OF AIRPORT 267
REGULATION
airports. Passengers’ perceptions are subjective and, as noted above, may be
influenced by factors outside the control of airport operators. Surveys of airlines’
views also constitute a subjective form of assessment. Although the regulatory
reports indicated that there were many favourable responses by airlines about
services provided by airport operators (also noted by Qantas, sub. 48), Melbourne
Airport commented:
It seems to us that individual airlines use this [airline surveys] as a device to have a
‘free kick’ at airports and often use it as a forum for a ‘pay back’ against an airport for
taking a particular line in a commercial negotiation. (sub. 7, p. 41)
The ACCC (2001e) commented in respect of its monitoring of Sydney Airport, that
at the time of the 1999-00 survey of airlines 15 of the 23 airline respondents to the
survey were taking legal action against SACL.
Both SACL (sub. 27) and Melbourne Airport (sub. 7) considered the airline
responses to be evidence of ‘regulatory gaming’. However, BARA considered that
airlines had ‘no real incentive to act in this manner’ (sub. 41, p. 58).
Fourth, there are some technical problems with airline and passenger surveys. For
example, as BARA noted, responses from airlines that rarely use an airport are
given equal weighting to major user airlines (sub. 41). Another problem relates to
the sample surveys of passengers at airports. Sampling biases may be associated
with passenger surveys, particularly as a result of the apparently non-systematic
way in which non-responses are handled in face-to-face interviews at airports.
Bearing in mind the above problems, the ACCC reports and inquiry participants’
comments suggest that the overall quality of service provided by operators at
Phase 1 airports has not deteriorated under the price cap since privatisation.
Several participants (for example, the Australian Airports Association (sub. 15) and
Northern Territory Airports (sub. 25)) commented that investment at airports had
been impeded by the regulatory regime in relation to necessary new investment
(NNI), and hence had restricted potential improvements in service quality. In other
words, future quality levels may be affected by application of past or current
regulatory arrangements. (Chapter 8 provides more detail on the effect of the
ACCC’s implementation of NNI provisions on investment by airport operators.)
5 Remote gates facilitate the embarking and disembarking of passengers when the gates adjacent
to a terminal are full, thereby enabling capacity to increase during peak-traffic periods. Remote
gates are distant from the terminal, usually requiring passengers to travel to and from the
terminal by bus.
REVIEW OF AIRPORT 269
REGULATION
Evaluation of ACCC monitoring
As noted above, there are some problems relating to the process that affect, or have
the potential to affect, the robustness of the ACCC’s monitoring process. It was also
noted that both BARA and Melbourne Airport were critical of various aspects of the
quality monitoring process.
BARA, more generally, commented that the process is ‘ineffectual’ and both parties
also noted that the ACCC did not appear to use much of the information collected.
BARA supported Melbourne Airport’s suggestion that:
If quality of service monitoring is to be a feature of any future regulatory system, which
we believe it should, the scope of monitoring and its objectivity needs to be seriously
examined. Any new set of arrangements must be auditable, systematic (rather than ad
hoc and anecdotal), and possess safeguards against gaming. (sub. 7, p. 41)
6 For a discussion about quality monitoring and standards, see CAA (2000d), and Betancor and
Rendeiro (1999).
7 APAC operates Melbourne and Launceston airports (through its subsidiaries Australia Pacific
Airports (Melbourne) and Australia Pacific Airports (Launceston) respectively).
270 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
The ACCC monitoring process inevitably imposes compliance costs on airport
operators, including direct staff costs, costs associated with outsourcing of
passenger surveys, and the cost of overheads. These costs appear to be modest at
major core-regulated airports. Melbourne Airport noted that ‘the marginal
regulatory cost is well below the full cost’ because, as noted above, it would
undertake quality of service monitoring in any event (sub. 7, p. 42). And Capital
Airport Group considered that reporting requirements were not ‘overly burdensome’
(sub. DR75, p. 9). The annual regulatory cost is likely to be of greater significance
to the smaller Phase 2 airports, such as Alice Springs and Launceston.
FINDING 9.1
Although the objectives of s. 192 are not enunciated in the Airports Act, the second
reading speech for the Airports Bill suggested the primary policy intent was to
facilitate access for new passenger airlines (HoR 1996, p. 1308). That the
Commonwealth Government introduced an airports-specific access regime for
privatised airports suggests it considered the Part IIIA provisions would not
adequately facilitate access to the services these airports provide. However, as
Part IIIA was in its infancy when s. 192 was introduced, the applicability to airports
was unclear at the time. As it turned out, Part IIIA has since been used to gain
access to airport facilities (see below).
Undertakings
Section 192 provides for airport operators to lodge undertakings setting out terms
and conditions under which access to airport services will be provided with the
ACCC (chapter 3). However, lodgement of undertakings has been limited (box 9.1).
APAC stated that it did not pursue lodgement of an undertaking beyond the draft
stage because:
… we had formed a view that any undertaking that would be acceptable to the ACCC
would actually leave us in a worse position than if we were to be subject to declaration
272 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
and subsequent arbitration. This was particularly the case where the ACCC was seeking
an undertaking that effectively extended into operational and commercial areas not
intended to be subject to Part IIIA. (APAC 2000b, p. 4)
The ACCC’s rejection of the draft undertakings submitted by Melbourne and Perth
airports appears to have discouraged other airport operators from submitting
undertakings. SACL stated:
The experiences of Melbourne and Perth airports in (unsuccessfully) pursuing access
undertakings resulted in no Phase 2 airports even attempting this route. The costs,
uncertainty and ultimate lack of flexibility have been factors in the deterrent. SACL has
similarly investigated the resources required to complete a successful Part IIIA
Undertaking and decided it is too onerous and uncertain to warrant pursuit.
(sub. 27, p. 46)
Airport operators’ ability to offer undertakings for some facilities was also limited
by other factors. For example, airport operators were not in a position to offer
undertakings for those domestic terminals for which long-term leases were held by
incumbent airlines (chapter 3).
The relatively short period in which undertakings could be lodged (12 and
24 months following privatisation for Phase 1 and 2 airports respectively), at a time
when airport operators were also required to develop draft airport master and
environment plans (chapter 3), and the fact that there was no scope for appeal
against an ACCC decision not to accept an undertaking, may also have been factors
contributing to the limited use of the undertakings provision.
The ACCC determines whether a given service is declared under s. 192 following a
request for a determination from an access seeker. As no undertakings were in place
at the end of the designated period, airport services at privatised core-regulated
airports were declared automatically. Rather than listing declared services, criteria
for declaration of services were specified in the legislation (chapter 3).
Access determinations
To date, application of the access provisions to airports has been limited. Delta Car
Rentals (Delta) and Virgin Blue sought determinations that services at Melbourne
Airport were covered by the automatic declaration of ‘airport services’ under s. 192.
Australian Cargo Terminal Operators (ACTO), now deregistered, sought
declaration of various services at Melbourne International Airport (MIA) and
Sydney International Airport (SIA) under Part IIIA (box 9.2).8
8 ACTO applied for voluntary deregistration in October 1999. Its status, according to the
Australian Securities and Investments Commission, is ‘deregistered’.
REVIEW OF AIRPORT 273
REGULATION
Box 9.2 Application of access regulation to airports
Section 192
Virgin Blue
On 2 March 2001, Virgin Blue lodged an application with the ACCC for a determination
that the service of the use of the new multi-user domestic terminal (MUDT) ‘for the
purposes of processing arriving and departing domestic airline passengers and their
baggage at Melbourne Airport’ was an ‘airport service’. The application followed
negotiations over the terms on which Melbourne Airport would grant Virgin Blue access
to the MUDT on a long-term basis.
The ACCC released its draft determination in October 2001, stating that, even though
the service met the criteria for definition as an ‘airport service’ under s. 192,
determining that domestic terminal facilities are ‘airport services’ was unlikely to result
in significant benefits. Thus the ACCC used its discretionary powers under s. 192 to
determine that the use of the MUDT was not an ‘airport service’ (ACCC 2001l).
(Continued next page)
Part IIIA
Although determinations under the access provisions to date have been limited, they
provide some insights into interpretation of the criteria by regulators and the courts,
compliance costs and declaration processes.
Delta determination
As outlined in box 9.2, Delta sought access to the landside drive area adjacent to the
terminals, while APAC argued that Delta should operate from the designated
The ACCC considered that Delta’s definition of the service as ‘the landside drive
area to pick up and drop off passengers’ was too narrow. It therefore used its
powers under ss 192(4A) and (4B) to define the service as ‘the provision of landside
roads and associated vehicle facilities for dropping off and picking up passengers at
Melbourne Airport’, where ‘landside roads and associated vehicle facilities include
landside roads, roads through carparks, kerbside parking areas, the designated
meeting point area (accessed via the carpark road) and any other vehicle access
facilities’ (Commonwealth of Australia Gazette, No. GN 25, 23 June 1999,
p. 1864).
As noted in box 9.2, Virgin Blue requested that the ACCC determine whether the
services provided by the use of the multi-user domestic terminal (MUDT) were
‘airport services’ under s. 192 of the Airports Act. The ACCC (2001l) has released
a provisional finding that the relevant service is not an airport service for the
purposes of s. 192.
Although a slightly broader definition of the service than proposed by Virgin Blue,
it is similar to the definition suggested by Australia Pacific Airports (Melbourne)
(the operator of Melbourne Airport), and consistent with Qantas’ proposal.
The ACCC also concluded that this service met the criteria for definition as an
‘airport service’ under s. 192(5) of the Airports Act. The ACCC found that the
relevant service was:
• necessary for civil aviation (as required under s. 192(5)(a)); and
• provided by significant facilities which cannot be economically duplicated (as
required under s. 192(5)(b)).
However, in reaching this provisional finding, the ACCC made use of its
discretionary powers granted under s. 192(4B) of the Airports Act. The ACCC
argued that services provided by the MUDT were regulated under the notification
provisions of the PS Act. Prices for the use of the MUDT had already been
approved by the ACCC under the NNI provisions of the notification. Hence, the
ACCC argued that:
In these circumstances it is not obvious that determining domestic terminal facilities are
‘airport services’ would yield significant benefits. The issues which would be
canvassed in the event that the ACCC was later called upon to determine a dispute over
access to the MUDT are likely to overlap considerably with the issues considered under
the NNI approval process. In the present circumstances it is not, therefore, obvious that
a determination along the lines sought by Virgin Blue would promote competition.
(ACCC 2001l, p. 26)
The ACCC has, in effect, decided to circumvent the arbitration process which may
have been initiated under the access provisions (Part IIIA) of the TP Act if the
service had been declared an ‘airport service’ under s. 192. The ACCC decision to
use its powers under s. 192(4B), while demonstrating the scope for discretion, may
also increase uncertainty among industry participants as to what services would be
defined as ‘airport services’ in any future determinations. The ACCC noted that the
draft determination:
… reflects the factual landscape surrounding Virgin Blue’s application. It is
emphasised that the ACCC might form a different view on the appropriateness of a
determination of similar facilities in other circumstances. (ACCC 2001l, p. 27)
The ACTO declarations at MIA and SIA under Part IIIA (box 9.2) illustrate that the
Part IIIA declaration criteria tests are also open to interpretation. While ACTO
sought access to various freight-handling and related services, the National
Competition Council (NCC) and Australian Competition Tribunal found that the
relevant facilities providing those services were the whole of MIA and SIA. Thus, it
was these facilities that were judged against the natural monopoly and national
significance tests.
The ACTO declarations also raised a number of other issues relating to the
interpretation of the Part IIIA criteria. These are considered at length in the
Productivity Commission’s report (PC 2001a) on the review of the National Access
Regime. The Commission recommended that the first declaration criterion be
strengthened,9 and that subsequent declaration decisions be reviewed in the next
review of Part IIIA with a view to determining whether further strengthening of
criteria is required.
The SIA declarations under Part IIIA (box 9.2) illustrate that there is scope for
considerable delays in the declaration process. ACTO applied to the NCC for
declaration of a number of services at SIA in November 1996. While the Minister
declared the services approximately eight months later, the FAC applied to the
Australian Competition Tribunal for a review of the decision. The Tribunal handed
down its decision affirming the declarations on 1 March 2000 — more than three
years after ACTO’s application. The administrative and legal costs of these
declarations are likely to have been significant, though insofar as precedents have
been determined, these costs should not all be attributed to this specific case.
Summary
The limited use of s. 192 to date makes it difficult to assess its contribution to
providing access at privatised core-regulated airports. The Delta determination
supports the view that the s. 192 declaration criteria are somewhat less stringent
than the Part IIIA criteria. However, the draft determination on Virgin Blue
indicates that even when the s. 192 criteria are met, the ACCC can use its
discretionary powers to make a negative determination. Whether airports warrant
continuation of special access provisions is discussed in chapter 11.
FINDING 9.2
Though privatised core-regulated airports have facilitated access for new entrant
airlines, airport-specific access provisions (s. 192 of the Airports Act) do not
appear to have been instrumental in achieving this outcome.
The successful use of Part IIIA by ACTO to obtain access declarations at MIA and
SIA also demonstrates that the general access provisions can be used to gain access
to airport services. However, these declarations have led to some concern about
interpretation of the Part IIIA criteria. The Productivity Commission in another
inquiry has recommended somewhat stronger declaration thresholds (PC 2001a).
Under the terms of reference, the Commission is required to identify and assess
alternatives to the price regulation implemented following the sale of airport leases.
In this and the next chapter, the main regulatory options are explored. This chapter
outlines cost-based and incentive regulation options. Further, issues relating to the
form and implementation of a price-cap regulatory regime are discussed. Issues
concerning the coverage of regulation — relating to single-till and dual-till
regulation — also are discussed. Chapter 11 assesses other regulatory options: price
monitoring, and access and anti-competitive conduct regulation, including price
undertakings and commercial agreements.
Cost-based regulation
Cost-based regulation sets prices that are based directly on the costs of the regulated
firm. Although there are other types of cost-based regulation,2 rate-of-return
regulation is the predominant form. Implementation of rate-of-return regulation
1 The term ‘price cap’ covers a multitude of regulatory regimes, including where the firm has all
prices subject to a strict price ceiling with no adjustment process. The process described here is
based on the Littlechild (1983) Retail Price Index (RPI)-X form of the price cap.
2 For example, return-on-cost allows the firm to charge a specific mark-up over total costs.
OPTIONS: COST-BASED 281
AND INCENTIVE
REGULATION
involves the regulator imposing a ‘fair’3 return on capital assets and then setting
prices to deliver this outcome. The objective of rate-of-return regulation is to ensure
that prices are set at a level that allows ongoing supply of the goods or services in
question (including investment) by the regulated firm, but are not set so high as to
allow excess profits.
3 ‘Fair’ is commonly used to describe a desired rate-of-return for the industry and includes a
risk-adjusted return on capital.
4 There may be other reasons for the monopolist to over-invest, for example, preemptive
investment to discourage new entrants.
5 After Averch and Johnson (1962), who first analysed the problem. For this result to hold, the
‘fair’ rate of return must be above the cost of capital. Kahn (1988) notes that the A–J effect may
offset the effects of under-investment due to monopoly and encourage risk-taking and output-
expanding investment.
6 Common costs may be allocated in a variety of ways, including according to revenue and
output shares, though essentially any allocation is arbitrary. The relative merits and problems of
allocating common costs are discussed by Europe Economics (2001).
282 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
• Rate-of-return regulation that ties prices to costs incurred by the firm may not be
appropriate where there is congestion and new facilities need to be built.
Efficient pricing needs to be linked to opportunity costs.
• The risk of any investment may be borne largely by customers, to the extent that
the regulated firm is able to pass through costs into higher prices.
There have been attempts to improve the outcomes from cost-based regulation.
Benchmarking techniques have been applied to overcome information problems
inherent in rate-of-return regulation, though with limited success (discussed below).
Another approach has been profit-sharing (or sliding-scale) regulation which is a
variant of rate-of-return regulation. In this approach, after the profit results have
been calculated for a designated period, any excess profits or profit shortfalls are
shared with the customers. This can be done through either refunds or future price
adjustments. These methods are designed to narrow the gap between costs and
revenues, thereby increasing allocative efficiency, without adversely affecting the
incentives for productivity improvements. A profit-related sliding scale requires an
explicit rate-of-return mechanism, so the information requirements can be
cumbersome.
Incentive-based regulation
Price caps are the main incentive mechanism used by regulators, though there are
many variations that fall under the price-cap banner. Price caps have their
theoretical basis in the work of Vogelsang and Finsinger (1979), with Littlechild
(1983) developing a practical method for the implementation of price caps for the
UK telecommunications industry (box 10.1).
OPTIONS: COST-BASED 283
AND INCENTIVE
REGULATION
Box 10.1 Vogelsang and Finsinger and Ramsey pricing
Economic efficiency generally requires that prices reflect marginal costs. However,
because airports have natural monopoly characteristics and substantial fixed costs,
pricing at marginal cost is not feasible in the long term. A desirable objective in this
situation is to price to cover average costs but in a way that minimises efficiency
losses. A standard economic solution in multi-product firms has been to implement
‘Ramsey pricing’, where the setting of prices reflects the inverse of the demand
elasticity for the good or service. Thus, the less price responsive that demand for the
good or service is to price changes, the higher the price.
Vogelsang and Finsinger (1979) proposed a method whereby a firm, under certain
assumptions, will set prices that satisfy Ramsey pricing conditions and earn sufficient
revenue to stay in business. This mechanism allows a firm to choose its own price
structure as long as it remains within a certain average price level for the regulated
basket of goods or services. Based on this theoretical approach, Littlechild (1983)
developed price caps that were first applied in the United Kingdom.
A price cap specifies the maximum price for a good or service over a certain period.
Typically, price increases are constrained to a level determined by an index —
commonly the rate of inflation (which serves as a proxy for exogenous rises in the
prices of inputs) — minus an X factor that (predominantly) accounts for expected
productivity improvements in the regulated firm. Any cost savings achieved beyond
the rate of inflation minus X adjustment accrue to the firm within a given regulated
period.
When there is regular reference to the costs of the firm, the essential remaining
difference between cost-based and price-cap regulation is the interregnum offered to
the regulated firm, during which it can retain profits arising from cost savings
beyond those incorporated in X values. But, viewed in this way, price-cap
regulation simply amounts to cost-based regulation with longer lags: in other words
if a price-cap regime were reviewed yearly with resetting of prices or adjustment of
the X factor related purely to the costs of the firm, then the two regulatory regimes
— and their outcomes — would be indistinguishable. The major additional feature
of price caps is that they can be used to stimulate a more efficient cost base.
Thus, if the review periods for a price-cap regime are short, then the incentives for
cost reduction are limited because prices closely track actual costs. If the review
periods are longer (perhaps three to five years), then the incentive to reduce costs by
the regulated firm — particularly early in the period — is stronger, because it can
retain part of the profit resulting from any cost-saving measures. (This assumes, of
course, that the regulator does not intervene within the designated regulatory period
and that the resetting of the price caps is always forward looking.) However, as the
price-cap review is approached, there may be an incentive for the airport to inflate
costs to obtain a lower X over the next period.
Another significant potential problem with price caps relates to the need for
maintenance and/or improvement of quality. Due to the structure of price caps,
there generally is an incentive to run down existing assets and degrade quality. With
a price cap in place, a firm may have an incentive to implement cost reductions at
the expense of service quality. Thus, price-cap regulation typically is complemented
by monitoring of service quality to ensure standards do not deteriorate.
Price caps also may constrain efficient pricing when capacity constraints are being
approached. In particular, in the calculation of X values, the costs used are those
incurred by the firm, not the costs imposed on others in the form of congestion.
Efficient prices are those that would allocate the scarce services to those who value
them most highly, not prices determined by costs incurred in operating the airport or
even ‘opportunity’ costs that reflect another (non-airport) use (appendix F).
The ACCC (sub. DR55) observed that airport operators have scope to introduce
peak-period pricing by restructuring charges within a price cap. The extent to which
price restructuring is able to address excess demand problems will depend partly on
the volumes in peak and non-peak periods. If the peak is long and reflects
significant excess demand, it is likely that market-clearing prices would generate
more revenue than allowed under a production-cost-based price cap. Broadly
speaking, the minimum efficient price in off-peak periods would still have to cover
the marginal cost of providing aeronautical services at those times. Prior to
September 2001, weekday volumes at Sydney Airport reached the 80 movements
per hour limit in five peak hours, and flights at these times represented around
40 per cent of daily movements. Introducing peak-period pricing may result in
existing shoulder periods also becoming fully utilised.
Finally, price caps, when they are fixed for other than a short term, are not very
flexible. If an airport’s volumes and/or costs are changing rapidly, adherence to the
7 If, for example, passengers are the base unit, there is little incentive to attract dedicated freight
flights, because revenue yield per passenger will increase and possibly exceed the cap,
requiring an offsetting reduction in aeronautical charges.
OPTIONS: COST-BASED 289
AND INCENTIVE
REGULATION
basket approach, because the revenue-yield approach is focused on a
homogeneous unit (typically passengers). The tariff-basket approach has better
incentives to provide different levels of service quality, because there is an
incentive to price different dimensions of quality according to each service’s
incremental costs and relevant demands.
The UK regulator, the Civil Aviation Authority (CAA 2001c) concluded, after
consideration of the advantages and disadvantages of the two approaches, that the
tariff-basket approach should replace revenue yield at Heathrow and Gatwick
airports. According to the CAA, the tariff-basket approach provided a ‘good basis’
for the proposed default price cap (see below) because, in particular, it avoided the
dilution problems associated with the revenue-yield approach.8 However, it
proposed maintaining the revenue-yield approach at Stansted and Manchester
airports, which are less congested.
Under a default price cap, an airport would be required to provide a specified level
of service at a given (or maximum) price. For any services beyond this standard,
each airline would have to negotiate directly with each airport. The extra services
could be separate services or services of a higher quality. This process has the
potential to encourage commercial negotiation between individual airports and
individual airlines, and targets regulation at the core services required by airlines.
The CAA noted that:
… a mechanism [default price cap] that facilitated greater direct contracting between
users and the airports could have significant benefits in terms of better use of existing
airport facilities, and in providing better incentives to ensure that the airport invests in
new facilities that users want. (CAA 2001c, p. 185)
The CAA (2001c) proposed that a default price cap be implemented at Heathrow
and Gatwick airports where there is evidence of significant excess demand and
price caps are likely to be tightly binding. Separate service contracts to provide
service ‘top ups’ or ‘top downs’ need not be treated as airport charges, so could be
made outside the price cap. The CAA also proposed that within the proposed price
cap there should be a term reflecting airport quality of service, based on a weighted
basket of quality attributes.
A default price cap and an adjustment for quality were considered to be unnecessary
for Stansted and Manchester airports. It was considered that at these airports, which
8 If a contract is entered into at prices lower than the default cap, then unless an adjustment is
made, the airport could increase prices to those users remaining in the default price cap
(CAA 2001c).
290 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
have excess capacity, the price cap would not be binding and therefore would not
act as a key driver of airport incentives to invest in additional capacity or to enter
into contracts between the airport and users.
Nonetheless, as the CAA conceded, the derivation of a quality term (or several) for
each UK airport is difficult. Numerous policy decisions are required, including in
relation to:
• the quality attributes to make up the basket;
• the ‘par value’ for each quality attribute in the basket;
• the relative weighting of each quality attribute; and
• the valuation of each quality attribute (in each period) (CAA 2001c).
The inclusion of a similar quality term in price caps at Australian airports would be
no less complex and has the potential to amplify the risk of regulatory error already
inherent in setting price caps. In any event, Australia faces a somewhat different set
of circumstances from those of the United Kingdom, in that domestic terminals in
Australia are mainly operated under long-term leases by the major domestic
airlines. This precludes some of the potential for quality differentiation in the
delivery of airport services by the airport; the level of the provision of services
associated with runways, and aprons, is largely non-discretionary. The use of
services, such as aerobridges, and international and domestic common-user
terminals, may be somewhat more discretionary, with airlines demanding various
levels of service.
It also is likely that there would be major disagreements between airports and
airlines as to whether a particular level of service corresponded to the level
specified under the default cap. Westralia Airports Corporation concurred, noting
that the default price cap:
… would be impracticable. The level of service requirement is difficult to specify and
may differ between users. It’s also very hard to measure, and it does depend at an
airport on the level of service provided by third parties. (trans., p. 566)
At Hamburg Airport, the price cap is designed to share increases in profits due to
exceptional passenger growth. Within a dual-till regime, the X factor is adjusted
according to a sliding scale based on passenger growth. If this growth exceeds
3 per cent then, for every extra 1 per cent growth, there is an increase in the X factor
by 0.5 per cent. (There is no provision for X to fall if passenger throughput falls
short of forecast levels.) This sharing of the extra revenue with consumers is based
on the premise that the extra profitability of the airport is highly correlated with
passenger growth, reflecting non-aeronautical revenues and/or lower unit costs.
Yardstick regulation/benchmarking
Benchmarks can be used within a price-cap regulatory regime for various tasks.
These include assessing the efficient cost structure of the firm to determine the level
of prices and assessing the value of equity in the determination of the cost of
capital. In setting or resetting the X factor, it is common to benchmark future
productivity gains against past productivity gains within an industry. As well,
benchmarking is used to assess quality performance and commonly is used within
the firm (rather than by the regulator) to assess the firm’s performance across a
range of activities.
The aim of benchmarking under a price-cap regime is to improve the incentives for
a firm by reducing the regulator’s reliance on the firm’s own costs to set the price-
cap parameters. This could provide incentives for cost efficiencies and to invest
appropriately.
Problems of benchmarking
Because there is no objective method for choosing the explanatory variables or for
allocating unexplained cost differences, the benchmarking process requires arbitrary
judgements at crucial points. This leads to an increase in the level of uncertainty and
increases the risk to the firm, which in turn may also raise its cost of capital.
The airlines (and their representatives) have proposed a range of regulatory options,
though generally advocating stricter price regulation than supported by the airports.
Virgin Blue proposed that ‘the CPI-X price cap should be applied to all aeronautical
services’ (sub. 30, p. 25). The Board of Airline Representatives of Australia
(BARA) (sub. 41 and trans., pp. 532–3) suggested rate-of-return regulation as one
sensible regulatory option for airports:
In BARA’s view, an effective, simple and relatively efficient approach to regulating the
price of airport services is rate of return regulation over each airport as a whole.
(sub. 41, p. 53)
As discussed above, there are several possible price-cap models as well as a number
of issues and options that need to be canvassed. These include the inter-related
issues of the starting prices, the resetting of X factors and the treatment of new
investment. In addition, the coverage of the price cap needs to be examined, along
with whether further modifications to the price cap are required to allow for
congestion pricing. The efficiency, incentive and compliance effects of each of
these options are also discussed.
9 Australian Airports (Townsville) considers that the balance of market power (at least for
regional airports) lies with the airlines and considers that regulation is required for this reason.
294 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
There seems no reason to prefer the use of a revenue-yield approach over the
existing tariff-basket approach to a price cap, particularly if incentives to invest are
considered to be appropriate. It also is clear that yardstick regulation cannot be
relied upon fully to supplant direct analysis of the costs of the firm. Benchmarking
could be one component of price regulation but ultimately firm-specific costs also
will need to be taken into account. Benchmarking has its place in comparing the
performance of airports to both airports within Australia and overseas. It could also
be used when establishing maximum prices between the resettings of the cap. As
well, the terms of reference for this inquiry state that price regulation should
facilitate benchmarking comparisons of airports.
The default price cap raises the issue of the appropriate specification of regulated
services. Although the default price cap has attractive theoretical underpinnings, the
derivation of a quality term that does not distort incentives is likely to be difficult
and complex. The users of aeronautical services will have different base
requirements, the minimum requirement will differ across airports, and disputes are
likely as to whether minimum specified standards are being met. In practice,
effective implementation of a default price cap may not be feasible.
While an airport with market power may have some incentives to under-invest
(chapter 7), price caps introduce a different set of incentives and potential
distortions. As observed by Professor Forsyth:
Price-caps are a simple form of control, but they open up many subsidiary problems.
Further, quite detailed regulation is needed to address quality degradation problems and
investment matters. (sub. 5, p. 35)
Cost-saving investment
Replacement/maintenance investment
In other words, if prices are set at an efficient level, then replacement of existing
capital can be expected to proceed, because it would be commercially viable. As
stated by SACL:
The reason that an NNI arrangement is required is that existing prices are below
incremental cost. If prices approximated incremental cost, new investment could be
funded from expected increased revenues from the volume growth, rather than unit
price increases. (sub. 27, p. 12)
Capacity-enhancing investment
Capacity-enhancing investment typically allows for traffic growth over time. If the
increase in capacity increases revenue, the less the requirement for additional cost
However, if regulated prices are such that an airport currently is making a loss on
the provision of a service, then there is no incentive for the airport to increase
capacity — it will just lose more.10
Quality-enhancing investment
Quality-enhancing investment increases the level of quality for a given service (for
example, an upgrade of terminal facilities). Under a price cap, an airport is unlikely
to be able to capture the extra benefits from a quality-enhancing investment, unless
the quality improvement encourages spending on services outside the cap or
increases demand for the airport’s services. It is likely that extra incentives,
probably an increase in prices, will be required to encourage this type of investment
by airport operators.
Where the benefits of such investment are likely to accrue to existing airlines, their
involvement in the approval process may be appropriate. However, airlines can
have divergent quality requirements. Even if existing airlines benefit, they may
oppose a quality improvement that would facilitate new entry.
10 Unless: (a) the airport expects a very large increase in demand such that unit costs fall; (b) costs
fall over all output ranges due to technological improvements; or (c) extra capacity encourages
additional spending on services outside the price cap.
OPTIONS: COST-BASED 297
AND INCENTIVE
REGULATION
Alternative price-cap treatment of investment
Apart from cost-saving investment, which the price-capped firm always will have
an incentive to undertake (because it can retain the benefits within a period), the
incentives to undertake the remaining types of investment depend crucially on the
detailed design of the price cap. The treatment of investment within a price cap is
inter-related with the starting prices for the regulated services and how the Xs are
set. Thus, for example, if there were no cost pass-through provisions for any
investment, then the starting prices and Xs would have to be set to accommodate all
future investment.
Figure 10.1 sets out three possible approaches to implementing price caps — each
of which, in principle, would provide for efficient investments and prices, at least
over time. These three approaches are not exhaustive; for example, the situation in
which starting prices are above levels required to provide for all investment is not
shown. In such a case there would be no need for provisions for the pass-through of
investment, while the X values could be made sufficiently large to drive prices to
their efficient levels over time.
The three interdependent decision variables listed down the left-hand side of
figure 10.1 are:
• starting prices;
• the setting of X values; and
• the scope of investment cost pass-through provisions.
The fourth (bottom) row represents other possible pass-through provisions for costs
outside the airport’s control — for example, noise levies, and mandated safety and
security provisions.
A B C
Starting Starting prices that do not Starting prices that allow Starting prices that allow
prices allow for any investment for expected replacement/ for all expected
maintenance and capacity investment
enhancing investment
1 2 3 4 5 6
Scope of other
pass-through Noise, safety, congestion etc Noise, safety, congestion etc Noise, safety, congestion etc
provisions
The solid arrows within each of the three approaches represent six feasible paths,
given the starting price decision, that could, in principle, deliver efficient pricing
and investment outcomes. (The path illustrated by the dashed line is discussed
later.)
If starting prices are below the levels required to cover any expected investment,
then there is likely to be a need to allow price adjustments for capacity-enhancing
and replacement/maintenance investment as well as for quality-enhancing
investment. All paths (1, 2 and 3) in approach A allow for anticipated productivity
growth to be incorporated in the X factor. However, the calculation of the X values
differs across the three paths with respect to the types of investment incorporated. In
path 1, the X values incorporate expected productivity improvements only, whereas
path 2 X values incorporate an allowance for replacement/maintenance and
capacity-enhancing investment as well as an allowance for productivity growth. In
path 3, the X values incorporate all of the investment and expected productivity
gains incorporated in path 2, as well as an allowance for quality-enhancing
investment.
Given decisions about setting starting prices and Xs, each of the paths requires
varying scope for the pass-through of investment costs. Path 1 allows for all
investment costs (except cost-saving investment) to be to passed through, whereas
under paths 2 and 4, only the costs of quality-enhancing investment can be passed
through. Under paths 3, 5 and 6 there is no need for ongoing investment assessment
(as investment is incorporated in the starting prices or Xs), but there is a need, in
exceptional circumstances, to allow for variations in cost pass-throughs provided for
investment.11 This will cover situations unforeseeable at the time the Xs are set.
(Where there is provision for assessment of investment on a continuing basis
(paths 1, 2 and 4), there is no need for such an ‘escape’ clause.)
Path 1 is the easiest path to implement at the start of the regulatory period. Prices
are carried forward and only expected productivity improvements need be
calculated. However, this ostensible simplicity is counteracted by the need for an
ongoing examination of every proposed investment (excluding cost-saving
investment). This assessment is likely to be complicated by the uncertainty
surrounding the existing price levels. To determine the amount of adjustment to the
prices for aeronautical services, the appropriateness of each investment will need to
be determined, as well as a dollar value for all the investments. Then there will need
to be an assessment of whether current prices will sustain these investments; if not,
an upward adjustment of prices will be required.
Some other aspects of path 1 are appealing. As discussed in chapter 8, the process
of cost pass-through can provide an opportunity for consultation between users and
the airport, possibly with a view to commercially-negotiated outcomes rather than
regulated ones (box 10.4). Also, the need for assessment of investment proposals by
the regulator occurs only when the investment proposal is submitted, therefore
avoiding the information problems and risks associated with planning investment
several years ahead.
Paths 2 and 3 (approach A) again have low starting prices but require some
assessment of investment at the beginning of the regulatory period for incorporation
into the X values. Path 2 will require a relatively high level of regulatory
involvement because investment needs must be assessed in setting the X factors as
well as on a continuing basis. Also, there will need to be a distinction made between
replacement/maintenance, capacity-enhancing and quality-enhancing investment. In
practice, this could be a very difficult and, at times, arbitrary determination.
Path 3 shares characteristics with paths 5 and 6 in that all investment must be
assessed at the beginning of the regulatory period. Approaches B and C are
302 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
characterised by the setting of the initial prices at levels adequate for the specified
investment. Compared with paths 1, 2 and 4, the ongoing information requirements
for paths 3, 5 and 6 are reduced — though there remains the substantial task of
determining the initial efficient price levels and Xs for aeronautical services. Major
elements of such an exercise are outlined in box 10.2.
Under the system in the United Kingdom, prices are reset every five years based on
a review of expected costs and demand. New investment over the regulatory period
is estimated and incorporated into the anticipated costs after a consultation process
with the industry. This system is similar to paths 3, 5 and 6, as all investment is
incorporated in the starting prices or the X values at the start of the regulatory
period. Although the UK approach has been to accept airport investment proposals
with minimal regulatory assessment, the potential always remains for intense
regulatory involvement in the investment decision-making process during price-cap
reviews.
The longer the price-cap period, the more difficult it is to predict the level and cost
of required investment. In addition, airports may have an incentive to overstate
investment requirements, to procure excessive up-front price increases, while
airlines may be tempted to understate their forward investment requirements to
achieve lower charges.12 Once an investment program is approved, there is an
incentive for airport operators to delay the investment process, because pricing
parameters have been fixed for the regulatory period. Hence, the regulator must
ensure the integrity of the investment plan by monitoring during the regulatory
period. These tendencies, and other failures of the process, have led the CAA
(2000e) to request feedback from airports and airlines on ways to ‘incentivise’
investment.
12 Such an approach would only be beneficial to airlines if they are still able to achieve their
desired airport investment profile in spite of airport charges being set too low.
OPTIONS: COST-BASED 303
AND INCENTIVE
REGULATION
Alternative paths?
The ACCC suggested several price-cap approaches (sub. 36). Essentially, all would
carry forward price levels from the current regulatory regime (approach A).13
However, the proposed approaches are unclear with respect to
replacement/maintenance and capacity-enhancing investment. The ACCC (sub. 36)
referred to its preferred option as a ‘hybrid’ approach. This would allow only pass-
through (upward adjustment of prices within the regulatory period) of the costs of
investment for major projects. Again, starting prices would be kept at the level
applying at the end of the current price cap; alternatively, an initial minor
adjustment could be made for expected small new investments.
If starting prices were not adjusted for smaller investment projects these would be
funded through adjustments to the Xs. The ACCC recommended that the distinction
between small and large investment be based on an (unspecified) dollar value. It
recognised that ‘the ‘X’ values should be consistent with the approach adopted in
relation to new investment’ (sub. 36, p. 110).
Another categorisation for the distinction between investment in the ACCC’s hybrid
approach is ‘developments that could not be anticipated at the time the ‘X’ values
were set’ (sub. 36, p. 107). This suggestion is somewhat similar to path 6, if prices
were set at the appropriate level at the start of the regulatory review period. If the
prices are not set in this way, then the process would proceed on a similar basis to
paths 3 or 5, in that all foreseeable investment would be assessed at the beginning of
the regulatory period and prices (including Xs) would be adjusted to accommodate
the expected investment program.
13 The ACCC considered that an allowance for smaller new investments could be factored in
either through adjustment to the X factors or starting point prices.
304 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
The ACCC indicated that its hybrid approach would allow higher prices to recover
the costs of projects that would qualify as major development projects under the
Airports Act 1996.
The pass through provisions should not distinguish between ‘replacement’ and ‘new’
investments. In other words the pass through provisions should be available for
investments irrespective of whether they replace existing assets or add to capacity or
quality. (sub. DR55, p. 17)
With the aim of lessening regulatory costs, the ACCC hybrid approach would allow
for smaller new investment (but presumably not replacement investment) being
included in the X values or in the starting point prices. The difference between the
two alternatives is a matter of the timing of the effect on allowable prices of such
investment over the regulatory period. If small new investments are included in the
starting prices, there will be a relatively small initial price increase, whereas
including them in the Xs will lead to each annual price change being marginally
higher than otherwise.
Over time, as more aeronautical infrastructure is replaced, prices under the hybrid
approach will tend to increase towards those necessary to cover aeronautical costs
(including appropriate returns on assets).14 The ACCC’s argument for the extension
of cost pass-through to major replacement investment, which is excluded under the
current framework, would seem to indicate a recognition that current aeronautical
prices under the price cap may not be sufficient to justify replacement investment.
The ACCC (sub. 36) observed that current prices were unlikely to reflect
aeronautical costs. Its apparent reluctance for starting prices to be reset to the levels
needed to cover such investment (at least at the beginning of a new regulatory
period) appears to reflect a concern that a rise in prices would deliver windfall gains
to airport operators. The ACCC explained that:
Introducing new CPI-X price caps for regulated airports raises the question of how to
set starting point prices and the ‘X’ values. The Commission [ACCC] proposes that
prices from the current regulatory framework should be carried over to form the
starting point for a new price cap. The alternatives, such as setting starting point prices
to reflect costs, are likely to result in significant increases or decreases in charges.
Given that these starting point prices relate to existing, mostly sunk assets, there is little
if any reason to make such a change from an economic efficiency perspective. Instead
the main effect of such a change would be a distributional one, either a transfer from
airlines and their passengers to airport operators or vice versa. (sub. 36, p. 10)
14 If the starting prices already include some returns to capital, then allowing price increases for
replacement investment could eventually lead to prices overshooting efficient levels. The price
increase allowed would need to be tempered by the depreciation and returns on existing assets
already contained in the starting prices.
OPTIONS: COST-BASED 305
AND INCENTIVE
REGULATION
The scope for windfall gains (or losses) would, however, depend on the
expectations of bidders regarding aeronautical price regulation (including NNI pass-
through provisions) at the time of bidding. As discussed in chapter 8, bidders might
have had some grounds for expecting regulated outcomes different from those that
transpired. Moreover, the price-cap regime was locked in for five years only and
described as a transitional regime. Bidders also were informed that single-till
pricing would not be mandated (DoTRD 1996) and yet this approach remains
incorporated to a substantial degree in current prices courtesy of the Federal
Airports Corporation charges used as the starting prices for the post-privatisation
regime. The Government’s commitment to a dual-till approach to establishing
maximum regulated prices was confirmed in its direction to the ACCC regarding
treatment of non-aeronautical revenue in the assessment of SACL’s pricing
proposal (Direction No. 22).
The ACCC is correct in observing that failure to provide sufficient returns on sunk
airport assets is likely to have limited efficiency effects, at least in the short term.
This is so for any industry with excess capacity. However, regulators have
recognised that longer-term considerations make short-run marginal-cost pricing —
the logical conclusion of the ACCC’s sunk costs argument — inappropriate on
efficiency grounds. In its decision on Sydney Airport, the ACCC (2001i) took a
longer-term view and allowed prices to rise to a level that provided returns on sunk
assets.
The Commission considers that setting starting prices for any new price cap to
reflect efficient long-run aeronautical costs offers a superior approach that would
reduce ongoing regulatory involvement with its associated costs and risk of error.
The CAA has made a preliminary proposal to rebase price caps for a number of UK
airports and observed that:
While the regulatory system would allow the incremental returns from additional
investments to cover their incremental costs eventually, it provides poor signals for the
airports and users as to the real costs and benefits of delivering additional outputs.
(CAA 2001c, p. xvii)
Implementation
The current price-cap regime is administered under the PS Act (chapter 3). In its
review of that Act, the Productivity Commission (PC 2001c) has proposed that the
Act be repealed. A CPI-X price cap could be administered within the TP Act either
via generic provisions (under Part IIIA as an industry code, for example) or an
industry-specific provision. Industry-specific provisions also could be placed in the
Airports Act, with the ACCC appointed to administer the cap.
Given that price-cap regulation concerns the competitive conduct of airports, its
inclusion within the TP Act rather than the Airports Act would seem desirable if the
PS Act were repealed. The Commission also considers that any price-cap regime for
airports should be implemented as an industry-specific amendment to the TP Act
(as for telecommunications (PC 2001d)).
Summary
In theory, price caps can be devised that could, at least over time, deliver efficient
prices and investment. The important questions are the likelihood of achieving such
a result in practice, and the direct and indirect costs involved in implementing the
regime. The various approaches outlined require different levels of regulatory
intervention and provide for different opportunities for commercial negotiation and
strategic behaviour by the parties. Major trade-offs relate to the level of ongoing
assessment of investment proposals and the time over which any adjustment needed
to bring prices to efficient levels are made.
The scope for game-playing is likely to be reduced if it is made clear to all parties
which price-cap approach has been chosen and, therefore, how different types of
investment will be accommodated. Nonetheless, the risk of regulatory error
remains, as does the almost inevitable convergence of price caps towards cost-based
In particular, because firms always possess more knowledge about the firm and its
markets than possessed by the regulator (information asymmetry), the firm
generally is in the best position to determine future cost structures, demand
forecasts and many other important facets of its business. It is difficult for a
regulator without this detailed knowledge to determine appropriate prices and
investment. For some airports, the importance of, and inherent problems in, valuing
airport land make regulatory determination of efficient airport prices particularly
difficult (appendix F).
Given this limited information and the resultant likelihood of regulatory error,
pricing rules applied by regulators can have an adverse impact on investment in
essential infrastructure. While firms will make investments based on an expected
probability distribution of returns, the common objective that regulated prices
should provide a firm with the market average rate of return, on average, will result
in below average returns. While the regulated price aims to preclude excessive
returns, if market conditions generate below normal returns, the firm is not
adequately compensated.
As noted in the Commission’s review of the National Access Regime (PC 2001a),
the result of setting prices too low is likely to be a failure to invest. This is
particularly so where there is lumpy investment with decreasing costs in which case
the investment may not be undertaken if the regulated price is set too low. Hence
the resultant costs to the community of inefficiently low regulated prices are
expected to be significantly greater than the costs that would flow from regulated
prices being set a little too high. The CAA (2001c) also noted the significant
distortions of imposing a regulated price that is too low and consequently argues for
a price cap slightly higher than the regulator’s best guess of efficient prices.
FINDING 10.1
The terms of reference for this inquiry set out several principles to guide future
price regulation, including that ‘future prices regulation should be applied to those
aeronautical services and those airports where airport operators have most potential
to abuse market power’ (in essence, the last option above). Moreover, core-
regulated airports were privatised on the basis that a single till would not be
mandated (DoTRD 1996) and the Government issued a Direction (No. 22) to this
effect in relation to Sydney Airport in April 2001. Nonetheless, several participants
argued in favour of broader application of price regulation on efficiency grounds.
These arguments are assessed here and in more detail in appendix C.
As one option for regulation of airports, BARA (sub. 41) suggested imposing rate-
of-return regulation across the entire range of services provided by airports (but not
for individual services). The rationale for regulating all airport services is that, for a
decreasing cost, multi-product monopoly to cover its fixed costs, while minimising
efficiency losses of pricing above marginal cost, prices should be set such that
markets with relatively inelastic demand bear a greater share of fixed and common
costs than do markets with more elastic demand (Ramsey pricing). In principle,
rate-of-return regulation applied across the entire range of airport services would
encourage such pricing. It also has the practical advantage of not requiring cost
allocation across various services.
While this model may be appropriate if firms have market power in all the services
they provide, if profits arise from locational advantages rather than market power,
then rate-of-return regulation could have undesirable consequences. As discussed
below, if an airport operator were regulated such that additional rents earned could
not be retained, the incentive to earn such rents would be removed. This could mean
that airport land was not used in the most efficient way. Therefore, rate-of-return
regulation may not bring about lower aeronautical prices. Rate-of-return regulation
also is likely to introduce incentives for the airport to allow costs to increase across
the whole range of airport activities (section 10.1).
OPTIONS: COST-BASED 309
AND INCENTIVE
REGULATION
Single-till price-cap regulation
One argument put for a single till is that profits from non-aeronautical activities
may reflect market power rather than locational rents. If this were the case,
however, then it may be more appropriate to reduce prices directly to promote
efficient consumption and protection of consumers of the service in question. The
single till would not prevent excessive pricing of non-aeronautical services by
airports; it merely would require that any monopoly profits were transferred from
consumers of those services to the owners of airlines and/or their passengers. As
Kahn observed:
It is no more consistent with economic efficiency or fairness if prices for restaurant
meals, duty-free sales, car parking or other commercial services at airports are set at
excessive levels, than if airlines were subjected to excessive charges for aviation
services. Moreover, the inefficiency resulting from the former monopolistic pricing
would not be mitigated, but compounded if the excess revenues were used to hold other
airport charges below the level of marginal cost. (Kahn 1991, p. 20)
To the extent that a single till discouraged an airport operator from earning any
monopoly profits in non-aeronautical activities, this would be a desirable, if
possibly unintended, consequence of such an approach to regulating aeronautical
prices.
BARA, Ansett and Qantas (subs 41, 42, and 48) suggested that efficient airport
pricing requires that some or all locational rents earned at the airport be applied to
reduce aeronautical charges. BARA provided some illustrations effecting this result.
However, even in highly-competitive industries such as petrol retailing (cited by
BARA, sub. DR54), price-taking producers (or land-owners) in relatively high-yield
locations (whether because of convenience or natural phenomena) will earn and
retain locational rents.
What an anchor tenant pays, however, will depend on the relative attractiveness of
the location. At very attractive (and profitable) locations, the owner of a shopping
complex is likely to have a choice of anchor tenant in which case higher rentals can
be charged. In other cases, there will be a ‘scarcity’ of tenants and they will be
rewarded accordingly.
As discussed in chapter 7 and appendix C, airports are likely to ‘reward’ airlines for
additional passenger throughput in recognition of any demand complementarities
between aeronautical and non-aeronautical services. The airline, in this case,
provides a scarce and profitable resource (passengers) to the airport. But, there does
not appear to be any reason that airlines (and their passengers) should receive all
locational rents earned at airports. In this regard, the CAA recently concluded that it
‘does not accept that airlines have any intrinsic rights over net commercial revenues
generated at the airports’ (2001c, p. 13). Importantly, others contribute to the
earning of rents (including the airport lessee who develops and allocates appropriate
spaces within the airport, thus promoting the creation of such rent, the airport land
owner and concessionaires).
This argument appears to rest on two assumptions — namely, that there are
significant common costs in supplying aeronautical and non-aeronautical services,
and that demand for non-aeronautical services is less elastic than demand for
aeronautical services. If these assumptions hold, then common costs could be
covered more efficiently by increasing the prices of non-aeronautical services
relative to aeronautical services. However, the extent of common costs in the
provision of aeronautical and non-aeronautical services appears limited. There may
be some shared terminal costs but, even in this instance, costs are likely to be
separable. In addition, as the ACCC (sub. 36) pointed out, for those non-
aeronautical services sold in competitive markets, prices cannot be raised above
marginal cost. Hence there would appear to be limited scope for prices to exceed
marginal cost in order to make a contribution to any common, fixed costs.
A case for a single till can be made on the grounds that non-aeronautical earnings,
to the extent that they are locational rents, could be ‘taxed’ in a non-distorting
manner (that is, without affecting economic behaviour) and used to reduce
OPTIONS: COST-BASED 311
AND INCENTIVE
REGULATION
aeronautical charges to ensure short-run marginal-cost pricing of those services. In
other words, locational rents could be used to pay for the airport’s aeronautical
assets. As discussed in appendix C, there may be an in-principle case for such cross
subsidisation, at least at uncongested airports where the marginal costs of providing
aeronautical facilities are likely to fall below average costs and where pricing of
aeronautical services would otherwise result in some marginal sales being lost.15
15 If an airport discriminates in its pricing reasonably efficiently, the marginal distortion will be
small. In this case, a single till largely would redistribute income without promoting efficiency.
16 To the extent that an airport can retain additional profits during the price-cap period, there will
be some incentive to make short-term investments that result in higher non-aeronautical profits.
17 Though it may be feasible to design an arrangement that would provide incentives for the
airport operator to earn additional locational rents (such as an up-front agreement under which
an airport operator pays expected infra-marginal rents), single-till arrangements in practice tend
to appropriate ‘excess’ (marginal) rents.
18 If demand were not rationed, then queuing, for example, could dissipate surplus.
312 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
In addition, as noted above, owners of leases for core-regulated airports bought the
leases on the basis that they could retain profits from services that were not subject
to the price cap. The (discounted) expected value of this profit stream largely would
have been factored into bid prices, benefiting the Commonwealth Government (and
taxpayers). Thus, the Government effectively has imposed an up-front ‘tax’ on
expected locational rents.
A dual-till approach refers to regulation where only those services in which the
airport is considered to have market power are subject to a price cap. Typically the
regulated ‘till’ includes only those aeronautical services in which the airport has
market power. A dual till may introduce some distortions in favour of non-
aeronautical investments, particularly if the price cap, over time, effectively limits
the rate of return allowed on aeronautical services. On the other hand, compared
with a single till, because a dual till allows aeronautical cost recovery, airports may
have a greater incentive to invest in aeronautical (as well as non-aeronautical)
activities and increased capacity.
In chapter 6 it was found that major airports are likely to have a relatively high
degree of market power in refuelling services. If continued price regulation of
airports were considered appropriate, then because refuelling is closely related to
aircraft movements, its inclusion in a price cap for aeronautical services at those
airports with market power would seem appropriate. This could conflict with
undertakings given to airports prior to sale, however.
The Commission considers that if price-cap regulation were to be continued for any
airports, then the cap should apply only to those aeronautical services in which the
airport has substantial market power. Profits earned in non-aeronautical activities
should not be taken into account in setting the cap.
If an airport exercises significant market power (as opposed to earning locational
rent) in any non-aeronautical activity, separate price monitoring or other
regulation may be appropriate.
This chapter continues the discussion of alternative regulatory options from the
previous chapter. Price monitoring, access provisions and general competition law
are discussed as alternatives or supplements to other forms of price regulation.
Price monitoring generally has been used in areas where scope for monopoly
pricing is limited but there are still some concerns about pricing. As noted in the
second reading speech of the Competition Policy Reform Bill, which introduced
price-monitoring provisions into the Prices Surveillance Act 1983 (PS Act):
Price monitoring may be appropriate where there is concern about the effectiveness of
competition, a history of price problems or community concern about price levels or
movements, or where industries have been recently reformed or deregulated. (HoR
1995, p. 2800)
Since 5 October 2001, prices, costs and profits of aeronautical services at Adelaide,
Canberra and Darwin airports have been subject to price monitoring, replacing the
price caps that previously applied to these services. The prices, costs and profits of
OPTIONS: PRICE 315
MONITORING AND
ACCESS
aeronautical-related services at all price-capped airports were monitored by the
ACCC until 5 October 2001; since then, aeronautical-related services have been
monitored only at those airports where either price caps continue to apply or where
aeronautical services are subject to price monitoring.
The ACCC also monitors the quality of selected aeronautical and aeronautical-
related services at all core-regulated airports under Part 8 of the Airports Act 1996
(chapter 3). Operators of core-regulated airports are also required under Part 7 of
the Airports Act to provide the ACCC with specified audited financial statements
and reports to supplement the information that they are required to produce under
corporations law (chapter 3). These monitoring arrangements are discussed in
chapter 9.
However, some participants were of the view that light-handed forms of price
regulation, such as monitoring, would not constrain the potential for abuse of
market power by airport operators effectively — for example, the Board of Airline
Representatives of Australia (BARA), Qantas, Ansett and Virgin Blue
(subs 41, 48, 42, and DR74). Virgin Blue commented that:
… the price monitoring framework proposed by the [Productivity Commission’s] Draft
Report is a weak and inadequate solution to the market power enjoyed by airport
operators. The proposal would create significant uncertainty in the industry and would
promote a wide range of regulatory gaming behaviour. For example, airport operators
1 The ACCC proposed that the range of aeronautical services be extended to include some
services previously monitored as aeronautical-related services.
316 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
could reap very high monopoly rents in the five years of the monitoring if they thought
either that increased regulation would not be implemented or that the increased
regulation would still be ‘worth it’. Alternatively, they could use their market power to
raise prices to a lesser but still significant and inefficient degree until the end of the
probationary period, then raise prices even higher after that period had ended.
(sub. DR74, pp. 9–10)
Airports in New Zealand and some airports in the United Kingdom (the revenues of
which exceed a specified threshold) are currently subject to light-handed regulatory
regimes that involve price monitoring.
Since 1988, there has been no direct price regulation of aeronautical services
provided by New Zealand’s three largest airports — Auckland, Christchurch and
Wellington. Instead, these airports have been subject to a ‘light-handed’ regulatory
regime where disclosure and consultation requirements, the countervailing power of
airlines, and the threat of the introduction of direct price control are intended to act
as checks on the abuse of any market power (see box 11.1 and appendix G for a
more detailed discussion of the NZ regulatory system).
The design of the regulatory system seems to have contributed to the willingness of
airport users to resort to litigation. For example, the meaning of the legislative
requirement that airports ‘consult’ with ‘substantive’ airline customers about price
changes has been frequently tested in the courts (appendix G). The willingness of
airlines to engage in litigation has been exacerbated by the lack of any dispute
resolution options other than the legal system.
In addition, since 1989, there have been three regulatory reviews of the system. The
current review by the CC, examining whether price controls should be introduced
for ‘airfield activities’,2 commenced in 1998, around the same time as the
privatisation of Auckland and Wellington airports. This might have encouraged
strategic behaviour by both airports and airport users to attempt to influence the
outcome of the review.
2 Airfield activities, as defined in the Airport Authorities Amendment Act 1997, cover facilities
and services that enable the landing and take-off of aircraft, including: the provision of
airfields, runways, taxiways, and parking aprons; facilities and services for air traffic and
parking control; airfield lighting; and services to maintain and repair airfields, runways,
taxiways, and parking aprons for aircraft. The terms of reference do not require the CC to
examine the provision of ‘passenger terminal activities’ and ‘aircraft and freight activities’
(which are also defined under the Act) (CC 2001a).
3 International landing charges for aircraft with a maximum take-off weight (MTOW) of more
than 40 tonnes were increased by 3 per cent in 1992 to contribute to the costs of the
development of a new international terminal building. Upon completion of the building the
318 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
This phased increase in charges of 18.5 per cent was agreed to by all of Auckland
Airport’s ‘substantive’ customers with the exception of its largest airline customer,
Air New Zealand. In October 2000, Air New Zealand instigated legal proceedings
against Auckland Airport on the grounds of an alleged failure to consult, and
withheld payment of the increase in the landing charges. However, in November
2001, the two parties agreed to a 12.5 per cent increase in airport charges (which
will apply to all airlines).
Christchurch Airport introduced new landing charges in January 2001 — the first
increase in charges for 10 years. The charges were accepted following a
consultation process with the airlines. Charges were set for three years and involve
price restructuring. Landing charges were previously levied on the basis of the type
of aircraft; they are now calculated based on maximum take-off weight (MTOW)
(CC 2001b).
Wellington Airport commenced consultation with airlines in July 2001 with a view
to setting new charges from July 2002 (CC 2001b). In the 12 years since this airport
was corporatised, charges in nominal terms have increased by around 50 per cent.
However, most of this increase came from a one-off increase in 1992. Since then
charges in nominal terms have increased by 9 per cent.
charges were reduced by 3 per cent. In 1997, international and domestic landing charges
increased for small aircraft (less than 6 tonnes) (CC 2001b).
4 The CC was to release its final report in November 2001, but this has been delayed because:
‘The [CC] is working through a range of complex issues and needs to consider all of the
information received. The report is expected to be finalised in the second quarter of 2002’
(CC 2001c).
OPTIONS: PRICE 319
MONITORING AND
ACCESS
For the period 1988-89 to 1999-00, the CC found that average annual rates of return
exceeded target ‘competitive’ returns at Auckland and Christchurch airports by
3.71 and 2.01 per cent respectively. In contrast, Wellington Airport, over the same
period, did not achieve this benchmark rate of return. The CC also estimated a
benchmark ‘competitive’ price for 1999-00 and compared this with actual airport
charges.5 The CC found that prices exceeded the competitive benchmark by less
than 3 per cent at Auckland Airport, while Christchurch and Wellington airports
were charging below ‘competitive’ benchmark prices (Christchurch by 10 per cent
and Wellington by 34 per cent) (CC 2001b).6 The CC forecast that, based on the
announced price increases at Auckland Airport, the differential between actual
charges and the competitive benchmark would increase to 15.5 per cent at
Auckland, and to 28 per cent at Christchurch Airport by 2002-03.
However, as argued by Kahn, it may be efficient to include (at least) part of the
costs of future capacity, before it becomes operational, in today’s prices:
The asserted principle that ‘today’s users should only bear today’s costs’ is
meaningless in an industry with lumpy, long-lived assets and fails to recognise the
causal effect of today’s demand on the investment requirements of tomorrow, and
accords neither with fairness nor economic efficiency … In situations in which it
conflicts with efficient pricing — specifically with an efficient behaviour of prices over
time — the principle explicitly adopted by the [Commerce] Commission itself dictates
that it be ignored. (Kahn 2001b, p. 14)
In the case of Auckland Airport, where airport users have agreed to the need for the
development of a second runway by 2007 (AIAL 2001), it would seem efficient for
Auckland Airport to incorporate (at least some of the costs) of developing increased
capacity into current landing charges.
Other concerns have been raised about the assumptions used in estimating future
returns to airports, and the costs and benefits of imposing price control (box 11.2).
5 Airport charges, for this purpose, were derived by dividing total landing charge revenue by
tonnes landed. The ‘competitive’ price was derived from the asset base and weighted average
cost of capital (WACC) determined by the CC.
6 If these results are correct, they imply that these airports were earning their highest rates of
return prior to privatisation.
320 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
For example, the CC assumed that both Auckland and Christchurch airports would
fully implement their pricing proposals. As discussed above, since the release of the
CC’s draft report, Auckland Airport has agreed to reduce the proposed increase
from 18.5 per cent to 12.5 per cent.
In summary, while the ACCC (sub. DR55) described the NZ approach as a failed
model, a closer examination demonstrates that, notwithstanding some deficiencies,
However, there is some evidence that the threat of regulation under the Airports Act
has acted as a deterrent to the potential abuse of any market power (Kunz 1999;
322 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
Starkie 2001b). Two Scottish airports operated by BAA plc, Glasgow and
Edinburgh, were subject to a designation application (that is, to impose a price cap),
which the UK Government rejected because there was no evidence of abuse of a
monopoly position or of inefficiency. When announcing its decision, the
Government added that it believed the threat of designation provided a strong
incentive for BAA plc to control its charges. Possibly reflecting this threat, BAA plc
capped its prices at both airports voluntarily — initially with the formula Retail
Price Index (RPI)-3 (Starkie 2001b).
The major potential advantages of price monitoring over stricter price controls are:
• the scope it provides for commercial relationships to develop;
• lower levels of regulatory intervention in price-setting and hence reduced
opportunity for regulatory error and consequent distortions in production and
investment; and
• lower compliance costs.
On the other hand, to ensure that market power is not abused, lower levels of
regulatory intervention in price setting must be balanced by a credible threat that
abuse of market power can and will be identified and appropriate action taken.
Therefore, in order to achieve the appropriate balance, key issues in the design of a
price monitoring regime are specification of:
• the information to be disclosed (to assist in determining whether market power
has been abused and also to promote informed commercial relationships); and
• the nature of the ‘threat’ or over-arching constraint on abuse of market power,
including in what circumstances action can be taken and the form that action will
take.
If these elements are not clearly spelt out, there is a risk that light-handed regulation
could become ineffective or, indeed, as intrusive as stricter price controls. Professor
Forsyth noted, in the context of regulation of airports in New Zealand, that this
could result in inefficiencies similar to those that occur when stricter forms of price
regulation apply:
The threat to regulate is not the same as actual regulation, but its impacts on the firm
may well be much the same. The regulated firm does not know what behaviour on its
part will induce the regulator to impose formal regulation. One possible trigger might
be its profitability; if the firm earns high or supernormal profits, the regulator may
intervene. If this is what the airports believe, this shadow regulation would have the
The potential for inefficiencies may be alleviated to some extent by defining the
behaviour on the part of the regulated firm that would trigger stricter forms of price
regulation (or, indeed, ‘good’ behaviour that would not trigger stricter regulation).
Nonetheless, clearly defining such behaviour may be difficult — high prices may be
a signal that new investment is required rather than an indication that monopoly
prices are being charged; high profits may reflect entrepreneurial skills rather than
market power, and increases in prices may simply reflect changes in costs or that
prices previously were too low. In a capacity-constrained airport, higher prices may
be a means to allocate the available capacity efficiently. This suggests that a broad
set of principles is likely to be preferable for guiding efficient behaviour to specific
criteria that if applied in isolation may not be consistent with efficient outcomes.
Specific criteria for triggering regulatory intervention could also encourage strategic
behaviour to this end. There is a need for a credible threat of stronger regulation, for
reasons discussed above. If it were made clear, however, that any such regulation
would not be reintroduced within a predetermined period, there would be less
potential for the undermining of bona fide commercial negotiations. A review at the
end of that period could then assess whether stricter forms of price regulation,
further monitoring, or any other action were warranted at individual airports. The
monitoring period would need to be long enough to encourage commercial
negotiation, but not so long that the threat of reintroduction of stricter forms of price
regulation was not an effective deterrent against abuse of market power.
The review at the conclusion of the monitoring period could take into account
changes in the competitive environment in which an airport operates and the
behaviour of the various parties during the monitoring period. Information collected
through monitoring could form part of that assessment.
Comprehensive requirements for disclosure that are spelt out clearly at the start of
the monitoring period, and not altered, may help to minimise regulatory (in this
case, monitoring) creep. Although there may be occasions when it is desirable to
vary disclosure requirements or seek further information, doing so may increase
compliance costs and regulatory uncertainty. Additional information could be
sought and provided on a voluntary basis, although there would be no guarantee that
the monitored firm would provide the requested information.
The information that airport operators in New Zealand are required to disclose is
detailed in box 11.4.
BARA (sub. 41) stated that the compliance costs of monitoring are not necessarily
lower than the compliance costs associated with the current regulatory
arrangements. Sydney Airports Corporation Limited (SACL) (sub. 27) also noted
that price monitoring incurs compliance costs. However, the compliance costs of
regulation will be reduced where the information required for monitoring is less
detailed and its analysis by the regulator less complex than for price caps. Airport
operators already may be required to collect and disclose some of the required
Indeed, even in the absence of price monitoring, airport operators may collect at
least some of the required information for their own purposes, and may make it
publicly available of their own accord, as has been suggested by Melbourne Airport
(PC 2001b). It was noted in chapter 9 that airport operators have incurred costs
complying with current monitoring arrangements, though costs have not been large
because the information requirements have not been onerous.
Confining monitoring only to those airports and services where there is clearly
scope for abuse of market power could help to minimise any compliance costs.
Ensuring that information is not required too frequently could also help. However,
this should be balanced against the need for regulators and others (such as airport
users) to gain an accurate picture of changes in monitored variables over time.
FINDING 11.1
Where airport market power is not substantial, or where there are commercial
constraints on the misuse of market power, price monitoring has significant
advantages over stricter forms of price regulation. Provided there is no easy
recourse to regulatory intervention, a price-monitoring regime can promote
Price monitoring could be implemented under the PS Act, the Trade Practices Act
1974 (TP Act) or industry-specific legislation. Price monitoring of aeronautical and
aeronautical-related services at some core-regulated airports currently is conducted
under s. 27A of the PS Act. However, in its inquiry into the PS Act, the
Commission concluded that the PS Act is an unsatisfactory vehicle for conducting
inquiries and monitoring (PC 2001c). It recommended that the PS Act be repealed,
and a new section incorporated in the TP Act to provide for monitoring and
inquiries (see below).
The TP Act contains a number of existing provisions under which price monitoring
could be conducted:
• s. 28 provides for the functions of the ACCC in relation to dissemination of
information, law reform and research;
• s. 29 requires the ACCC to comply with directions of the Minister and
requirements of Parliament;
• Part IVB provides for voluntary or mandatory codes to be declared by the
ACCC; and
• s. 29B details the functions and powers of the National Competition Council
(NCC) (PC 2001c).
While these provisions do not provide specifically for price monitoring, they permit
the Minister to direct the ACCC or NCC to undertake research and analysis, and
could allow the Minister to direct either organisation to conduct price monitoring.
However, as noted in the review of the PS Act, these provisions lack a clear
framework for defining the objectives of monitoring and ensuring its appropriate
application.
The TP Act could also be amended to provide for price monitoring. This could be
done through either generic provisions as proposed in the Commission’s review of
the PS Act or industry-specific provisions. The Commission argued that the
inclusion of a new part in the TP Act:
… would consolidate the various legislative elements of Australia’s competition policy
into one legislative package. It would complement Part IIIA and Part IV of the TP Act
as an element of Australia’s competition policy. (PC 2001c, p. 84)
The Commission is of the view that any criteria for monitoring incorporated into
industry-specific legislation should reflect generic monitoring criteria and be
consistent with the monitoring principles discussed in the Commission’s review of
the PS Act.
As noted above, under its recommendation to repeal the PS Act and insert a new
section in the TP Act, the Commission proposed that the ACCC be responsible for
collating and auditing information and ensuring compliance. This would ensure the
ACCC’s expertise in monitoring prices is applied in the new regime. However,
Melbourne Airport, although not opposed to the ACCC taking such a role,
suggested that other agencies such as the BTE may also be able to fulfil that role,
particularly if the aim of monitoring is to inform policy makers rather than to trigger
intervention in pricing decisions.
Part IV
Though Part IV of the TP Act proscribes certain practices that can create market
power through restricting competition or through mergers, and makes illegal the use
of market power to harm or eliminate competitors where market power is already
established, Part IV relies on ex post remedies for abuse of market power, and
monopoly pricing per se is not proscribed. Although s. 46 can address pricing issues
such as price fixing or predatory pricing, it does not directly address situations
where market power results in monopoly prices. There would be no contravention
of s. 46 unless a pricing decision were taken for one of the purposes it proscribes.
The legal costs associated with prosecution for contravention of the provisions of
Part IV may also be significant, and it may be difficult to prove an offence has
occurred.
Access arrangements
Airport operators currently are subject to s. 192 of the Airports Act and Part IIIA
(the National Access Regime) of the TP Act. The five-year, automatic declarations
of privatised, core-regulated airports cannot be renewed under s. 192. However,
new airport-specific access arrangements or Part IIIA could continue to complement
any future price regulation of airport services or, indeed, provide an alternative to an
airport-specific price-regulation regime. Prices of airport services could be
regulated indirectly through regulation of the terms and conditions of access to an
airport service, if a service were declared.
There has been limited application of access provisions and general competition law
to airports to date (chapter 9). However, reliance on these provisions as an
alternative to direct regulation of prices could result in greater use of these
provisions by airport users.
Access regulation could have some advantages compared with price regulation. It is
activated only when a user complains and provides some encouragement of
commercial negotiation and agreements (PC 2001a). Though compliance costs can
be high, once precedents are set, the need for arbitration may decrease and the costs
of any arbitration may decrease as precedents are set and participants become more
familiar with the process.
Some participants argued that the general access provisions available under Part
IIIA (and the provisions of Part IV) provide sufficient regulation to prevent airports
abusing any market power. For example, the Australian Airports Association argued
that:
Due to the significant countervailing power of airlines, and the active competition
between airports for a range of important services, a strong argument can be made that
both the Prices Surveillance Act … and the automatic declaration of airport services for
the purposes of Part IIIA of the Trade Practices Act 1974 under s. 192 of the Airports
Act 1996 should be removed. This would leave airports subject to declaration under
Part IIIA on a case by case basis in the same way as any other infrastructure is liable to
Part IIIA, and subject to the usual application of Part IV of the [TP Act]. (sub. 15, p. 5)
7 Part VII of the TP Act confers on the ACCC power to authorise practices otherwise proscribed
under Part IV.
330 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
Nonetheless, application of Part IIIA to airports to date has raised a number of
concerns, including the degree to which the declaration criteria are open to
interpretation, that the national significance test is linked to the facility rather than
the service provided by the facility, and that there is considerable scope for delays
in the declaration process (see chapter 9 and PC (2001a) for a more detailed
discussion).
In the final report for its review of the National Access Regime, the Commission
proposed a number of amendments to the current Part IIIA regime to address these
and other concerns. Those relevant to airports include:
• modification of the declaration criteria, including a requirement that declaration
would promote a substantial increase in competition;
• inclusion of pricing principles to improve certainty for access seekers and
providers;
• provision for the ACCC to conduct multilateral arbitrations following
consultation with the parties to the dispute;
• provision to lodge undertakings after a service has been declared;
• appeal rights for decisions on undertaking applications; and
• exemption from Parts IV and VII of the TP Act of the terms and conditions of:
arbitrated determinations for declared services; agreements reached under
certified regimes or negotiated under accepted undertakings; and private
agreements for declared services covered by registered private contracts.
As it stands, s. 192 of the Airports Act effectively lapses once initial access
declarations expire. (As noted in chapter 3, the Minister is required to specify the
expiry date of the determination, and no power is conferred on the Minister under
s. 192 to renew the declaration once it has expired (ACCC, pers. comm., 5 July
2001).) These declarations expire on 30 June 2002 for Phase 1 airports and on
30 June 2003 for Phase 2 airports.
Though s. 192 could be amended to continue to operate in its current form, at issue
is whether there is a case for continuation of an airport-specific access regime and,
if so, what form that regime should take.
Moreover, that s. 192 has not been invoked extensively need not mean that it has
not influenced airport behaviour in other circumstances. As discussed in chapters 6
and 7, airports may have some incentive to frustrate access to other elements of the
airport where, by doing so, competition in a particular market (such as car parking)
can be constrained and monopoly profits earned by the airport operator. However,
airport operators do not seem to have strong reasons to deny or frustrate airline
access to the airport.
The only application of Part IIIA to airports to date has been the Australian Cargo
Terminal Operators (ACTO)8 declarations at Sydney and Melbourne International
Airports (chapter 9). Indeed, these are the only declarations in any industry to date
under Part IIIA. As noted in chapter 9, there were significant delays involved in
The Part IIIA declaration criteria are designed to ensure that the access framework
is applied only where access would promote competition in a related market, it is
uneconomic to develop another facility to provide the service, and the facility is of
national significance. The criteria for declaration as an airport service under s. 192
generally are weaker than the Part IIIA criteria.9 There is no requirement under
s. 192 that access to a service promote competition in another market, and the
facility need not be of national significance. Some participants noted (for example,
Hastings Funds Management (sub. 19) and SACL (sub. 27) that this could result in
broader coverage of services under s. 192 than would occur under Part IIIA.
The ACCC (sub. 38) suggested that the requirement under s. 192 that ‘facilities
cannot be economically duplicated’ should be amended to reflect the (possibly less
stringent) Part IIIA requirement that ‘it would be uneconomical for anyone to
develop another facility to provide the service’. It also advocated ‘specification of
certain up-front declared services, coupled with a mechanism for declaration of
other services (or variation of the initial list) in the future’ (sub. 38, p. 15).
9 A possible exception is that criterion (b) under Part IIIA, which requires that it be
uneconomical for anyone to develop another facility to provide the service, is potentially a
weaker test than the s. 192 test that the facility providing the service cannot be economically
duplicated (PC 1998a).
OPTIONS: PRICE 333
MONITORING AND
ACCESS
service to be a declared service for the purposes of Part IIIA. Section 192 does not
completely remove inefficiency from the administrative process, but it does improve it
greatly. (sub. 48, p. 27)
S. 192
S. 192(5) of the Airports Act states that an airport service means a service provided at
a core-regulated airport, where the service:
(a) is necessary for the purposes of operating and/or maintaining civil aviation services
at the airport; and
(b) is provided by means of significant facilities at the airport, being facilities that
cannot be economically duplicated;
and includes the use of those facilities for those purposes.
Part IIIA
S. 44G(2) of the Trade Practices Act states:
The [National Competition] Council cannot recommend that a service be declared
unless it is satisfied of all of the following matters:
(a) that access (or increased access) to the service would promote competition in at
least one market (whether or not in Australia), other than the market for the service;
(b) that it would be uneconomical for anyone to develop another facility to provide the
service;
(c) that the facility is of national significance, having regard to:
(i) the size of the facility; or
(ii) the importance of the facility to constitutional trade or commerce; or
(iii) the importance of the facility to the national economy;
(d) that access to the service can be provided without undue risk to human health or
safety;
(e) that access to the service is not already the subject of an effective access regime;
(f) that access (or increased access) to the service would not be contrary to the public
interest.
Sources: Airports Act 1996; Trade Practices Act 1974.
In its review of the National Access Regime, the Productivity Commission found:
The current approach of a national access regime operating in tandem with industry-
specific regimes has significant advantages. In effect, it draws on the strengths of both
the generic and specific approaches, while avoiding some of the pitfalls of a one-
dimensional solution.
Some changes to both Part IIIA and Clause 6 of the Competition Principles Agreement
are nonetheless required to strengthen the access framework and to discourage
unwarranted divergence across industry-specific regimes. (PC 2001a, p. 122)
In contrast, the ACCC’s proposal for up-front declaration of certain airport services
would seem to by-pass altogether the need for assessment of likely efficiency
outcomes of declaration, while the Qantas proposal would weaken further s. 192
criteria relative to current Part IIIA declaration criteria. Given that an airport’s
incentives to deny access are limited, the case for considerably weaker declaration
criteria than those applied to other industries does not seem to be strong. Despite its
proposal for listing declared airport services, the ACCC also observed:
When a service provider is vertically separated it will usually have little incentive to
deny access. While the service provider may exploit its market power by setting high
prices it is unlikely to manipulate other terms and conditions to limit access.
Nevertheless the negotiate-arbitrate provisions allow an access seeker to seek
arbitration over non-price terms and conditions. This could result in unnecessarily
intrusive arbitration over detailed operational matters. (sub. 36, p. 94)
However, this could be addressed to some extent within Part IIIA by allowing
‘multilateral’ arbitration of terms and conditions of access to a declared service. As
noted, the Commission has recommended such an amendment to Part IIIA in its
review of the National Access Regime. If such a change were not implemented
within the National Access Regime, an industry-specific regime that allowed for
multilateral arbitrations (but which was consistent with Part IIIA in other respects),
may warrant consideration.
FINDING 11.2
Undertakings
Some participants supported a model under which airport operators would develop
‘undertakings’, which set out the terms and conditions under which airport services
would be provided.
Part IIIA currently provides for airport operators to lodge access undertakings with
the ACCC, provided the services in question have not been declared for access
purposes. Airport services at privatised core-regulated airports were declared
automatically for the purposes of Part IIIA under s. 192, though they were given a
period of grace during which they could submit undertakings. Currently there is no
provision for undertakings covering declared airport services to be lodged
(chapter 3). However, declarations under s. 192 will expire on 30 June 2002 and
Qantas (trans., pp. 275–6) suggested that an access model based on an industry code
such as the National Electricity Code (NEC) (box 11.6) may be a desirable
approach to regulating prices for airport services. In particular, Qantas argued for
regulation of minimum service levels:
Qantas believes that the most effective and practical means to ensure minimum levels
of service quality within the airport industry is to include within the regulatory
framework service level commitments. These are included in other regulated industries
such as electricity. (sub. 48, p. 5)
In the final report for its review of the National Access Regime, the Commission
noted that the access arrangements in the NEC ‘result in a more prescriptive
approach to the provision of access than regimes in some other sectors that rely
more on commercial negotiations between the parties’ (PC 2001a, p. 450). The
Code effectively regulates prices and other terms and conditions of access. If such a
regime were imposed on airports it would impose considerably stronger regulation
than currently applies.
Airport-specific undertakings
The ACCC suggested that, although airports could be required to submit for
approval a set of price and non-price terms and conditions applicable to the
provision of the declared services at the airport and a dispute resolution mechanism:
… experience with airport regulation in Australia to date suggests that there are a
number of difficulties associated with putting in place ex ante terms and conditions for
access to core airport services. These arise primarily from the fact that airports provide
a range of interlinked but different (non-homogeneous) services, and that the dynamics
of the provision of those services is constantly changing in response to changing market
conditions. As a result, it is difficult to establish generic terms and conditions that are
sufficiently precise as to ensure that disputes will not arise in relation to their
application in a particular case. (sub. 38, pp. 14–15)
Just as the Commission does not see a strong case for setting weaker declaration
criteria for airports, it does not consider that airports should be compelled to submit
or meet prescribed access obligations. At the same time, the Commission does not
consider that airports should be allowed exemption from declaration for access
purposes on the basis of undertakings that otherwise would not satisfy Part IIIA
criteria. In other words, insofar as third party access is concerned, airports should be
treated neither more strictly nor more leniently than other industries.
FINDING 11.3
Commercial agreements
The model advocated by Ansett, which in its view would provide flexibility for
airports and airlines to reach commercial agreement, while providing a framework
to moderate the market power of airports, is a variation of the industry-specific
That such guidance from government may be helpful for commercial entities in a
commercial environment is perhaps surprising. The reason for it is the historical
legacy of decades of government ownership of this industry and the pervasive
effects of regulation.
In this chapter, the Commission outlines its assessment of the need for price
regulation of particular airports and airport services, and its preferred option for
such regulation.
APPROPRIATE 343
FUTURE
REGULATION
As noted in chapter 4, in essence these principles (many of which mirror the
Competition Principles Agreement) suggest that any future regulation should be the
least required to target the source of any problem and promote efficient outcomes,
while being applied in a way that fosters market outcomes where feasible, imposes
minimal compliance costs on all parties, and promotes transparency and
competition. Importantly, the terms of reference guide the Commission to
recommend regulation only where it is necessary to promote efficient outcomes.
The Commission considers that the four largest Australian airports — Sydney,
Melbourne, Brisbane and Perth — have a high degree of market power in core
aeronautical services and therefore warrant some form of airport-specific price
regulation, additional to general third-party access and competition regulation. As
discussed in chapter 11, these general provisions of the Trade Practices Act
1974 (TP Act), while potentially regulating some terms and conditions (of declared
services) and proscribing certain practices of firms with market power, would not
regulate prices of aeronautical services per se.
Remaining core-regulated airports, because they appear to have much less market
power, or because, given their size, the costs of regulation would far outweigh any
potential benefits, should not be subject to any airport-specific economic regulation,
including price or quality monitoring. (They would continue to be subject to the
TP Act (as would all airports) and relevant provisions of the Airports Act 1996.)
For those airports with moderate to high market power, the Commission considers
that, based on its assessment of various regulatory options in chapters 10 and 11,
two types of regulation, incentive-based price caps and price monitoring, merit
consideration. The choice essentially comes down to forms of regulation that best
promote incentives for efficient outcomes. Of the stricter forms of price regulation,
CPI-X price caps provide the best incentives but inevitably they bring significant
risks of regulatory error. Given that airports face several commercial constraints and
incentives that will moderate their behaviour, the Commission sees significant
advantages in a more light-handed approach involving price monitoring. Therefore,
two regulatory options are outlined, differentiated by their treatment of Sydney,
Melbourne, Brisbane and Perth airports.
For Melbourne, Brisbane and Perth airports, an annual CPI-X price cap would be
set for five years, complemented by price and quality monitoring.
The price cap would apply only to those aeronautical services in which the three
airports have been assessed by the Commission as having a high degree of market
power. Broadly speaking, this means all services designated as aeronautical services
for the purposes of current price caps plus aircraft refuelling services (box 12.1).
APPROPRIATE 345
FUTURE
REGULATION
However, some assets (such as landside roads) that are used for both aeronautical
and non-aeronautical purposes will have to be apportioned between these activities.
Average prices allowed under price caps should broadly reflect the anticipated cost
of efficiently providing regulated aeronautical services on a dual-till basis
(box 12.2). In other words, unlike current price caps where inherited single-till
prices are adjusted incrementally as new investment is put in place, the cap should
correspond to anticipated efficient dual-till prices.
APPROPRIATE 347
FUTURE
REGULATION
Price monitoring of some services currently designated as ‘aeronautical related’, in
which market power has been assessed as moderate (for example, check-in
counters, staff car parking) would continue at these airports (box 12.1).
For reasons discussed in box 12.3 and appendixes F and H, in the absence of
defined slot rights and trading mechanisms, regulation preferably should allow
aeronautical prices at a capacity-constrained Sydney Airport to reflect more closely
the opportunity costs incurred by airlines and their passengers in using the facility
(that is, the value of slots to those who miss out at peak times), rather than simply
reflecting the efficient costs of production.
At the very least, provided capacity remains constrained, aeronautical prices should
not be required to decline in real terms and should be adequate to encourage
efficient, feasible expansion of aeronautical capacity at that facility.
• This could be implemented either by requiring notification of aeronautical price
increases above the CPI, or by imposing a CPI-X cap with the X set at zero.
• In either case, price increases should be allowed to reflect peak-period demand
(as provided for in the current regulatory framework for Phase 1 airports), and to
accommodate necessary investment.
For all other airports, there would be no airport-specific price regulation or quality
monitoring. This would require amendment of the Airports Act so that Hobart,
Launceston, Alice Springs, Coolangatta and Townsville airports no longer were
designated as ‘core-regulated’ airports.
APPROPRIATE 349
FUTURE
REGULATION
Option A: review and access provisions
An independent, public review would need to be conducted towards the end of the
five-year period to ascertain, on the basis of that experience, whether there should
be any future price regulation of price-capped and price-monitored airports. Other
airports should be included in this review only where there is prima facie evidence
of persistent misuse of market power. Proposed review guidelines are set out under
Option B in section 12.4.
All airports, whether they are subject to price regulation or not, should be subject to
the generic provisions of the National Access Regime (Part IIIA of the TP Act). An
airport-specific access regime for price-regulated airports should be considered only
if procedural improvements, such as scope for multilateral arbitrations
recommended in the Commission’s Review of the National Access Regime
(PC 2001a), were not made to that regime (chapter 11).
Price monitoring
For Sydney, Melbourne, Brisbane, Perth, Adelaide, Canberra and Darwin airports,
there would be mandatory price monitoring by the ACCC. The monitoring regime
would continue for five years.
• During this probationary period, the regulator would not have the power to alter
unilaterally the monitoring regime or impose stricter price regulation.
• Information requirements would be specified at the commencement of the period
and could not be amended without agreement of the parties. As outlined in
box 12.4, the Commission envisages somewhat more detailed monitoring of
Sydney, Melbourne, Brisbane and Perth airports (specifically, requiring
reporting of the weighted average cost of capital (WACC) for aeronautical
APPROPRIATE 351
FUTURE
REGULATION
Quality monitoring
Commercial agreements
Review criteria
An independent public review would need to be conducted towards the end of the
five-year monitoring period to ascertain whether there should be any future price
regulation of those airports. Other airports could be included in the review only
where there is prima facie evidence of persistent misuse of market power.
• Factors to be taken into account by the review in assessing whether airports have
abused market power should be specified at the start of the regulatory period.
Suggested criteria are summarised in box 12.5. Efficient pricing principles for
airports are discussed in chapter 4 and also have been developed more generally
by the Commission in its reviews of the National Access Regime and
Telecommunications Competition Regulation (PC 2001a and 2001d). They are
predicated on the need to avoid excessive prices, without the regulator
attempting to set prices too precisely, with the resultant risk that prices may be
pushed too low and efficient investment discouraged.
• In line with these principles, at least at airports without significant peak periods,
efficient prices broadly should generate revenue that is not significantly above
the long-run costs of efficiently providing aeronautical services (on a stand-alone
basis). At airports with significant capacity constraints, as discussed in box 12.3
and appendix H, efficient peak/off-peak prices may generate revenue that
exceeds the production costs incurred by the airport. Price discrimination also
352 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
can promote efficiency — this may mean that some users pay a price above the
long-run average costs of providing aeronautical services, while more price-
sensitive users pay a price below it.
• Additional factors to be taken into account by the review would include whether
quality has deteriorated or failed to meet the requirements of users; the extent to
which commercial agreements have been negotiated; the level of consultation
and exchange of information; and the level (and success) of applications for
access and the number (and validity) of user complaints.
Pricing principles
• At airports without significant capacity constraints, efficient prices broadly should
generate expected revenue that is not significantly above the long-run costs of
efficiently providing aeronautical services (on a dual-till basis). Prices should allow a
return on (appropriately defined and valued) assets (including land) commensurate
with the regulatory and commercial risks involved.
• At airports with significant capacity constraints, efficient peak/off-peak prices may
generate revenues that exceed the production costs incurred by the airport.
• Price discrimination and multi-part pricing that promote efficient use of the airport
should be encouraged. This may mean that some users pay a price above the long-
run average costs of providing aeronautical services, whereas more price-sensitive
users pay a price close to marginal cost.
Other criteria
• Whether quality-of-service outcomes have deteriorated and/or failed to meet the
requirements of users.
• The extent to which commercial agreements on prices and quality of service have
been negotiated.
• The degree of consultation with airport users and the extent of the exchange of
information.
• The number and outcome of applications for third-party access and the extent and
validity of user complaints.
For all other airports, there would be no airport-specific price regulation or quality-
of-service monitoring. This would require amendment of the Airports Act so that
APPROPRIATE 353
FUTURE
REGULATION
Hobart, Launceston, Alice Springs, Coolangatta and Townsville Airports no longer
were designated as ‘core-regulated’ airports.
For all airports, access provisions (and provisions for access undertakings) should
not differ from the generic provisions of the National Access Regime (Part IIIA of
the TP Act). An airport-specific access regime should be considered only if
procedural improvements, such as scope for multilateral arbitrations (as
recommended by the Commission in its Review of the National Access Regime
(PC 2001a)), are not made to that regime. The Commission sees no need to exempt
from access regulation airports that enter into commercial agreements with users.
The Commission has not been persuaded, however, that there is a strong case for
the continuation of price caps at any privatised core-regulated airports. This is for
two principal reasons.
The first is the ever-present risk of regulatory failure, given the severe information
problems confronting any regulator. Setting price caps inevitably entails detailed
regulatory assessment of, and involvement in, airport operations and investment
decisions. It should therefore be used only where the potential efficiency costs of
abuse of market power are significant. Even then there is a risk that regulation will
cause its own distortions to production and investment decisions. While the
Commission agrees that some transitional problems with current price-cap
arrangements may have been settled, and that the price caps proposed under
Option A should reduce regulatory involvement in investment decisions, the risk of
regulatory failure remains high. This risk has been amplified by the uncertainty that
currently pervades global aviation markets.
The second and related reason is that the ‘problem’ to be addressed does not
warrant such a heavy-handed regulatory regime. Though the four largest airports
have considerable market power, the prospect of them using that power in a way
that would generate significant costs to the economy or community is supported
neither by the evidence nor the analysis. There are strong commercial incentives
pulling in the other direction, including scope for increased profits in non-
aeronautical activities from increasing passenger volumes, and incentives to
discriminate and differentiate in pricing.
On balance, therefore, the Commission considers that while the undoubted market
power of the four major airports warrants some form of regulatory constraint, the
continuation of price caps is not the best approach. Option B offers a much better
regulatory mechanism for promoting the principles for regulation identified in the
terms of reference.
APPROPRIATE 355
FUTURE
REGULATION
numerous unregulated smaller airports, both privately- and publicly-owned, and
some unregulated larger ones (for example, Cairns). Relations may not always be
smooth, but there seems to be considerable scope for reasonable commercial
interaction between airports and users, provided there is some ultimate constraint on
abuse of any market power (which Option B provides, in addition to the TP Act).
Some participants expressed concern about the need for additional public scrutiny
of any principles designed to guide airport behaviour. However, what the
Commission is proposing (box 12.5) is not detailed prescription, but rather broad
principles of efficient pricing that have been discussed extensively during this
inquiry and parallel inquiries into infrastructure regulation (including reviews of the
National Access Regime, the PS Act and Telecommunications Competition
Regulation).
Some participants also cited their interpretation of the recent New Zealand
experience with light-handed regulation in an attempt to rebut the Commission’s
price-monitoring option. But, closer examination reveals that the New Zealand
system, notwithstanding some deficiencies, has not been a failure (chapter 11). For
example, Auckland and Christchurch airports have agreed on new aeronautical
prices with their major airline customers, and those price outcomes do not appear
excessive.
While light-handed regulation currently is not the dominant model worldwide, there
are signs that the direction is changing. For example, in the United Kingdom, the
Civil Aviation Authority recently has proposed modifications to regulatory
arrangements that are in part designed to foster commercial negotiation between
airports and airlines at major airports.
The Commission considers that the full benefits of privatisation of airports are
unlikely to be realised if commercial relationships between airports and airlines
continue to be heavily conditioned by intrusive price regulation. The ongoing need
for substantial investments at major airports requires a more commercial and
cooperative approach. The potential for regulation unduly to constrain prices poses
a real risk and one that could impose significant costs on consumers in the future.
RECOMMENDATION 12.1
For Sydney, Melbourne, Brisbane and Perth airports, price caps and prices
notification arrangements should be replaced by mandatory price monitoring
arrangements for a probationary five-year period, as outlined in Option B.
• Airport-specific price-monitoring arrangements could be incorporated either
in the Airports Act 1996 (Airports Act) or the Trade Practices Act 1974
(TP Act), but should be consistent with any generic price-monitoring
provisions that may be introduced into the TP Act following the Commission’s
separate review of the Prices Surveillance Act 1983 (PS Act).
APPROPRIATE 357
FUTURE
REGULATION
In the event that the Government opted for a stricter form of price regulation at
these four airports, Option A should apply such that:
• annual price caps of the form CPI-X continue for five years at Melbourne,
Brisbane and Perth airports. Price caps should be set to reflect the efficient
costs of providing aeronautical services in the long run, on a dual-till basis.
Price caps should be complemented by price monitoring of some
‘aeronautical-related’ services; and
• for a capacity-constrained Sydney Airport, prices should not be required to fall
in real terms. Regulation should comprise either prices notification or a price
cap of the form CPI-X, with X set at zero. Price increases should be allowed to
reflect peak-period demand and to accommodate necessary investment.
RECOMMENDATION 12.2
RECOMMENDATION 12.3
RECOMMENDATION 12.4
Neither price monitoring nor price caps should be reintroduced for Alice Springs,
Coolangatta, Hobart, Launceston and Townsville airports. The Airports Act
should be amended so that these airports are no longer designated as ‘core-
regulated’ airports.
RECOMMENDATION 12.5
RECOMMENDATION 12.6
Price regulation of airports should be reviewed towards the end of the five-year
regulatory period. The review should be independent and public. Its objective
358 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
should be to ascertain the need for any future price regulation of airports
(including price monitoring or more stringent price regulation). In making its
assessment, the review should be guided by principles of efficient pricing plus
several other criteria set out under Option B. Agreed review criteria should be
spelt out at the beginning of the regulatory period.
Other airports should be included in the review only where there was prima facie
evidence of persistent misuse of market power (namely, evidence of inefficient
prices, poor quality etc).
RECOMMENDATION 12.7
All airports should be subject to the generic provisions of the National Access
Regime in Part IIIA of the TP Act. An airport-specific access regime should be
considered only if procedural improvements, such as scope for multilateral
arbitrations, are not made to the National Access Regime.
RECOMMENDATION 12.8
APPROPRIATE 359
FUTURE
REGULATION
APPENDIXES
A Terms of reference: correspondence
TERMS OF 363
REFERENCE:
CORRESPONDENCE
364 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
B Public consultation
PUBLIC 365
CONSULTATION
Major, Hugh DR79
Melbourne Airport 7, 37, DR66
MTAA Superannuation Fund Pty Ltd 22, 34, DR67
Northern Territory Airports Pty Ltd 25, 50, DR71
Perth Airports Municipalities Group 12
Qantas Airways Limited 48
Queensland Transport 31
Regional Aviation Association of Australia DR64
Scott-Bloxam, W.H. 2
Shell Australia DR63
South Australian Government 33
Stott, Donald 29
Sydney Airports Corporation Limited 27, DR62
Tourism Tasmania 13
Victorian Hire Car Association DR68
Virgin Blue 30, DR74
Western Australian Government 17
Westralia Airports Corporation Pty Ltd 21
B.2 Visits
Adelaide Airport Limited
Airport Co-ordination Australia
Airservices Australia
AMP Henderson
Ansett Australia
Australian Airports Association
Australian Competition and Consumer Commission
Australian Federation of International Forwarders
Australia Pacific Airports Corporation
Board of Airline Representatives of Australia Inc
Brisbane Airport Corporation Limited
Bureau of Transport Economics
Cairns Port Authority
Capital Airport Group
Commerce Commission (New Zealand)
Department of the Treasury (Cwlth)
PUBLIC 367
CONSULTATION
Northern Territory Airports Pty Ltd
Professor Peter Forsyth
Qantas Airways Limited
Sydney Airports Corporation Limited
Virgin Blue
Western Australian Government
Westralia Airports Corporation Pty Ltd
This appendix explores some conceptual issues arising from the complementary
provision of aeronautical and non-aeronautical services at most major airports,
specifically:
• implications for pricing of aeronautical services;
• the distinction between locational rents and monopoly profits; and
• arguments for and against ‘single-till’ regulation.
Despite this competition, it would appear, for most core-regulated airports, that the
profitability of non-aeronautical services exceeds that of aeronautical activities. The
report prepared for the ACCC by KPMG (sub. 36, attachment A) provides some
evidence that this result is not attributable to arbitrary allocation of costs across the
two categories.
1 Not all services are complementary, however. As noted in chapter 2, some airports are
developing business parks that appear as dependent on local business as on the airport.
AERONAUTICAL AND 369
NON-AERONAUTICAL
SERVICES
The current imbalance in profitability may reflect regulation of aeronautical
charges. In the absence of price-cap regulation, airports may raise aeronautical
charges and their profits from this sector.2
The other key requirement is that the demand for non-aeronautical services (and
hence profits from these activities) flows directly from consumption of aeronautical
services, not the other way around. This condition appears to be met at airports. It is
unlikely that people primarily visit an airport to shop and decide to take a flight
while they are there. As Kahn notes:
The critical condition for such a cross-subsidization (pricing one of the complementary
products below its separate incremental cost) is that the cross-elasticity of demand for
the complementary service be high enough to compensate for the out-of-pocket losses
on the sales of the first of these, considered in isolation. (Kahn 2001a, p. 17)
Figure C.1 illustrates the possibility. The diagram is a modified version of Starkie’s
(2001c) exposition. The figure shows a stylised price of, and demand for,
aeronautical services (eg for landings or use of terminal facilities) at an airport. As
drawn, the demand curve is downward-sloping and therefore assumes that the
airport has some market power. For simplicity, marginal (and average) costs of
providing these facilities are assumed to be equal and constant.
2 This could result from airports using their market power to push prices above efficient levels or
it may just be that current charges are below levels consistent with cost-recovery and therefore
would rise even in the absence of market power (chapter 8).
370 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
Figure C.1 Aeronautical pricing with non-aeronautical profits
Paero
MRaero+MPna
Pm
Pna
MC=ACaero
Pc
Daero
MRaero Qaero
It is possible, even where demand and profit increases are feasible, that prices will
not be reduced for all users of aeronautical facilities. Airports (with excess capacity)
have an incentive to target price discounts at marginal, or more price sensitive,
airlines and passengers, especially those who contribute more to non-aeronautical
profits (eg international passengers).
Additional airport profits from related non-aeronautical activities may also augment
airlines’ bargaining power: the potential loss of airport profits will be greater for
any threatened reduction in services by airlines.
Provided airports do not constrain artificially the provision of space for non-
aeronautical facilities, profits earned from providing such space will reflect
locational rents. These rents in turn reflect the inherent scarcity of land proximate
and convenient to airside activities at an airport. An airport’s ability to raise prices
through artificial scarcity will be constrained by the ability of concessionaires to
locate, and consumers to purchase, elsewhere. For example, any monopoly profits
(that is, in excess of locational rents) earned from car parking are likely to
encourage off-airport providers and substitution by airport users to other travel
modes.4 Monopoly retail rentals would drive concessionaires to relocate because
uncompetitive rentals cannot be passed on to consumers (who, in turn, have a range
of choices of where to buy these goods and services).
3 Some airport operators also may just be very good at developing profitable ventures at airports.
In this case it may be expected that skilled personnel would retain a reasonable share of any
quasi-rents in the form of higher remuneration.
4 However, the airport’s control over ‘front-door’ access may allow it to influence competition
from off-airport car-park providers and other travel modes (chapters 6 and 7).
AERONAUTICAL AND 373
NON-AERONAUTICAL
SERVICES
power are then regulated under price caps. Airports are free to set rentals and prices
for retail and other non-aeronautical activities. Car-park prices have been monitored
by the ACCC (chapter 3) but car-parking revenue has not been taken into account
when setting the price caps.
This contrasts with the single-till regulatory arrangements for major airports in the
United Kingdom, where revenues from non-aeronautical services are subtracted
from expected airport-wide costs to determine allowable revenue from aeronautical
services (appendix G). A similar system was used to set aeronautical charges at
Federal Airports Corporation-operated airports prior to privatisation — aeronautical
charges covered residual capital and operating costs (plus a real rate of return on
capital) after taking into account projected revenues from non-aeronautical
activities.
Privatised core-regulated airports appear to have been sold on the basis that a single
till would ‘not be mandated’, and the Commonwealth Government, in April 2001,
directed the ACCC to implement a dual till at Sydney Airport (Direction No. 22).
But, as outlined in chapter 10, several participants (Board of Airline Representatives
of Australia (BARA), Ansett and Qantas; subs 41, 42 and 48) argued in favour of
airport price regulation on a full or partial single-till basis on the grounds that
efficient pricing requires it.
One argument put for a single till is that profits earned in non-aeronautical activities
reflect market power rather than economic (locational) rent. If this were the case,
then the single till may not prevent excessive pricing of non-aeronautical services
by airports. It merely would require that monopoly profits earned in non-
aeronautical activities were transferred to airlines and their passengers. However,
the single till could remove the incentive to earn these profits. This would be a
desirable, if unintended, consequence of a single till. If prices of non-aeronautical
services reflected market power, it may be more appropriate to reduce them directly
to promote efficient consumption and to protect consumers of the service.
BARA, Ansett and Qantas (subs 41, 42 and 48) argued that efficient pricing of
airports requires that any locational rents earned from non-aeronautical activities by
airports should be applied to reduce aeronautical charges. BARA demonstrated that
if there were two identical airports (including, it must be assumed, with respect to
the relative attractiveness of their location), then competition for customers would
ensure that both airports earned normal profits. BARA is correct that if there were
no scarcity in the supply of any factor used in the production of airport services (and
no natural monopoly characteristics), long-run supply would be perfectly elastic.
Consequently, there would be no producer surplus (rent) earned on infra-marginal
units.
BARA (sub. DR54) cited the example of petrol stations that combine petrol
retailing with convenience outlets. In this industry, competition will drive down the
price of petrol such that any rents earned in the related retailing activity are
competed away. If there is no scarcity of any factor, then rents will not be earned in
the first place — that is, the price of petrol will decline only if the
petrol/convenience store combination reduces the cost of selling petrol. However, if
some petrol stations are more conveniently located than others and attract more
customers to their convenience stores, rents will be earned at these stores that will
not be bid away (unless another petrol station can open in the same location).
Therefore, even in highly-competitive industries, price-taking producers in
relatively high-yield locations (whether because of convenience or natural
phenomena) will earn and retain locational rents.5
In the case of airports, natural monopoly characteristics mean that there is only one
major regular public transport airport in each Australian capital city. This, in turn,
means that airport land that can be used to provide a range of non-aeronautical
activities (albeit complementary with aeronautical services), is scarce. (It may be
the case, if airport services could be supplied by large numbers of providers in any
location, that airport land would not be scarce. The reality is different, however.
Airport services are not supplied (efficiently) by a highly-competitive market.)
Given this scarcity, locational rents can be earned. As in any market where there is a
scarce factor, there does not appear to be any reason on efficiency grounds that
scarcity rents should accrue to consumers. Indeed, as discussed below, preventing
returns to owner-operators that reflect scarcity may discourage optimal use of the
scarce factor of production.
5 Generally, the rents will accrue to the original owner/exploiter of the site’s value. Those who
subsequently buy the site will pay the discounted, capitalised value of anticipated rents in the
sale price.
AERONAUTICAL AND 375
NON-AERONAUTICAL
SERVICES
As the UK Civil Aviation Authority noted:
Given the cost structure of airports and the diverse services which they provide … it is
unlikely that the provision of airport services would be perfectly
competitive … Moreover, given that capacity constraints are the key issue for the
industry, this characterisation assumes that scarcity rents which follow from planning
restrictions should necessarily be clawed back by the regulatory regime. This has not
occurred in the case of supermarkets … or in other markets where scarcity rents
exist … (CAA 2000f, pp. 11–12)
Demand complementarities
Common costs
Another argument for a single till is that a multi-product monopoly (with large fixed
common costs and a requirement to be (just) self-financing) should be encouraged
to set prices to minimise efficiency losses — that is, to implement Ramsey pricing
(Crew and Kleindorfer 2001). Generally, this means that markets/customers with
relatively inelastic demand should bear a greater share of common, fixed costs than
do those with more elastic demand.
This argument appears to rest on two assumptions — namely, that there are
significant common costs in supplying aeronautical and non-aeronautical services,
and that demand for non-aeronautical services is less elastic than demand for
aeronautical services. If these assumptions hold, common costs could be covered
more efficiently by increasing the prices of non-aeronautical services relative to
those of aeronautical services. However, the extent of common costs in the
The ACCC compared opposing arguments of Kahn, and Crew and Kleindorfer, on
this point:
Professor Kahn argues that the apparently high returns accruing to airport operators
from retail services is related to the locational advantage of the airport. Implicit in this
argument is the point that SACL’s monopoly market power does not extend beyond
those services defined as aeronautical. By contrast, Professors Crew and Kleindorfer
explicitly state that SACL’s proposal ‘develops a multi-till approach to price
regulation, but this proposed approach leads to a number of problems, not least of
which is that it allows non-aeronautical services to be priced at monopoly levels’.
For the reasons outlined above, the Commission [ACCC] agrees with Professor Kahn
that the dual till is in general a superior approach to aeronautical pricing, provided the
services defined as aeronautical include all those in which the airport operator has
significant market power. (sub. 36, p. 74)
6 This assumes that the marginal locational rent flowing from car parking is not inflated by any
market power in that activity. That is, the rent received does not exceed the marginal rent
forgone from not using the land in the next-best, alternative (competitive) use.
378 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
• Some rents may reflect an airport owner/operator’s entrepreneurial rather than
locational advantage. Appropriation of rents from this source could encourage
these operators to move to activities where rents were not taxed as heavily.7
• Reducing aeronautical charges can promote efficiency only if stand-alone
aeronautical prices exceed their marginal cost. As discussed above, it is possible
that an airport, internalising complementary demands for non-aeronautical
services, voluntarily sets aeronautical prices for marginal customers close (or at
least closer) to marginal cost. Airports may also charge in such a way that
marginal consumers are not deterred from using the facility (via some form of
discriminatory pricing). In both cases, the efficiency argument for single-till
pricing is weakened.
• Alternatively, marginal costs may exceed average costs, for example, as a result
of capacity constraints or decreasing returns to scale at airports. If an airport is
already experiencing excess demand (that is, charges are below market-clearing
levels), then as noted by Kahn (2001a), lower aeronautical prices largely will
redistribute profits from airports to airlines — fares will not fall (for there will be
no incentive for airlines to reduce fares below market-clearing levels), so airline
profits will rise.8 With prices below market-clearing levels, limited capacity will
have to be rationed by a non-price mechanism which, almost inevitably, will
incur efficiency costs.9
• In effect, single-till regulation can impose incentives similar to those of cost-
based regulation on non-aeronautical activities. One possible result — as for
most cost-based regulation — is that airports will have an incentive to inflate the
costs of non-aeronautical activities to reduce measured profits, with consequent
losses of productive efficiency. It also could lead to a perverse situation where
aeronautical activities effectively subsidised inefficient expansion of non-
aeronautical activities (eg if airports undertook inefficient investment in retail
facilities to increase costs and reduce non-aeronautical returns on assets).
(Starkie and Yarrow 2000)
7 In the economy as a whole, rents are taxed via capital gains and income taxes. The single till, in
the limit, imposes a 100 per cent tax on rents.
8 The ACCC (sub. 36) appeared to reject this argument, at least in relation to Sydney Airport, on
the basis that there is scope for inter-airline competition. While this potential exists, at peak
times when slots are fully allocated, airlines are unlikely to initiate a discount war for peak
traffic. This is unlikely because the scope for a more efficient airline to increase market share is
limited by the slot allocation scheme — a more efficient airline, officially, cannot buy extra
slots. In other words, airlines are unlikely to compete on price among each other for additional
customers who, without an additional slot, they cannot carry (appendix H).
9 Even in the (unlikely) event that a non-price rationing scheme allocates capacity to those who
value it most highly, administration of the scheme will not be costless and wasteful rent-
seeking is likely to be encouraged (appendix H).
AERONAUTICAL AND 379
NON-AERONAUTICAL
SERVICES
• In the case of privatised core-regulated Australian airports, an additional
complication would arise from introduction of a single till. These airports appear
to have paid for the rights to exploit commercial opportunities on airport land (as
the result of a competitive bidding process) and the land-owner (the
Commonwealth Government) largely has captured expected (infra-marginal)
locational rents already.10 In this sense, some or all of the locational rents earned
by airports are not pure profits. If these rents were redistributed to airlines and/or
their customers, then airports would be likely to suffer large capital losses.
Changing the rules could also raise concerns about sovereign risk for future
investors in airports and possibly other regulated activities.
In sum, where the airport has little or no market power in the provision of non-
aeronautical services, there may be a theoretical case to appropriate airport
locational rents to push the price of aeronautical activities closer to marginal cost.
Gains are possible only when the marginal cost of providing aeronautical services
lies below their average cost and the airport operator cannot or does not offer
inducements to marginal airport users.
A dual till, which regulates only those aeronautical services in which an airport is
most likely to have market power, is not without problems, particularly in its
implementation. A dual till requires the regulatory basket to be clearly and
comprehensively defined (see chapters 8 and 9 for a discussion of some issues
arising from the definition of current price caps). Further, if prices under a price cap
reflect airport costs, then any common costs must be allocated between regulated
and unregulated activities. Under a dual till, an airport also has a strong incentive to
10 This raises the question of whether it may be more appropriate for the Commonwealth
Government to use airport lease sale proceeds to subsidise aeronautical activities, if such
subsidisation were considered efficient. Indeed, it could be argued that the Government did this
to some extent by selling core-regulated airports subject to five-year price caps that largely
maintained single-till aeronautical prices.
380 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
restrict competition from off-airport providers (eg by restricting access to the airport
or by extending the airport’s boundaries by regulation).11
A dual till also has the potential to discourage investment in aeronautical services in
favour of non-aeronautical services if allowable returns in the former are
constrained relative to returns in the latter. At the same time, however, an airport
operator may have an incentive to expand aeronautical capacity to increase
passenger throughput and, consequently, rents from commercial activities. This may
offset any tendency for under-investment in aeronautical facilities.
11 The airport also could buy up surrounding land, but presumably it would have to compete with
other buyers and pay a competitive price.
AERONAUTICAL AND 381
NON-AERONAUTICAL
SERVICES
D Characteristics of demand and
competition at core-regulated airports
This appendix summarises the main demand and competition characteristics of the
core-regulated airports. These are used in the analysis of the extent of market power
held by particular airports in providing domestic passenger services (chapter 5).
In the tables that follow, the categories ‘annual passenger movements’ and
‘proportion of passenger movements that is international’ are for 2000-01 and are
taken from the Department of Transport and Regional Services (unpublished data).
The ‘proportion of revenue that is non-aeronautical’ is taken from ACCC (2001b, c,
d, f, m), for 2000-01 for Sydney Airport and 1999-00 for all other airports. As noted
in chapter 2, non-aeronautical revenue covers a range of services, not all of which
are provided at all core-regulated airports (eg business parks). This may contribute
to some of the variation in the proportion of non-aeronautical revenue across
airports. ‘Main market segments’ generally refers to interstate overnight visitors to
the city, region or State (not the airport) (where it refers to domestic — interstate
and intrastate — visitors, this is stated). Unless otherwise stated, these data, as well
as data on modal substitution possibilities, are from BTR (2000b) for 1999.
CHARACTERISTICS 383
OF CORE-REGULATED
AIRPORTS
Table D.2 Demand and competition characteristics of Alice Springs
Airport
Annual passenger movements : 717 722
Proportion of passenger movements : 0%
that is international
Proportion of revenue that is : 61%
non-aeronautical
Main market segments (percentage of : Holiday/leisure (55% to the Northern Territory as a
interstate overnight visitors in 1999) whole). Of all travellers (including interstate and
international) to the ‘Centre’ region, 77% went for
holiday/leisure purposes in 1999-00 (NTTC 2000).
Destination substitution possibilities : High, because Alice Springs competes with other
tourist destinations.
Modal substitution possibilities : Moderate. More than half the interstate visitors to
the Northern Territory arrive by air, but a significant
proportion (over 40% in 1999-00 (NTTC 2000))
arrives by other modes.
Airport substitution possibilities : High. Yulara (Ayers Rock) Airport provides a viable
alternative to Alice Springs, especially for tourists
who travel to destinations such as Uluru.
CHARACTERISTICS 385
OF CORE-REGULATED
AIRPORTS
Table D.6 Demand and competition characteristics of Darwin Airport
Annual passenger movements : 1 078 481
Proportion of passenger movements : 16%
that is international
Proportion of revenue that is : 54%
non-aeronautical
Main market segments (percentage of : Holiday/leisure (55% of interstate overnight visitors
interstate overnight visitors in 1999) to the Northern Territory as a whole; and 55% of all
visitors (including interstate and international) to the
‘Top End’ region of the Northern Territory in 1999-00
(NTTC 2000)).
Destination substitution possibilities : High. Although the proportion of business travellers
to the ‘Top End’ is higher than for the rest of the
Territory, most travellers go for a holiday. Therefore,
Darwin and surrounding areas compete with other
tourist destinations, including other areas in the
Territory.
Modal substitution possibilities : Low for business travellers and other travellers
visiting Darwin only, given the relative isolation of
Darwin. For holiday travellers who visit several
regions in the Territory, the potential for modal
substitution appears to be more significant (over
40% of interstate visitors to the Territory arrived by
modes other than air in 1999-00 (NTTC 2000)).
Airport substitution possibilities : Vary by market segment. Low for those visiting only
the ‘Top End’. May be higher for those visiting
several areas within the Territory, but still likely to be
low overall.
CHARACTERISTICS 387
OF CORE-REGULATED
AIRPORTS
Table D.10 Demand and competition characteristics of Perth Airport
Annual passenger movements : 5 162 980
Proportion of passenger movements : 31%
that is international
Proportion of revenue that is : 71%
non-aeronautical
Main market segments (percentage of : For Western Australia as a whole, business (40%)
interstate overnight visitors in 1999) and VFR (26%).
Destination substitution possibilities : Relatively low, given the dominance of business and
VFR travellers.
Modal substitution possibilities : Low, given the isolation of Perth. Of interstate
overnight arrivals to Western Australia in 1999, 82%
arrived by plane.
Airport substitution possibilities : Low. There are no proximate RPT airports.
CHARACTERISTICS 389
OF CORE-REGULATED
AIRPORTS
E Fuel throughput levies and taxi
charges
The introduction of fuel throughput levies and taxi charges by some airport
operators has generated considerable debate. This appendix describes the
background to these charges, discusses their treatment under price regulation
following the sale of leases, and highlights issues for future regulation.
Background
Refuelling facilities at Brisbane and Perth (international) airports are known as joint
user hydrant installations (JUHIs). They consist of a fuel storage facility, a hydrant
Airport operators charge the oil companies for use of the land by way of licence
fees and rents payable pursuant to the leases under which the oil companies occupy
the refuelling sites. This charge for aircraft refuelling services, when imposed by the
Federal Airports Corporation (FAC), was not subject to prices surveillance. Since
the sale of leases for Phase 1 and 2 airports, and the lease of Sydney Airport to
Sydney Airports Corporation Limited, this charge has been subject to price
monitoring by the ACCC.
According to BP (sub. to ACCC 1998b), in 1995 the FAC mooted the concept of a
fuel throughput levy during negotiations with the oil companies to establish a
standard licence for JUHIs. The oil companies strongly resisted the inclusion of a
fuel throughput levy in a standard licence. Negotiations stalled until 1997 when the
oil companies signed the licences (to continue for 15 years), with the inclusion of a
provision for a fuel throughput levy. The FAC, however, did not activate the
provision, although it had the power to do so. Oil companies continued to pay, on a
dollar per square metre basis, for lease of the land.
In 1997, BAC informed Shell of its intention to impose a new charge for aircraft
refuelling services — a fuel throughput levy of 0.4 cents per litre on all fuels
supplied, distributed or transferred through the combined main/short pipeline at
Brisbane Airport. Shell objected and the dispute was referred to an ‘independent
expert’, in accordance with licence provisions, who subsequently confirmed that
‘BAC had a legal right to charge the levy and the level of 0.4 cents per litre was
reasonable in terms of BAC’s contractual rights’ (ACCC 1998b, pp. 16–17). In
July 1998, BAC introduced the levy.
WAC introduced a fuel throughput levy of 0.5 cents per litre on refuelling
operations at the Perth Airport international terminal from June 1999.
The revenue raised by the BAC and WAC fuel throughput levies, in 1999-00, was
$2.5 million and $727 000 respectively (ACCC 2001b, d). The revenue is in
addition to revenue obtained from the existing lease charges.
Many airports in other countries charge for refuelling services on a volume of fuel
throughput basis, including Amsterdam, Kuala Lumpur, Los Angeles, Manchester
and Aberdeen, and Auckland and Wellington airports in New Zealand. Wellington
The ACCC also took account of the Treasurer’s media release on price monitoring,
which stated:
Price monitoring will allow the ACCC to collect data where the airport operator may
have scope to exercise market power but where coverage of the services under the more
formal price cap arrangements is not considered warranted. Any abuses of market
power detected through the prices monitoring arrangements will be the trigger for
consideration of stricter forms of prices oversight. (Costello 1998)
The ACCC reported to the Treasurer and publicly released its report in
December 1998. It reconfirmed its approach this year, suggesting that refuelling
services be subject to a price cap (sub. 36). Moreover, in its draft decision on
aeronautical pricing at Sydney Airport, the ACCC (2001h) decided that ‘above-
normal’ returns from aeronautical-related services, such as fuel throughput levies
and car parking, should be taken into account in pricing aeronautical services.
Specifically, these returns were to be subtracted from aeronautical revenue to
generate a total allowable revenue from aeronautical services for the airport
(ACCC 2001h). Following a Direction (No. 22) in April 2001 from the Minister for
Financial Services and Regulation, the ACCC (2001i) moved away from this
position in the final decision.
Divergent views
Submissions to the ACCC and, more recently, to this inquiry, have highlighted the
contentious nature of the fuel throughput levy. Airport operators contended, in
essence, that they should be allowed to introduce a fuel throughput levy, and that it
should not be included under price-cap arrangements.
On the other hand, oil companies (including Shell, sub. DR63) argued that the fuel
throughput levy should not have been introduced by BAC and WAC, that its
imposition represents an abuse of market power and cannot be justified, and
therefore that the levy should be subject to stricter prices oversight. The airlines and
the International Air Transport Association (sub. DR56) in general supported this
view.
Several airport operators have introduced airport vehicle access charges for taxis. In
1998, BAC introduced a fee for taxis of $1 per passenger pick-up at Brisbane
Airport. WAC also introduced a fee for taxis in 1998 — $1 per pick-up at Perth
Airport (unbooked) and $2 per pick-up (booked). The following year Capital
Airport Group introduced a taxi charge of $2 at Canberra Airport.1 Taxi charges
were recently introduced at Melbourne Airport — a 66 cent charge per taxi for
1 Northern Territory Airports introduced taxi charges at Darwin and Alice Springs airports in
1998, but removed them the following year.
FUEL THROUGHPUT 395
LEVIES AND TAXI
CHARGES
passenger pick-up (passengers are charged $1, 66 cents of which is revenue to the
airport operator, and 34 cents is a handling commission to the taxi).2
The introduction of these charges has been particularly contentious. The airport
operators argued that taxi charges did not relate to the use of ‘landside roads’ and
were not within the definition of ‘aeronautical services’, and therefore that revenue
derived from taxi charges had not (and should not be) included within the price cap.
Hastings Funds Management (part-owner of several airports) noted:
We have consistently maintained that charges for ground transport are in fact not
charges to access the land-side roads (as would be the case, for example if a toll was
placed on the road), but a concession fee for the right to conduct business by taxi and
bus operators. (sub. 19, p. 14)
The ACCC, on the other hand, considered that revenue derived from taxi charges
was covered under the definition of ‘aeronautical services’ (being included in
‘landside roads’) and therefore was included in the price cap (ACCC 1999e, f;
2000d). The ACCC treated these as ‘new’ charges under Direction No. 20, pursuant
to the PS Act, which stated that ‘charges on new or varied services are to be
factored into the price-cap arrangements if the services are declared services’.
The ACCC therefore requested that BAC, WAC and Capital Airport Group
formally ‘notify’ the ACCC of their proposals to introduce a taxi charge, which they
did, albeit on a ‘without prejudice’ basis. This inclusion has contributed to BAC and
WAC not complying with the price cap; revenue has been ‘over-recovered’ and will
have to be passed back to users within a specified time period.
Canberra Airport instigated an action in the Federal Court against the ACCC in an
attempt to have the ACCC’s decision on taxi charges overturned. In March 2001,
the Federal Court ruled, in a ‘line-ball’ decision, in favour of the ACCC — finding
that the charge was within the price cap because it related to the use of landside
roads. The Court stated:
… it is submitted for the applicant [Canberra Airport] that, on the facts, the area in
question is properly described as a car park or marshalling yard and is simply not an
access way for through traffic.
The primary submission on behalf of the respondent [ACCC], in summary, is that the
area is physically an extension of the main road …
The issue is finely balanced, with each argument capable of acceptance. My mind has
fluctuated as to the correct result. In the end I am persuaded that the area is best seen as
part of the overall road system of the Airport in a way which, for example, car parks are
not. (Federal Court of Australia 2001a, paras 21–3)
2 A $2 per vehicle pre-booked taxi fee applies to passengers departing in a taxi from the
Premium Parking area.
396 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
The Full Federal Court has since dismissed an appeal by Canberra Airport,
concluding that:
In our view, the area is, in its physical aspect, sufficiently connected to the main
thoroughfare, and, in its functional aspect, properly seen as incidental to the purpose
served by that thoroughfare, to warrant itself the description of ‘road’. (Federal Court
of Australia 2001b, para. 16)
Since then, the changes to price regulation in October 2001 (chapter 3) removed
aeronautical services at Canberra Airport from the price cap. Both aeronautical and
aeronautical-related services are now subject to the same price-monitoring
arrangements. Thus, for the time being, this taxi charge issue is not relevant to
Canberra Airport in the context of price regulation.
Melbourne Airport is the only airport operator to seek ACCC consideration of the
taxi charge under necessary new investment (NNI) provisions of the price-cap
arrangements (chapters 3 and 8). However, in so doing, Melbourne Airport (2001)
noted that it considered that the charge should be subject to price monitoring, not
declaration under the price cap, and that because of different circumstances, the
Federal Court decision regarding Canberra Airport would shed little light on the
Melbourne Airport situation.
Melbourne Airport sought approval under NNI provisions to introduce a $1.40 taxi
charge to recover costs associated with development of a taxi facility, including
unrecovered road costs, taxi car-parking development costs and taxi rank labour
costs. The Victorian Taxi Association, representing the taxi industry, disagreed with
the imposition of the charge, commenting that taxi passengers would not receive
any service improvement, that the charge was an unfair tax, and that the timing of
its introduction was poor. The Association also noted that it was concerned about
the imposition of taxi charges in principle — that taxi operators may not be allowed
to pass on charges to passengers without delay, and that charges may affect the
demand for taxi services (sub. to ACCC 2001a). The Transport Workers Union,
representing a smaller but increasing number of taxi drivers, noted that taxi drivers
(content with existing facilities) saw no need to introduce new taxi facilities and
therefore objected to the charge (sub. to ACCC 2001a).
The ACCC considered the proposed taxi charge according to criteria for NNI set out
in the Department of Transport and Regional Development Pricing Policy Paper
(DoTRD 1996) and replicated in Direction No. 20 pursuant to the PS Act
(chapter 3). It found that some of the costs met the criteria and therefore could be
‘passed through’ the price cap — specifically, that 66 cents (GST inclusive) of the
proposed $1.40 charge would not be subject to the price cap (ACCC 2001a).
Following this decision, Melbourne Airport introduced a 66 cent taxi charge, as
noted above.
FUEL THROUGHPUT 397
LEVIES AND TAXI
CHARGES
E.3 Issues arising from price regulation
The debates regarding fuel throughput levies and taxi charges highlight a problem
intrinsic to a dual-till system — that given there must be two baskets of services
(those subject to a price cap, and those not subject) there is likely to be contention,
at least for some services, regarding:
• which services are within the price cap and which are not (illustrated by the taxi
charges debate); and
• which services should be within the price cap and which should not (illustrated
by the fuel throughput levy and taxi charges debates). The fuel throughput levy
debate highlights, at least for some airport operators and some services, that
whether the potential for abuse of market power exists (and is abused) can be a
contentious issue.
Similarly, there may be disagreement regarding whether services not within the
price cap are, or should be, subject to price monitoring or to no price regulation.
The taxi charges debate highlights the importance of clarity and precision in
legislation defining the basket of services to be subject to the price cap. The scope
for different interpretations of particular legislative clauses cannot be eliminated,
but it can be minimised in the drafting process. Moreover, shortcomings in the
legislation can be addressed by appropriate amendment as they arise.
The lack of clarity about what services relate to ‘landside roads’ has created
uncertainty among airport operators and users. As with fuel throughput levies, the
uncertainty has been exacerbated by the length of time that these issues remain
unresolved and the apparent difference between the ACCC interpretation and the
Commonwealth Government’s intent on these issues.
In relation to fuel throughput levies, airport operators claim to have assessed the
risks and made commercial decisions (bidding for airport leases) based, in part, on
their perception of Commonwealth Government policy at the time of sale of leases
— that refuelling services were outside the price cap.
Airport operators were of the view that when they exercised this contractual right,
charges (including fuel throughput levies) for aircraft refuelling services would not
be subject to a price cap. As noted above, when the FAC operated airports, charges
for the provision of refuelling services were not subject to price regulation.
Moreover, airport operators (Melbourne Airport, BAC, WAC; subs 7, 8, 21) added
that representations by the Commonwealth Government to prospective bidders for
the leases of Phase 1 and 2 airports did nothing to dispel their view that fuel
throughput levies could be implemented outside the price cap. Melbourne Airport
commented:
In relation to fuel throughput levies, it is our view that in the information memorandum
to bidders the Commonwealth did represent that that was a source of revenues available
to them that would not be within the cap. (trans., p. 169)
In its submission to the ACCC review of fuel throughput levies, WAC commented:
If the Government did not want WAC, or other bidding groups, to impose such a fee, it
should have made [it] perfectly clear prior to January 1997 … (sub. to ACCC 1998b,
p. 3)
Phase 1 airport bidders may not have been clear about the implications of the formal
monitoring process. Although the Department of Transport and Regional
Development Pricing Policy Paper (DoTRD 1996), distributed to prospective
bidders for Phase 1 airports, noted that there would be monitoring of selected
aeronautical-related services, it did not specify the services and did not make
mention of the power of the ACCC to recommend that particular aeronautical-
related services be transferred to within the price cap. It was not until June 1997,
after finalisation of the bids, that the Treasurer publicly announced that there was
the potential for stricter prices oversight (Costello 1997).
In summary, with respect to these two charges, considerable uncertainty has ensued.
This seems to stem from differences in interpretation, a lack of clarity, precision and
transparency regarding the policies at, and since, the sale of leases, and time delays
in formal Commonwealth Government statements. Moreover, changes in
Government policy that may conflict with Government commitments at the time of
sale could raise issues of sovereign risk for parties that perceive themselves as
adversely affected.
This appendix considers some issues that arise in the valuation of airport land for
the purposes of regulation of aeronautical prices. It begins with an in-principle
discussion of land valuation and the importance of the concept of opportunity cost.
Some practical issues associated with land valuation are then considered, drawing
on the issues raised in the recent ACCC (2001i) review of aeronautical prices at
Sydney Airport. The intention is not to recommend or suggest a detailed valuation
methodology, which would be beyond the scope of this inquiry, but rather to
explore the broad principles that can guide the valuation of aeronautical land.
Aeronautical services, particularly for large aircraft in large cities, are land
intensive. Runways need to be several kilometres in length and substantial buffer
zones between the airport and surrounding activities (particularly residential areas)
are desirable. In addition, most airline passengers value proximity to city centres,
and airports often are situated on land that would be valued highly for other uses. At
June 1997, the Federal Airports Corporation (FAC 1997) valued total land in its
airport network at around 30 per cent of its total (including non-aeronautical) fixed
assets.1
Because of its significance in the aeronautical asset base, the valuation of land can
have a major effect on the aeronautical prices that a regulator may consider justified
on the basis of recovering airport costs. In general, this has not been an issue to date
for the privatised core-regulated airports because their (average) aeronautical
charges have been determined by adjustments to FAC starting prices under price
caps, including related new investment cost pass-throughs.2 However, Sydney
Airport is not subject to a price cap; and the ACCC examined Sydney Airports
1 This was the last year in which the FAC operated all of the capital city airports. The FAC
valued land on the basis of market value for alternative use (capped at light industrial) at 30
June 1996. Other fixed assets were valued at written-down replacement cost at 30 June 1996
plus asset additions and less asset sales and depreciation during 1996-97.
2 Where new aeronautical investment has involved use of land previously used for non-
aeronautical purposes, regulatory assessment of the allowable price increase has included a
return on that land.
VALUATION OF 401
AERONAUTICAL
LAND
Corporation Limited’s (SACL) September 2000 proposal for aeronautical price
increases using a cost building block approach.
Although Sydney Airport is smaller in land area than most other major Australian
airports, it is situated close to the Sydney CBD and hence the market value of its
land is very high. SACL’s (2000) valuation of aeronautical land averaged $115 per
square metre and represents nearly 42 per cent of the aeronautical asset base.3
Participants in the ACCC’s examination of SACL’s price increase proposal
presented a variety of options for valuing land for the purpose of price regulation.
These provided a very wide range of land values and, by implication, significant
variations in cost-based aeronautical prices.
In considering Sydney Airport land values, the ACCC (2001i) drew attention to its
earlier views (ACCC 1999c) on asset valuation in general:
In determining an appropriate asset valuation methodology economic principles and
analysis do not provide an unambiguous decision rule for the valuation of sunk assets.
Rather economic principles provide lower and upper bounds — scrap value and
replacement cost. Within these bounds there is opportunity for regulatory judgement.
(ACCC 2001i, p. 132)
The scope for such ‘regulatory judgement’ appears particularly pronounced with
regard to Sydney Airport land. The ACCC reduced SACL’s proposed value for
aeronautical land of $705 million by over one-third to $452 million. In itself, this
lower land value leads to average aeronautical prices being about 8 per cent lower
than otherwise.4 Using the zero land value (for existing land) suggested by the
Board of Airline Representatives of Australia (BARA 2000), and applying the
ACCC’s assessment of SACL’s cost of capital, would have led to prices about
20 per cent lower than SACL’s request.
This wide variation in the valuation of land contrasts with other important elements
of Sydney Airport’s cost structure about which there was more agreement and in
which the ACCC, in reaching its pricing decision, varied much less from SACL’s
proposal. The ACCC accepted, for example, SACL’s valuations of other assets
3 SACL estimated the opportunity cost of land by considering the price that a developer would
pay for a similar land parcel in a similar location (after allowing for development and holding
costs). It then added the land-related costs (for example, holding costs) of developing the site
into an airport over five years. This is a ‘new entry cost’ concept for valuing land.
4 In conjunction with its proposal to include land at market values, SACL also included a
deduction of $14.7 million from allowable aeronautical revenue to allow for the forecast annual
real capital gain on land. However, because the ACCC preferred to use indexed historical cost
land values it did not take account of SACL’s proposed deduction when determining allowable
prices.
402 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
(although it reduced allowable depreciation by nearly 25 per cent) and it reduced
allowable operating and maintenance expenditure by 10 per cent.
The opportunity cost concept is the appropriate approach to land valuation from an
economic efficiency perspective. It assists the government (and private investors in
airports) in making decisions on the efficient location of the airport by signalling to
users the land use costs of their air travel decisions — their willingness to pay
indicating that they value the current airport site more than its next best use. Any
move away from opportunity cost pricing will obscure these signals. Opportunity
cost also provides the correct incentives to the airport operator regarding use of
airport land.
The New Zealand Commerce Commission (CC), in its draft report on price control
for major NZ airports, argued in favour of opportunity cost as the appropriate value
of land for price regulation purposes, although it excluded land held for future
airport development:
Valuing airfield land at opportunity cost provides appropriate signals to either continue
operating the land in its existing use (as an airfield) or to put the land to alternative use
and relocate the airport. It also provides the appropriate incentives for new investment.
Opportunity cost should be determined based on the highest alternative use value of
airfield land. (CC 2001b, p. xxvi)
The ACCC, in its response to the Productivity Commission’s draft report, noted that
the Productivity Commission:
… argues that land at Sydney Airport should be valued at opportunity cost. The
Commission [ACCC] agrees with this principle. (sub. DR55, p. 18)
The important questions are: what is the appropriate concept of opportunity cost?
And how can it be estimated in practice? Section F.1 provides an in-principle
discussion of aeronautical land valuation issues, focusing on the importance of land
valuation for:
• determining the appropriate location for an airport; and
• deciding how to use land within the airport precinct.
VALUATION OF 403
AERONAUTICAL
LAND
Section F.2 then considers the third role of land valuation the setting of regulated
prices. This issue is explored by drawing on the recent ACCC decision in relation to
Sydney Airport.
Figure F.1 presents a very simplified picture of the demand for airport services and
the costs of providing them. For simplicity all airport services are bundled together
(including leases for retailing and so on) and the supply and demand for the package
is related to aircraft movements. Demand is aggregated so there are no differences
in demand at different times of day or year.
Figure F.1 Market for airport services: different valuations of airport land
AC1
Pc
AC3 AC2 D
P1
P2
P3
O A
Aircraft movements
The average cost curves (AC1, AC2 and AC3) are drawn for different valuations of
land. For AC1, it is assumed that the average costs incorporate the highest
The difference between Pc and P1, P2, and P3 respectively, multiplied by the quantity
OA, shows the ‘economic rent’ that could accrue to someone other than the airport
if prices were constrained to P1, P2 or P3 (some of the rent may be dissipated by
queuing). It is only the price Pc that shows the value of the airport to the operator or
potential purchaser, in its present site; it is this value that provides an appropriate
signal as to whether to sell and move elsewhere, and to a government in evaluating
the effects of regulation.6
5 The position of the average cost curves is for illustrative purposes. For example, it is also
possible that AC2 may be higher than AC1 if proximity to the airport increases the value of
neighbouring land relative to its value in an alternative use.
6 It should be noted that environmental considerations are not taken into account here — they are
a necessary factor to be addressed in making any decision regarding moving etc in practice.
VALUATION OF 405
AERONAUTICAL
LAND
price P1 than P2 or P3. Also, the rents accruing to those other than the airport
operator (or government) are smaller with P1 than P2 or P3.7
The analysis is made a little more complicated if the airport were capacity
constrained only at certain times of the day. A more detailed discussion of capacity-
constrained pricing issues is contained in appendix H.
Now consider the appropriate land valuations to guide the use of the fixed amount
of airport land by the airport operator. Initially, the assumption is made that land (at
the margin) can be allocated between different uses. Allowed pricing freedom, the
operator would allocate land among various activities so they yielded the same
(marginal) return on each. This would be equal to the price Pc if the output is
constrained.8 For those services that could be provided on or off the airport, only
those that yield a benefit of Pc or more would be supplied on the airport. If the price
is constrained below Pc then the operator would no longer have to be so selective in
choosing what was located on-site. As noted earlier, constraining prices to below Pc
may mean that some users who value airport services below Pc may obtain the
services while those who value them higher than Pc may be excluded. So it may be
that some services that are valued (at the margin) below Pc are provided on-site,
instead of those that are valued at Pc or more. This potentially inefficient use of the
airport site would be aggravated the lower is the regulated price.
If the regulated price were to be such that a single till ‘taxed’ away from the
operator all profits from some airport activities to reduce the price of others, the
operator would have no incentive to allocate airport land efficiently and would have
an incentive to move off-site all activities on which a higher return was possible. (If
the constrained return were below P2, then there would be an incentive to sell some
airport land if that were possible.)
If a dual till were to be applied, regulating prices on some activities but not others,
then an efficient allocation of land between the two types of activity could be
obtained only if the costs allowed in determining the regulated prices incorporated
the full opportunity cost of the land. That opportunity cost would be the return
available on land from producing unregulated services.
7 Note that this is not implying that land values should be inflated or manipulated in order to
achieve prices sufficient to ration demand to the constrained supply. Land should be valued at
its opportunity cost and this value used for regulatory purposes.
8 Assume that the constraint is due to the availability of land at the airport.
406 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
Now assume that there are constraints on allocating land at the margin between
uses. In particular, assume that there are two types of land — airside and landside
— and that the constraint on aircraft movements means there is no point in moving
landside land into airside use. (It is also assumed that there is no incentive to
convert airside land into landside land.) The relevant opportunity cost of land for
landside activities as a whole would be the actual cost of land off the airport site. If
the services provided on landside land are free to locate either within the airport
boundary or outside, then over time the price of landside land within the airport and
surrounding land would be expected to converge. In the long run, the value of
surrounding land would therefore indicate the lower bound on the valuation of
landside land within the airport.
However, if there were locational advantages from being on the airport site (or on
parts of it) then the locational rent should be added to the off-site value in
considering the relevant opportunity cost for allocating any particular land between
alternative on-site uses.
A key issue was whether Sydney Airport would continue to operate as an airport
and the impact of this on the opportunity cost of land. The Government has
announced that it considers that Sydney Airport will be able to handle Sydney’s air
traffic growth until 2010, with a review of Sydney’s airport needs to be conducted
in 2005 (Anderson 2000). Even when a second airport is built, it is likely that
Kingsford Smith will be retained because of its locational advantage.
BARA (2000) argued, in view of this, that the appropriate opportunity cost
valuation of Sydney Airport land is zero because there were no other uses to which
it would be put. BARA considered that any purchases of new land should be valued
at its purchase price to provide appropriate incentives for SACL in making marginal
additions to land. Network Economics Consulting Group (NECG 2000b), in a report
to the ACCC, also contended that if there is no likelihood of Sydney Airport being
closed then there is no opportunity cost associated with SACL land.
VALUATION OF 407
AERONAUTICAL
LAND
Pitchford (2000) argued that if the use of the current site as an airport is considered
mandated by the Government, then the land’s sale value is not relevant for assessing
required regulatory return. He considered that for existing land, a (non-zero) value
derived from users’ valuations of airport services is appropriate.
It should be recognised that while such regulatory considerations may limit the
airport owner’s options in relation to sale of the land, they do not alter the
opportunity cost to the economy of the land itself. The opportunity cost remains the
value of the land to society in its next best available use (adjusted for any costs
needed to prepare it for that use, such as the cost of demolition of existing
facilities).
Another issue that has been raised relates to the costs and benefits of moving
Sydney Airport and how these affect the valuation of land for regulatory purposes.
The ACCC (2001i; sub. DR55) argued that, in deciding to move Sydney Airport,
the Commonwealth Government would need to take into account:
… a wide range of issues. These could include the costs of relocating the airport, the
costs of providing infrastructure to service the new airport as well as less tangible
considerations such as the costs and benefits of relocation on airport noise and travel
times. Since a complete assessment of such matters is complex, and the magnitude of
the components of the calculation is likely to change over time, the merits of using a
full opportunity cost valuation should be weighed carefully against alternative
approaches and is considered beyond the scope of this decision. (ACCC 2001i, p. 138)
The Civil Aviation Authority (CAA) considered a similar issue in its review of price
caps at major UK airports. It concluded that:
A full analysis of the demand and costs of airports would need to take into account the
wider externalities created by airport activities. The most direct of these are
environmental externalities, particularly noise, road congestion and emissions … The
CAA believes that it is important that these costs and benefits be properly taken into
account in decisions to expand capacity. However, taking direct account of these
externalities is not one of the CAA’s statutory objectives as an economic regulator of
airports. This is the role of the planning system. (CAA 2001c, p. xiii)
It would be appropriate that the Government take account of all costs and benefits
(both private and social) if it were considering relocating Sydney Airport. However,
the opportunity cost of land at Sydney Airport remains its value in its next best use.
The opportunity cost valuation should be used in regulatory pricing decisions
because prices based on any another valuation will mean that signals regarding
408 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
consumers’ willingness to cover the efficient cost of using the airport will be
distorted.
The ACCC (2001i) considered that because the Mascot site was likely to continue
as an airport or would need to be replaced by another airport, it was not appropriate
to adopt SACL’s proposal to use an estimate of its market value as an opportunity
cost measure of aeronautical land value in developing cost-based prices. It also
argued that prices based on market value of the whole aeronautical section of the
site were not necessary to ensure efficient use of airport land by SACL. Instead, the
ACCC valued aeronautical land by indexing the original cost of each of the land
purchases that had gone into making up the current aeronautical land by CPI
increases since their purchase. Hence the real value (at least in terms of the various
CPI baskets over the years) of the land was maintained. New land purchases were to
be included in the asset base at their purchase price, and then indexed by the CPI.
The ACCC also argued that there were complexities in estimating the opportunity
cost of Sydney Airport’s aeronautical land. These included whether purchase or sale
of the land (with associated development or clean-up costs respectively) was
relevant and the consideration of externalities (costs and benefits) of relocating to a
new site (discussed above). Hence it concluded:
… the Commission [ACCC] is not persuaded that SACL’s proposal can be considered
a measure of the true opportunity cost of land at Sydney Airport. It also concludes that
such an assessment would be highly complex and well beyond the scope of this
decision. (ACCC 2001i, p. 141)
Dr Gannon argued that there are practical difficulties with measuring the
opportunity cost of land and therefore alternative valuation methodologies, such as
indexed historical cost, may have to be used. However, he noted:
These are poor surrogates as they are unlikely to bear a reliable relationship to the
underlying opportunity cost. For example, an indexed historical cost basis (as resorted
to by the ACCC …) may have some properties that allow it to serve as a reasonable
substitute. But it could result in a valuation that is higher or lower than the real
opportunity cost. (sub. DR55, attachment B, pp. 1–2)
The ACCC did not justify using indexed historical cost as an opportunity cost
concept, but argued instead that the investment and land use signals that such
historical cost pricing provided to SACL would not be inappropriate for efficient
decision making. However, it recognised that valuing aeronautical land at current
market value would meet this criterion.
VALUATION OF 409
AERONAUTICAL
LAND
The ACCC argued that the relative simplicity of the indexed historic cost approach
was a factor in its adoption, because of:
… the difficulty of tying down an opportunity cost valuation. Given the limited time
available to it in making its decision, the Commission [ACCC] considered the
alternative of a historic cost based measure. One advantage of this approach is data
availability. (sub. DR55, pp. 18–19)
However, assumptions must be made regarding the data used in the calculation —
most notably, regarding the price index used. The ACCC used the CPI to inflate the
value of past land purchases. But changes in the general level of prices need bear no
relation to changes in the opportunity cost of land at Sydney (or any other) airport.
Prices based on the ACCC historical cost valuation do not provide signals to the
Government regarding the value that aeronautical users place on the facility
compared with its alternative use. The willingness of consumers to pay prices set on
the basis of the opportunity cost of using Sydney Airport land (measured by the full
market value) would assist the Government in deciding whether an airport is the
best use of the land.
Increases in airport charges to reflect the value placed on using the airport would
increase the sale value of Sydney Airport — a benefit that would accrue to the
Government and the community at large. Lower charges, and a sale price based on
these, imply that rents accrue to parties other than the owner or operator of the
airport. Some of these rents currently support the reservation of slots (and low
charges) for regional airlines. Some accrue to major airlines (and their shareholders)
and are reflected in the high yields obtainable on peak-hour flights into and out of
Sydney. In part, these high yields may support flights between other destinations on
which yields may cover marginal, but not average, costs.
1 BAA was privatised under the Airports Act 1986 and 500 million shares were sold on the
London Stock Exchange in July 1987.
INTERNATIONAL 411
EXPERIENCES
Economic regulation of airports
There are two levels of economic regulation of airports in the United Kingdom. For
a small number of ‘designated’ airports that are considered to have significant
market power, economic regulation consists of a Retail Price Index (RPI)-X price
cap. The second level comprises a system of light-handed regulation for airports
that achieve a pre-determined revenue threshold.
Light-handed regulation
A key component of the system is public disclosure of airport charges and accounts.
All airports holding CAA permission must provide the CAA with their annual
statutory accounts, schedules of airport charges and changes (if any) to the
information provided in their original application. Airports do not need to seek
2 However, unlike other UK regulators, the CAA has been given no specific duty to promote, or
even to facilitate, competition (Cotterill 1999).
3 Airports currently excluded from regulation under the Airports Act (or the Airports (Northern
Ireland) Order) are those in the Isle of Man and Channel Islands, those owned or managed by
the CAA or a CAA subsidiary and those managed by the Government. An airport becomes
subject to economic regulation by the CAA nine months from the end of the financial year in
which it first meets the turnover qualification. Should the annual turnover at a regulated airport
fall below £1 million for two years, the Secretary of State may determine that the airport shall
cease to be regulated.
412 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
CAA approval before they revise their airport charges but must notify the CAA of
the charges before they take effect.
First, restrictions can result from complaints brought against an airport operator by
airport users and others (including other airports) for pursuing a course of conduct
specified in the Airports Act. In broad terms, complaints may be brought against an
airport that:
• unreasonably discriminates against any class of users (or a particular user) of the
airport; or
• unfairly exploits its bargaining position relative to users generally; or
• levies charges that are both unduly low and cause damage, or are designed to
cause damage, to another airport (CAA 2000b).
If the CAA considers that there is a case to answer, it will investigate and, where
necessary, recommend actions or impose ‘conditions’ on the airport to rectify the
situation.
Second, there is the threat that an airport may become designated by the Minister of
State under s. 40 of the Airports Act and, consequently, be subject to price-cap
regulation. While there are no formal criteria for designation in the Airports Act, the
Government has stated that it considers the relevant criteria are:
• the market position of the airport, including the degree of competition from other
airports and other modes;
• prima facie evidence of excessive profitability or abuse of a monopoly position;
• the scale and timing of investment, and the implications for profitability; and
• the efficiency and quality of service (CAA 2000a).
As noted above, under the Airports Act, there are provisions for airports to be
designated and become subject to more restrictive regulation than those airports
holding CAA permission. Current designated airports in the United Kingdom are
Heathrow, Gatwick and Stansted in London, and the major international airport in
the north of England, Manchester.
INTERNATIONAL 413
EXPERIENCES
requires designated airports to reveal, among other things, the revenue and costs
from three classifications of their activities: airport activities, other airport-related
activities and non-airport activities (CAA 2000b).
The principal feature of economic regulation of designated airports is the price cap.
In practice, economic regulation of designated airports is a hybrid model of price-
cap and rate-of-return regulation. The price cap, which is similar to the price caps
commonly applied to other regulated industries in the United Kingdom, comprises a
RPI-X price cap applied in the form of an average revenue yield per passenger
(Cotterill 1999). Airport charges subject to the price cap are those associated with
the landing, take-off, and parking of aircraft, and with the processing of passengers
through the terminals. As individual charges are not subject to the price cap, the
airport operator has a degree of discretion with respect to the level of each
individual charge and the relationship between them (Starkie 2001c).4
Application of the RPI-X price cap at designated airports differs from other UK-
regulated industries subject to a price cap in that, when resetting the price cap, the
CAA adopts a single-till approach. Under the single till, future revenues and costs
are assessed on an airport-wide basis to determine allowable average revenue yield
per passenger. That is, the regulator takes into account not only the revenue
generated from aeronautical services, but also the revenue generated by activities
such as retailing, and the provision of rental property and other services to tenants
and licensees (box G.1).
The price-cap approach to the regulation of designated airports has been in place
since 1987. The cap is reset every five years by the CAA, in conjunction with the
Competition Commission,5 after an extensive review process. Every quinquennial
review begins with a reference to the Competition Council, which is given six
months to report its analysis and recommendations concerning the price cap, and
any conclusions as to whether the airport company has acted against the public
interest. The Competition Council’s recommendations are then made available to
the public by the CAA for consultation and comment. Finally, the CAA announces
its findings on the price cap, and also indicates how it intends to implement any
public interest findings.
4 At BAA plc’s designated airports, a single revenue yield price cap applies to Heathrow and
Gatwick airports and a separate cap applies to Stansted (subject to the constraint that the charge
differential between Heathrow and Gatwick is required to increase by at least one percentage
point per year) (CAA 2001b). The allowable rate of return for BAA plc implicit in the price-cap
calculations for the period 1997–2002 was 7.5 per cent.
5 Formerly the Monopolies and Mergers Commission.
414 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
Box G.1 UK approach to single-till price-cap regulation
The Civil Aviation Authority and the Competition Council undertake a review process to
reset the Retail Price Index-X price cap at designated airports every five years
(although this process is currently under review). The price-cap model used is similar
to price caps applied in other UK regulated industries, except that a single-till approach
is used to calculate the revenues the airport may earn from the provision of
aeronautical services.
The procedure for calculating the price cap at designated airports under the single till
comprises four main steps.
1. An agreed program of capital expenditure for the airport is determined. In addition,
based on consultation between the regulators, the airports, airport users and other
interested parties, the regulator determines, for the coming five-year period,
estimates of:
– traffic and passenger numbers;
– operational expenditure; and
– commercial revenues (revenues from non-aeronautical services).
2. The value of the airport’s asset base is derived, and an allowable risk-adjusted rate
of return is determined by the regulator.
3. The overall revenue required by the airport to achieve the approved rate of return is
then estimated. The estimated commercial revenues are then subtracted from the
overall revenue requirement to obtain the residual revenue requirement.
4. The residual revenue requirement is what airports may earn from charges from the
provision of aeronautical services under the price cap. The Xs, which are set by the
regulator, are estimated to allow the airport to recover the residual revenue
requirement.
Source: Kunz (2001).
There is no explicit access regime for airports in the United Kingdom. There are
general provisions for determinations to be made on access to ‘essential’ facilities
on a case-by-case basis under UK and European law (ACCC, sub. 36; PC 2001a).
As noted previously, price regulation at designated airports has differed from other
UK industries subject to a price cap in the application of a single till. The single-till
approach to airport regulation in the United Kingdom stemmed from international
INTERNATIONAL 415
EXPERIENCES
treaty obligations6 and concerns over equity and distribution. Cotterill noted that
distributional concerns have continued to be used as an argument to support the use
of the single till:
… [the Monopolies and Mergers Commission in the 1997 quinquennial reviews]
pointed for example to the large windfall profits which removal of the single till would
mean for the airport companies at the expense of the airlines and the universally
adverse reaction of the airlines to such a change. (Cotterill 1999, p. 4)
However, as reflected in the CAA findings in the current review (see below), it
appears that the objectives of the regulation (outlined earlier) are not being met. As
discussed below, significant concerns have been raised that the regulatory system is
proving to be an impediment to the efficient pricing of current airport facilities, and
that it is not providing the appropriate incentives to encourage investment in major
airport infrastructure, such as runways and terminals. Other issues raised in relation
to the regulatory system include the potential for gaming to occur, and the high
compliance costs of the system.
6 Until 1991, the UK Government was committed to applying the single-till principle under the
terms of the Bermuda II Air Agreement with the United States, although this is no longer the
case (Starkie and Yarrow 2000).
416 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
invest efficiently. Airport operators potentially can game the system, for
example, by inflating recorded and projected costs in order to obtain a ‘looser’
price cap, or by putting forward investment proposals that are ‘gold plated’ or
are not demanded by users (CAA 2000g; Kunz 2001).7 The CAA also noted the
possibility of gaming by airport users (CAA 2001c).
The CAA, as part of its current quinquennial review of price caps at designated
airports, is undertaking a fundamental review of its approach to the economic
regulation of airports within the existing framework of the Airports Act (the review
is to determine how the price caps should be set for the period 2003–08 and
beyond). The review is broad ranging in scope, and has arisen out of concerns that
the current regulatory framework is not best suited to address a number of issues
that have emerged or intensified in recent years. These include:
• that demand for access to Heathrow and Gatwick airports exceeds available
capacity;
• in the absence of an efficient market for take-off and landing slots, utilisation of
existing capacity may not be optimal;
• whether incentives for the promotion of appropriate investment in capacity are
efficient;
• the importance of unregulated revenue in setting charges; and
7 The CAA, as part of its current review of the price-cap regulation, is examining a number of
options that might result in a lessening of the potential to game. These include the use of
benchmarking (CAA 2000g) and a ‘default’ price cap (CAA 2001a).
INTERNATIONAL 417
EXPERIENCES
• the importance of service quality for customers and consumers, and the wide
variation in quality that different users may require (CAA 2000c).
The CAA (2001c) released its preliminary conclusions in November 2001. After
examining several options for setting price caps, it recommended substantial
changes to the way the caps are applied. In particular, it recommended a move to
dual-till price caps for all four designated airports. The single-till approach was seen
as being particularly unsuitable at the capacity-constrained Heathrow and Gatwick
airports because:
• under conditions of excess demand, the single till was an inefficient way of
allocating scarce capacity; and
• it did not provide airports with good incentives to invest optimally.
The CAA noted that the argument against the single till was not as strong at
Stansted and Manchester airports (which currently are not congested). For a number
of reasons, however, the CAA recommended that the single till should not be
applied at either airport.
• Stansted currently faces competition from Luton Airport, so it is not clear that it
has monopoly power. Thus:
… the case for retaining the single till at Stansted is a trade-off between a minimal or
non-existent gain in restraining prices with the costs and distortions that persisting with
a wider regulatory framework, that was only marginally binding, would generate.
(CAA 2001c, p. xvii)
• On the other hand, the CAA was not convinced that Manchester Airport
operated in a competitive environment. It also concluded, however, that although
Manchester has a significant local monopoly it faces more competition than
Heathrow and Gatwick. That Manchester ‘had not sought to expand passenger
numbers through low cost carriers’ (CAA 2001c, p. 122) was cited as one
indicator of the lack of competition it faces. Given this:
… the loss in efficiency from moving to a RRCB [Revised Regulatory Cost Base] price
cap may be higher [than at Stansted], but a demonstrated ability to price differentiate
and its local government ownership should ensure that any loss in output from a move
to a RRCB would still be low. The CAA believes that the distortions caused by
regulating the commercial business by retaining the single till would outweigh this loss.
(CAA 2001c, p. xvii)
- The CAA also was concerned about the potential impact of applying the
single till at Manchester on inter-airport competition:
… Manchester is in a situation where it is subject to increasing, albeit fringe,
competition and so tight price cap regulation runs the risk of the most undesirable
distortion of all: that low prices set by the dominant firm under regulation may
hinder the growth and development of a more competitive airport market.
Moreover, the CAA did not accept that airlines had any intrinsic rights over the
commercial revenues generated at airports.
On balance, the CAA found that the existing single-till framework ‘is unlikely to be
the best basis for meeting its statutory objectives given the challenges now faced
over the next five years and beyond’ (CAA 2001c, p. xviii).
The CAA recommended as the appropriate basis of the price cap the Revised
Regulatory Cost Base (RRCB) at all four designated airports. The RRCB includes
only those aeronautical activities in which the airport operator has clear monopoly
power. The CAA identified three main reasons for modification of the price-cap
framework to the RRCB.
• It would reduce the scope of regulation to core aeronautical activities ‘where the
airport has a clear monopoly in relation to its users’ (CAA 2001c, p. xviii).
• It would generally result in prices that better reflect market conditions at
Heathrow and Gatwick airports, though prices would remain ‘well below’
market clearing levels.
• Profitability of investment in increasing capacity would be increased, ‘resulting
in a greater likelihood of more investment in aeronautical infrastructure than
under a single till’ (CAA 2001c, p. xviii).
Other options for setting the cap that were examined by the CAA included:
incremental costs, value-based incentives, and contracting between the airport and
users.
• The CAA considered that there would be significant benefits — in terms of
incentives for both investing in appropriate capacity and cost-effectiveness — if
a long-term price path could be set in terms of forward-looking incremental
costs.
- It noted, however, that setting caps on this basis is not straightforward, with
risks of both under- and over-estimating costs.
- At capacity-congested airports (Heathrow and Gatwick), prices would be well
above RRCB levels, but would result in improved resource use in the
medium term.
• Prices incorporating a premium over costs (value-based incentives) may be
appropriate where there is excess demand and ‘the value of additional outputs to
users may … be much higher than the costs to the airport of delivering those
outputs’ (CAA 2001c, p. xxi).
INTERNATIONAL 419
EXPERIENCES
• Given that real prices could rise with the new price cap, there would be
opportunities for greater contracting within the cap set. The CAA noted that it:
… would expect the airports to use this greater latitude pro-actively and responsibly to
deliver material benefits in terms of improved investment in service quality and
capacity, to engender a greater consensus with its users on the strategic direction being
taken and to pursue the objectives desired. (CAA 2001c, p. xxi)
As well as examining options for the setting of the price cap, the CAA identified a
number of other areas where the regulatory framework required improvement,
including in relation to service quality, the default price cap, information disclosure
and pricing structures.
• The CAA noted that users had expressed concerns about the treatment of service
quality. It added, however, that ‘specifying and fixing quality standards carries
major risks of perverse outcomes, would result in a very detailed oversight of
airport operations by the regulator, and would be likely to reduce the
accountability of the airports’ (CAA 2001c, p. xxii).
• It noted that the default price cap would give protection to users while allowing
and encouraging contracting between the airport and users. This would allow
services and prices to be tailored to user needs. Where the price cap would be
binding, it argued that:
… explicit provision should be made in the price cap condition for direct contracts for
different levels of service quality, and for specific facilities that would not be counted
as airport user charge revenues for the purpose of meeting the price cap limits. The
CAA recognises that its provisions will require some degree of regulatory oversight, in
order to ensure that direct contracts do not have a serious detrimental impact on those
users that remain on the default price cap. (CAA 2001c, p. xxiii)
• The CAA found that none of the designated airports provides sufficient
information to help users assess project proposals. It argued that airports should
provide further information to users, including demand, capacity and cost
projections, service quality, investment plans and resourcing implications. It
commented, however, that the CAA ‘does not have, and could never have, the
information to take ownership of the airports’ investment plans, and to attempt
to do so would compromise the management and accountability of the airport
and its users in delivering services to passengers’ (CAA 2001c, p. xxiv).
• The CAA argued that there was considerable scope for improving the use of
airport capacity through price differentiation. This could be done through the
default price cap, but also through a move to a tariff basket approach. It also
The major thrust of the CAA’s preliminary recommendations is to create the right
incentives for future investment so as to alleviate the capacity constraints at
Heathrow and Gatwick airports, as well as ensuring that similar situations do not
arise at the other two designated airports. The CAA also considered that the
package contained initiatives to place stronger pressure on the airports to improve
their service quality, to move to greater direct contracting, and to improve
consultation on airport development.
Gatwick also would move to an RRCB pricing framework, but with no separate
returns for additional output. A ‘simple’ RRCB would apply at Stansted and
Manchester.
INTERNATIONAL 421
EXPERIENCES
• moving regulation of Stansted Airport to a stand-alone basis, and the ending of
any cross-subsidy of Stansted’s asset base from charges at Heathrow and
Gatwick airports; and
• setting separate price caps at Heathrow and Gatwick airports.
The CAA envisaged that the new prices would be phased in over the five years,
rather than being introduced at the start of the period:
This will give users in particular time to adjust to the new system, and encourage
airports to facilitate a move to greater accommodation … within it. (CAA 2001c,
p. xxix)
It acknowledged that adopting the RRCB approach would be likely to result in price
caps that generally are higher than single-till prices, and a transfer of economic
rents to airport operators. With regard to Heathrow and Gatwick, however, it noted
that:
These higher prices [for aeronautical services] are justified on the basis of increasing
the prospect that available capacity is utilised as well as possible given the serious
levels of unsatisfied demand at these airports at current prices. (CAA 2001c, p. xxix)
The CAA’s final report and recommendations are due to be released by the end of
February 2002, with the final decision on the price caps to be delivered by end-
November 2002.
New Zealand has adopted what has been referred to as a ‘light-handed’ approach,
with major airports not subject to any direct economic regulation. Although there
are examples internationally of government-owned major airports not subject to
direct regulation, indirect economic regulation of privatised airports is more
unusual.
The NZ approach to economic regulation of airports is in line with the approach the
Government adopted with former state-owned industries in the 1990s. In general,
this approach focused on:
• requiring the disclosure of prices, terms and conditions for contractual
arrangements, costs, performance measures, and financial performance
indicators;
• the use of the Commerce Act 1986 to control anti-competitive behaviour; and
• threats of further regulation, such as price control if market dominance is abused,
but perhaps in a different form than was previously employed in New Zealand
(PSA 1995).
Airport companies, like other companies in New Zealand, are subject to the general
competition law provisions under the Commerce Act. Several sections of the
Commerce Act are relevant to the regulation of airports, in particular Part IV, which
enables the Governor-General, on the recommendation of the Minister of
Commerce, to impose price controls in circumstances of restricted competition.9
9 Other sections of relevance include: Part II, which covers restrictive trade practices, and also
contains provisions relating to resale price maintenance and market dominance; and Part III,
which prevents acquisitions that would result in a dominant position or a strengthening of such
a position.
INTERNATIONAL 423
EXPERIENCES
Privatised airports and light-handed regulation
As discussed in chapter 11, there has been considerable debate about the
effectiveness of the NZ system. The ability of the system to limit the abuse of any
market power held by airports has been questioned and the costs of using the
system, both to airports and airport users, allegedly have been high. The regulatory
system appears to have been characterised by a high degree of uncertainty, both in
terms of its implementation and how it may evolve over time. It also appears that
this uncertainty might have contributed to the high costs of using the system.
Since 1989, there have been three reviews of the regulatory system. As the current
review commenced at around the same time as the privatisation of Auckland and
Wellington airports in 1998, there has been potential for strategic behaviour by both
airports and airport users alike in an attempt to influence the outcome of the review.
The regulatory system has resulted in a high incidence of litigation between airlines
and airport operators and (in some instances) the Government, in part over
interpretation of key elements of the legislative framework. The most well-
documented of these was a case instigated by Air New Zealand and a number of
Litigation between airports and airlines has also been cited as evidence of the lack
of countervailing power of airlines. Under the regulatory system, it has been argued,
airlines faced with increased airport charges have had to resort to litigation
(PSA 1995). However, the regulatory regime may have promoted the use of
litigation. It is also possible that airlines have been exercising countervailing power
by initiating or threatening expensive litigation.
10 These were Qantas, Bilmans Management Limited (Ansett) and the Board of Airlines
Representatives of New Zealand.
INTERNATIONAL 425
EXPERIENCES
with applicable instruments is at hand, the threat of regulation is not credible at all.
(Kunz 1999, p. 39)
The PSA also noted that the disinclination of the NZ Government to introduce price
regulation generally reduced the threat of any such regulation being applied to the
airports sector:
… both the Government and the Commerce Commission [in 1995] have made clear
their reluctance to implement or recommend price control, thereby undermining the
threat of its use. (PSA 1995, p. 11)
However, the CC’s current review of the need for price regulation at New Zealand’s
international airports might have made the threat of price regulation more credible.
Forsyth noted the threat of price controls, combined with the current review, ‘would
be a deterrent to [airport operators] using market power and setting high charges’
(2001, p. 12).
Although the scope of the review is limited to airfield activities, the terms of
reference require the CC to consider the impact of other airport activities.
‘However, in reporting to the Minister, the [CC] … intends to confine its
recommendations to airfield activities’ (CC 2001a, para. 33).
11 The Airport Authorities Amendment Act 1997 defines airfield activities as one of three
identified airport activities, the others being: aircraft and freight activities; and specified
passenger terminal activities. Airfield activities cover facilities and services that enable the
landing and take-off of aircraft, including: the provision of airfields, runways, taxiways, and
parking aprons; facilities and services for air traffic and parking control; airfield lighting; and
services to maintain and repair airfields, runways, taxiways, and parking aprons for aircraft
(CC 2001a).
426 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
The CC (2001b) released its draft report in July 2001. The preliminary
recommendation is for price controls to be introduced at Auckland Airport only. In
addressing the terms of reference for the review, the CC found there is evidence
that:
• airfield activities … are supplied or acquired in a market in which competition is
limited or is likely to be lessened; [and]
• there is evidence that it is necessary or desirable for the prices of the airfield
activities supplied by … [Auckland and Christchurch airports] to be controlled in
accordance with the Commerce Act in the interests of the acquirers of airfield
activities. (CC 2001b, p. xliv)
Several participants raised concerns about the methodology used in the CC’s draft
report. These concerns related to the definition of the aeronautical asset base and its
valuation, the modelling of future returns and the dynamic efficiency gains that it
estimated would be achieved through price controls (chapter 11).
To consider further the substantive issues raised in response to the draft report, the
CC has delayed the release of its final report by six months (until the second quarter
of 2002). If price control is recommended in the final report, then a decision on the
type of model will be made after a consultation process as required by the
Commerce Act.
G.3 Germany
While most major German airports remain subject to some variant of cost-based
regulation based on a single till, the recent privatisation of airport infrastructure has
been associated with a move to incentive-based regulation. Nonetheless, Hamburg
is the only airport where incentive-based regulation has been introduced.12
Hamburg Airport was partially privatised in 2000.13 A new regulatory system was
adopted for the privatised airport, specified in a public contract between Hamburg
Airport and the Ministry of Economic Affairs of Hamburg. The contract is in place
for five years, from the beginning of 2000 to the end of 2004.
12 A price cap is planned to be introduced at Berlin Brandenburg International Airport when the
current privatisation process is completed.
13 Hochtief AirPort GmbH and Aer Rianta acquired a 36 per cent share, with an option for a
further 13 per cent. The City of Hamburg remains Hamburg Airport’s major shareholder.
INTERNATIONAL 427
EXPERIENCES
The basis of the regulation at Hamburg Airport is a dual-till CPI-X price cap, based
on revenue yield per passenger. The price cap applies to landing fees, passenger
handling fees, noise level charges and aircraft parking fees. The airport must also
attain quality of service targets under the regulatory framework. These include:
• availability of aircraft parking positions;
• availability and punctuality of passenger and baggage transport systems; and
• availability and quality of restaurants and retailers.
Capital expenditure is dealt with outside the cap, with proposed projects having to
pass a public review process.
G.4 Denmark
The system of economic regulation employed at Copenhagen Airport is another
variant of price-cap regulation. The approach has been to implement a system that
creates the incentive properties of price-cap regulation but on a more informal basis
than those used at airports in the United Kingdom and Germany.
The approach appears to be designed to provide similar incentives to those that exist
with a price cap (by providing airports with an incentive to reduce costs, and
airlines with decreasing airport charges in real terms), with the advantage of lower
compliance costs compared with more formal price-cap arrangements. However,
because any increase in airport charges requires approval from the regulator —
which will involve, to some extent, an assessment of the costs, revenues and
428 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
profitability of the airport — the system will be subject to some of the problems
associated with cost-based regulation discussed above (for example, the information
asymmetry and compliance cost issues discussed in section G.1).
While there appears to be no formal criteria against which proposals are judged, the
Ministry of Transport has stated that the airport should be allowed to make a
reasonable profit (TRL 2000b). Since 1992, there has only been one price increase
at Copenhagen Airport — a 15 per cent increase in 1999. This increase was
associated with the abolition of the availability of duty-free goods on intra-
European travel in June of that year.
In its draft report, the Commission suggested, in relation to Sydney Airport, that
airport charges that cleared the market for landing slots were likely to promote more
efficient outcomes compared with non-price allocation mechanisms, including the
current slot allocation scheme. This conclusion elicited comments and criticisms
from several participants.
This appendix explores in more detail some issues relating to efficient rationing of
scarce airport slot capacity. Though allocation of slots has particular relevance to
Sydney Airport (where hourly aircraft movements are restricted and a curfew
applies), other Australian airports experience excess demand for some facilities at
certain times of day or more occasionally. Capacity constraints also may become of
greater importance to them in the future whether due to exogenously-imposed
movement limits (eg curfews), environmental concerns or possible consequences of
price regulation on new investment.
ALLOCATING 431
SCARCE AIRPORT
SLOTS
Congestion refers to a situation where use of a facility by one party imposes costs
(delays etc) on other users, and vice versa. NECG defined congestion in a
submission to a concurrent Commission inquiry (Radiocommunications Acts) as:
… the impedence users impose on each other in conditions where the use of the system
by means of which the service is provided approaches its capacity limits. The ensuing
outcome reflects a negative externality, namely that the attempted consumption of an
additional unit will lower the utility derived from total realised consumption.
(NECG 2001a, p. 8)
Once the number of airport slots is fixed for whatever reason, and the slot limit is
binding, the issue is not one of additional use of the airport generating congestion
externalities, because additional use is not permitted. There may still be some
congestion at the airport consistent with the level of use allowed by the slot limit
but, at the margin, the slot limit (when binding) will set the level of use, not average
1 In other words whether property rights can be adequately defined and enforced (that is, whether
the services are ‘public’ or ‘private’). The services of airports seem to meet most of the
requirements of private goods.
2 Noise levies also apply to certain jet aircraft; these roughly average about $2 per arriving
passenger (chapter 3).
432 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
costs (including average congestion costs).3 Additional units of demand do not add
to congestion; rather, additional units of demand are competing for a fixed number
of slots (Forsyth 1997). The problem becomes one of allocating those scarce slots.
Congestion may ration use of other airport facilities where access is not controlled
or directly priced — for example, on landside access roads and inside terminals. But
this does not seem to be a significant matter for most of these facilities, and easing
such congestion is in the interests and, in general, under the control of the airports.
Pe a
Pa b c
D (peak hour)
Q0 Qs Qe Aircraft movements
As drawn, the imposed quantity constraint generates a loss of surplus equal to the
triangle abc; or the cost of limited capacity, relative to unconstrained capacity. This
3 That is, average costs (including congestion costs) will not lie above the point where demand
equals the fixed supply of slots. Marginal costs may equal, lie above or below this point.
4 The market-clearing price of course will vary with shifts in demand.
5 This charge might have been set such that the airport is expected to cover its average costs,
given total anticipated utilisation levels of the airport over the relevant regulatory period. For
example, it may be a charge estimated on the basis of a cost building-block methodology.
ALLOCATING 433
SCARCE AIRPORT
SLOTS
loss occurs whichever method for eliminating excess demand is used. Of course,
there may be no such loss, when all factors are considered, if the constraint were
imposed to address congestion or other externalities. For example, if the restriction
reduced congestion, promoted safety or reduced noise, there may be a net social
benefit in restricting use to Q0Qs.
At issue is which mechanism should be used to allocate Q0Qs slots, given excess
demand equal to QsQe at price Pa. There are two broad options for rationing excess
demand: price rationing and non-price rationing. Non-price rationing can involve
either formal mechanisms such as administered allocation, or informal mechanisms
(essentially queuing). (Non-price rationing will be combined with some price
rationing if price Pa prevails. That is, if slots were free, then demand would exceed
Qe.) Price rationing involves pricing slots in some way. It could involve a higher
charge for each time a slot is used and/or the sale or lease of scarce slots at specified
times for a specified period.
Rationing by queuing
If slots are neither fully priced nor systematically allocated to users, then rationing
will occur automatically by queuing. For example, planes could be placed in
holding patterns or some could delay their departure from other airports. Queuing in
regulated airspace could be viewed as a form of congestion, though there are rules
preventing encroachment on the airspace of another plane. The main ‘externality’
will be that the average time required to reach (or depart from) the airport (at times
of excess demand) will increase, with delays and disruptions to schedules.
This method of equilibrating the market involves real resource costs — the value of
time spent queuing, the opportunity cost of aircraft and crews, and additional direct
costs (including the cost of fuel incurred by airlines). In effect, the market-clearing
price Pe will be paid (figure H.1), but with part of this price paid in money (Pa) to
the airport and the remainder (Pe minus Pa) paid in queuing costs.6 Passengers will
tend to pay the equilibrium price either as the value of their time forgone and/or
through higher fares reflecting additional costs incurred by airlines. Thus the
rectangle of surplus PaPeab is likely to be eroded entirely by queuing costs. Airport
operators would continue to receive price Pa and thus revenue equal to their total
costs.
6 Strictly speaking, the demand curve will differ from the normal demand curve when goods and
services are allocated by queuing etc. This demand curve will reflect willingness to queue
rather than willingness to pay.
434 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
In addition, it is possible that some airlines and consumers who value the slots at
less than their market-clearing value (Pe as drawn) gain access at the expense of
those prepared to pay at least that market-clearing value. The additional costs per
passenger of circling above the airport for an aircraft, for example, may be roughly
the same as the additional costs incurred by a larger aircraft. This could make it
worthwhile for the small plane (and its passengers) to join the queue and compete
for the valuable slot. To the extent that users with lower valuations of the slots gain
access at the expense of those with higher valuations, additional surplus could be
forgone.
Administered allocation
ALLOCATING 435
SCARCE AIRPORT
SLOTS
from Dublin to Heathrow are KLJKHU WKDQ IDUHV IURP 'XEOLQ WR *DWZLFN 7KLV
difference is not explained by differences in airport charges.)
However, with slots allocated rather than priced to clear the market, some slot
holders are likely to service markets in which passengers, on average, have lower
valuations of the slot (eg tourists who are less time sensitive). Slot holders in this
category will also tend to use price to ration seats but they will receive an average
fare premium somewhat smaller than PaPe.
A formal quantity rationing scheme (where secondary slot trading is not permitted)
could achieve the same allocation as achieved by price rationing, so airlines with
passengers with the highest valuations obtain access at price Pa. If this were to
occur, airlines would capture the area of surplus PePaba in figure H.1. However, in
practice, even if such an efficient allocation were sought, it is highly unlikely that it
could ever be achieved. This is because there is no mechanism for gauging the slot
valuations of the various user airlines. Typically, however, such schemes are
designed to bring about a somewhat different allocation, reflecting community or
other objectives. Nonetheless, any move away from an ‘efficient’ allocation will
reduce potential economic surplus, and this cost has to be weighed against the
benefits of overriding that allocation.
Airlines with slot allocations that are more valuable to others also may use up
resources (eg persist with inefficient schedules and inappropriate plane size) to
retain allocations for their future use or to prevent new entrants. They have an
incentive to do this if the cost of holding the slot is low relative to the value of the
slot to potential competitors. It also is possible that airlines use some of the rents
that accrue from slot allocations to cover fixed costs of other flights.
Airport slots can be price rationed in various ways, ranging from charges for using a
slot, to the sale of future access rights to, for example, a daily or weekly slot or to a
bundle of such slots. As discussed below, the prices that airlines are willing to pay
for future slot rights will be highly sensitive to user charges levied by airports and
potential changes in slot capacity. In other words, defining future rights and
conditions of airport access may be difficult unless constraints are imposed, or
agreements reached, on future airport pricing and investment.
Traditionally, airports have charged for aircraft landings and sometimes for take-
offs. Thus they charge for use of the runway and related infrastructure. As discussed
in chapter 7, a profit-maximising airport operator has a strong incentive to introduce
efficient peak charges to ensure that the airport extracts scarcity rents. As also
discussed in chapter 7, as well as higher charges at peak times, efficient pricing of
scarce runway capacity is likely to require charges to be levied in a way that is
invariant to plane size (for example, a fixed fee per landing, unless plane size
affects time spent landing and taking off). This will facilitate access at such times of
larger planes with higher payloads at the expense of smaller ones with lower
payloads.
In figure H.1, and assuming that peak demand is stable (implications of demand
volatility are discussed below), if user charges (rather than the sale of slots) were
used to allocate scarce runway capacity, then the price of using a slot at the peak
would rise to Pe to clear the market.7 At this price, the airport would retain scarcity
rents equal to PePaba.
Whether the airport earned higher profits overall would depend on charges levied at
off-peak times. If the latter fall to their short-run marginal cost, overall, the airport
may continue just to cover total costs.8 In other words, revenues generated by the
7 This assumes independent demands between peak and off-peak times. If demands are
interdependent, then the price rise required at peak times may be somewhat less than this.
8 NECG (ACCC, sub. DR55, attachment A) suggested that off-peak charges could be pushed to
zero to ensure that the revenue constraint is not breached by peak prices. If the revenue
constraint is fixed, such restructuring may promote efficiency, by providing scope for even
higher peak prices and a greater differential between peak and off-peak charges. However, it is
difficult to see why off-peak users should pay a price below the short-run marginal cost of
operating the airport at these times, just to ensure that the airport does not make profits in
excess of ‘normal’ levels. Moreover, unless costs fall as a result, an airport will have little
incentive to restructure charges if allowable revenue is fixed.
ALLOCATING 437
SCARCE AIRPORT
SLOTS
optimal peak/off-peak price structure feasibly may not exceed cost-related revenue
constraints. However, there is no a priori reason that efficient peak and off-peak
pricing will or should generate this result.
If demand fluctuates from day to day, the market-clearing user charge will need to
adjust to clear the market. As it is unlikely that a ‘spot’ market in slots would be
feasible or efficient, airports are likely to set an average peak charge, probably
somewhat below Pe. This, then, would require a complementary form of rationing to
clear the market. As discussed below, if the airport owns or controls slot rights, it is
likely to devise contracts and pricing structures to address this issue. If the airport
did not own or control slot rights, the market could be cleared by queuing, formal
slot allocation (and slot swapping), or slot trading.
With peak user charges, those airlines and passengers with the highest willingness
to pay will obtain access. Passengers not prepared to pay the peak price will shift to
flights at different times, use other transport and communications modes or not
travel at all. Airlines operating flights that carry insufficient passengers willing to
pay the higher charges will reschedule or reduce these flights. Thus peak charges
will encourage rationalisation of flight schedules so that each flight carries enough
passengers prepared to pay on average the peak charge.
Compared with free allocation of slots, airlines may be less likely to engage in
strategies to keep competitors out. Not only would they have to incur the costs of
flying the route, but also the higher airport landing charge. However, it is feasible
that one airline could buy all available slots with a view to monopolising the
industry if access to the slot-constrained airport were critical to network viability.
Under the existing slot allocation scheme operating at Sydney Airport and in most
other countries, slots can be swapped but, officially, not traded for cash. However,
slot trading increasingly has been mooted as one way of promoting more efficient
slot allocations. In addition, there has been discussion of selling rather than giving
slots to airlines.9
9 For a discussion of issues relating to the introduction of slot auctions and slot trading see
PC (1998a, chapter 8) and Ewers et al (2001).
438 PRICE REGULATION
OF AIRPORT
SERVICES
If airlines value certainty of airport access (for example, to facilitate scheduling),
and property rights for slots could be adequately defined (in the sense of defining
future rights of access to slots at an airport), slot rights could be leased or sold to
airlines.10 Airlines then would be prepared to pay the discounted value of
anticipated scarcity rents (that is, the additional expected fare revenue) for slots. As
with market-clearing user charges, slot sales generally would ensure that slots were
obtained by those who valued them most.
Future slot rights could be leased or sold to airlines by a body other than the airport
(so that, for example, scarcity rents accrued directly to the government). However,
in bidding for slots, airlines would take into account anticipated airport user
charges; any increases in user charges would reduce the value of a slot. They also
would need to take into account the potential for airport expansion, which also
could undermine the scarcity premium. In other words, as already noted, defining
and pricing rights for future airport slots is inextricably linked to expected future
airport pricing and investment behaviour.
If property rights for slots were vested in the airport, the airport operator might
introduce a form of two-part pricing, whereby airlines reserved access to the airport
at a certain time by purchasing a slot (with these access prices reflecting slot
scarcity), and pay a user charge (reflecting airport operating costs) when exercising
that access right. Again, how much airlines were prepared to pay for access at a
specified time would depend on the user charge and the potential for changes in slot
availability. Consequently, airports would have an incentive to sell a ‘package’
combining clearly-defined slot rights and future user charges. Whether particular
slots were reserved or leased (and for what period), sold outright or neither leased
nor sold, would depend on an assessment by airlines of the benefits and costs
associated with holding future slot rights versus not reserving access and paying on
the basis of airport use.
If property rights for future slots were vested with airlines (that is, if slots were
given to airlines on an indefinite basis or for a fixed period), and trading of these
slots permitted, the traded price of slots also would tend to reflect their scarcity
value and encourage transfer to their most efficient use. The incentive for an airline
to use a slot inefficiently would be reduced (compared to the situation where slot
trading is not permitted) because that slot could be sold to another airline. However,
incumbent airlines (which have been given slots) may retain an advantage over new
airlines (which must buy slots). Even though the opportunity cost of holding a slot
10 The ACCC (sub. DR55) refers to these allocation mechanisms as market-clearing mechanisms
rather than price mechanisms. But the question is not whether the market will clear. Rather, the
question is which variable adjusts to equilibrate supply and demand. In the case of slot sales,
prices for slots adjust to clear the market.
ALLOCATING 439
SCARCE AIRPORT
SLOTS
would increase (reflecting its cash value), incumbent airlines could use the rents
they derive from slots to drive down network prices in order to deter new airline
entry. In essence, slot quota rents could give incumbents deeper pockets than new
entrants. As noted above, slot acquisition could also be used as a monopoly
strategy.
Queuing
A non-price demand management scheme (where slot trading is not permitted) has
advantages over queuing to the extent that the value airlines place on the slot
exceeds the regulated price. Thus, some of the potential surplus (represented in
figure H.1 by the area dPaba) will not be forfeited. Instead, it will tend to accrue to
airlines that hold the slots and that ration, through prices, available seats among
passengers. In principle, while an administered allocation could mimic the outcome
under price rationing such that all of this surplus is retained, in practice it is highly
unlikely that all scarce slots would accrue to those airlines and passengers who
value them most highly. This may be deliberate policy, but unless the allocation
addresses a market distortion, it comes at an efficiency cost. Also, as mentioned
above, as with any quota allocation scheme, slot allocation schemes create
incentives for wasteful rent-seeking behaviour by airlines in a bid to obtain or retain
valuable slots.
Price rationing
Allocating scarce resources via the price mechanism generally will ensure that those
with the highest willingness to pay, obtain slots. This could occur whether pricing
occurs via charges for use of the airport or via slot sales and trading (provided
property rights for future airport access can be contracted).
The ACCC suggested that price rationing using airport user charges is likely to be a
very difficult exercise:
One of the disadvantages of the approach to congestion pricing recommended by the
PC is the substantial information required to set efficient prices. This is not a trivial
issue. To the contrary it is central to establishing workable regulatory arrangements.
Furthermore the potential efficiency losses of getting prices wrong could be substantial.
(sub. DR55, p. 17)
Though pricing is a difficult exercise for most industries in the economy, producers
generally have an incentive to devise price structures that increase their profits.
They also are likely to have better information than most others (except the users)
about demand for their product. As discussed in chapter 7, an airport operator facing
an exogenously-imposed capacity constraint will have an incentive to devise
efficient prices to increase profits. Indeed, for this reason, an airport operator is
likely to devise an efficient peak/off-peak price structure (including marginal off-
peak users paying prices equal or close to short-run marginal cost). Implementing
this structure probably will require iterations from time to time (for example, by
adjusting discounts/rebates), but this need arises in any market.
That said, as discussed earlier, demand for slots is likely to change from day to day,
thus causing the market-clearing price to change. It is unlikely that clearing the
market for slots by continual iterations in airport user charges would be efficient. In
ALLOCATING 441
SCARCE AIRPORT
SLOTS
particular, many airlines are likely to value certainty of access to the airport and
predictable (maximum) future prices. Therefore, efficiency is likely to require user
charging combined with some form of slot reservation mechanism. This could be
achieved by long-term contracts and pricing structures devised by the airport or
airport user charges complemented by an independent slot trading mechanism.
As for efficiency over time, the main requirements are that current prices signal the
strength of demand for a service, and that the provider has an incentive to invest
appropriately, including some expectation of making a reasonable return on the
investment required to meet that demand.
The CAA (2001c, p. xiv), while concluding that a ‘price cap at market-clearing
levels would be likely to improve the use of scarce capacity’, also noted that ‘while
market-clearing prices may provide good signals to the airports of where new
capacity is desired, they may not provide good incentives to actually deliver it at the
socially desirable time’.
In short, while higher airport charges may signal clearly the need for new
investment, that investment may not be forthcoming if the airport retains scarcity
rents. As discussed in chapter 7, under certain assumptions, an airport with market
power will under-invest to maximise monopoly profits over time. This does not
mean that an airport operator will never invest, just that investments will be delayed
to maximise profits. Nonetheless, to the extent that price discrimination is feasible
and/or additional throughput increases non-aeronautical profits, even an airport with
market power will have some incentive to invest efficiently in additional
aeronautical capacity. The threat of potential competition (from existing or new
airports) also may encourage more efficient investment. It is interesting to note that
physical capacity constraints at some airports overseas appear to have arisen with
regulated prices held below market-clearing levels and apparently below the
incremental costs of expanding capacity.
If future slot rights could be bought and sold, there would be some indication of
scarcity rents and the willingness to pay for those slots. While this may assist in
assessing whether new investment would be socially desirable, the airport will
invest only if the regulated price will provide a reasonable return on that
investment. Also, just as airports may have an incentive to delay investment,
airlines holding slot rights would have an incentive to lobby against any expansion
of airport capacity that may undermine their value.
11 In the USA, however, airlines are required to provide information to government about average
route yields.
12 The situation at Sydney Airport is somewhat unusual in that additional airport capacity is likely
to be developed at another facility. So key objectives for pricing at Sydney Airport are
promotion of efficient use of that constrained facility and signalling (to government) when a
second facility should be built. If bidders were advised they could set market-clearing prices
(and made aware that the government would choose when construction of the second airport
would commence), bidders would tailor their bids accordingly.
ALLOCATING 443
SCARCE AIRPORT
SLOTS
References
REFERENCES 445
—— 1999d, Delta Car Rentals Request for Determination — Statement of Reasons,
April.
—— 1999e, Regulatory Report: Brisbane Airport, 1998-99, December.
—— 1999f, Regulatory Report: Perth Airport, 1998-99, December.
—— 2000a, Infrastructure Industries: Aviation, May.
—— 2000b, New Investment Costs Pass-through, Position Paper, April.
—— 2000c, Perth Airport: Proposal to Increase Aeronautical Charges to Recover
the Costs of Necessary New Investment — Final Decision, April.
—— 2000d, Regulatory Reports: Phase II, 1998-99, March.
—— 2000e, Submission to the Productivity Commission’s Review of the National
Access Regime, Sub. 25, December.
—— 2000f, Brisbane Airport, Proposal to Increase Aeronautical Charges to
Recover the Costs of Necessary New Investment — Decision, April.
—— 2000g, Melbourne Airport, Multi-User Domestic Terminal — New Investment
Decision, August.
—— 2001a, Melbourne Airport, Necessary New Investment: Taxi Charge Proposal
— Decision, May.
—— 2001b, Regulatory Report: Brisbane Airport, 1999-00, April.
—— 2001c, Regulatory Report: Melbourne Airport, 1999-00, April.
—— 2001d, Regulatory Report: Perth Airport, 1999-00, April.
—— 2001e, Regulatory Report: Sydney Airport, 1999-00, April.
—— 2001f, Regulatory Reports: Phase II, 1999-00, April.
—— 2001g, Review of Price Control Arrangements, February.
—— 2001h, Sydney Airports Corporation Ltd: Aeronautical Pricing Proposal —
Draft Decision, February.
—— 2001i, Sydney Airports Corporation Ltd: Aeronautical Pricing Proposal —
Decision, May.
—— 2001j, Virgin Blue Request for a Determination, Issues Paper, March.
—— 2001k, Melbourne Airport, Proposal to Increase Aeronautical Charges as per
Direction 24, Issued by Federal Minister, Joe Hockey, Final Decision,
November.
—— 2001l, Draft Determination, Pursuant to section 192 of the Airports Act 1996,
Application by Virgin Blue in Respect of Certain Terminal Services at
Melbourne Airport, October.
446 REFERENCES
—— 2001m, Regulatory Report: Sydney Airport, 2000-01, November.
—— 2001n, Sydney Airport charges, Media Release no. 199/01, 23 August.
ACT (Australian Competition Tribunal) 2000, Sydney International Airport
[2000] AcompT 1, 1 March, http://www.austlii.edu.au/au/cases/cth/ACompT/
2000/1.html (accessed 6 April 2001).
ADR (Aeroporti di Roma) (no date), Areas of Business, http://www.adr.it/en/soc/
societa-03.html (accessed 24 May 2001).
Aer Rianta (no date), Current Structure, http://www.aer-rianta.ie/htmlonly/ar/htm/
struct/index.htm (accessed 24 May 2001).
AIAL (Auckland International Airport Limited) 2001, Submission to Commerce
Commission Draft Report (July 2001) and Preliminary Recommendations —
Airfield Price Control Inquiry, August.
Anderson, J. (Deputy Prime Minister and Minister for Transport and Regional
Services) 2000, Sydney’s future airport needs, Media Release no. A197/2000,
13 December.
—— 2001a, Tesna Consortium Bid for Ansett Australia, Media Release no.
A257/2001, 27 November.
—— 2001b, Sub. to ACCC in response to Sydney Airport 2000 pricing proposal,
12 January, p. 1.
—— and Gosche, M. (New Zealand Minister for Transport and Minister
Responsible for Civil Aviation) 2000, Australia – New Zealand open skies
agreement, Joint Media Release no. A182/2000, 20 November.
—— and Kemp, R. (Acting Minister for Finance and Administration) 2001, Sale of
Sydney (Kingsford-Smith) Airport, Joint Media Release no. A11/2001,
29 March.
APAC (Australia Pacific Airports Corporation) 1998, Delta Car Rentals, Request
for Determination Under Section 192 of the Airports Act, Submission to the
ACCC, December.
—— 2000a, Annual Report 1999-00.
—— 2000b, Submission to the Productivity Commission’s Review of the National
Access Regime, Sub. 10, December.
—— 2001, Review of the National Access Regime: Comments on Position Paper,
Submission to the Productivity Commission’s Review of the National Access
Regime, Sub. DR60, May.
ASA (Airservices Australia) 2000, Charges for Facilities and Services: Standard
Contract Terms, 1 July, Canberra.
REFERENCES 447
Averch, H. and Johnson, L. 1962, ‘Behavior of the firm under regulatory
constraint’, American Economic Review, vol. 52, no. 5, pp. 1052–69.
BAC (Brisbane Airport Corporation) 2001, Airport announces release of new land,
Media Release, 22 February.
Ballantyne, T. 2001, ‘Terminal ailment’, Bulletin with Newsweek, 23 October,
pp. 84–5.
BARA (Board of Airline Representatives Australia) 2000, Submission to the ACCC
Regarding Sydney Airport Corporation Limited’s Draft Pricing Proposal,
November.
Barbeliuk, A. 2001, ‘Rush for cheap seats as Kendell takes flight’, (Hobart)
Mercury, 8 October, p. 9.
Barlow, C. 2001, No increase in international airline charges, Media Release,
Melbourne Airport, 5 November.
Bartholomeusz, S. 2001, ‘Domestic key to Qantas’ future’, Age — Business News,
6 October, p. 1.
Battersby, B. and Oczkowski, E. 2001, ‘An econometric analysis of the demand for
domestic air travel’, International Journal of Transport Economics, vol. 28,
no. 2, pp. 193–204.
Baumol, W.J., Panzar, J.C. and Willig, R.D. 1982, Contestable Markets and the
Theory of Industry Structure, Harcourt Brace Jovanovich, New York.
Betancor, O. and Rendeiro, R. 1999, ‘Regulating privatized infrastructures and
airport services’, World Bank Policy Research Working Paper no. 2180,
September.
BTCE (Bureau of Transport and Communications Economics) 1995, Demand
Elasticities for Air Travel to and from Australia, Working Paper no. 20, AGPS,
Canberra.
BTR (Bureau of Tourism Research) 2000a, International Visitors in Australia,
1999, Canberra.
—— 2000b, Travel by Australians 1999: Annual Results of the National Visitor
Survey, Canberra.
Button, K. and Stough, R. 2000, Air Transport Networks: Theory and Policy
Implications, Edward Elgar Publishing, Cheltenham, United Kingdom.
CAA (Civil Aviation Authority) 2000a, Easyjet Application for Designation of
Luton Airport, London, http://www.caaerg.co.uk (accessed 7 June 2001).
—— 2000b, Economic Regulation of Airports — General Guidance, London,
http://www.caaerg.co.uk (accessed 7 June 2001).
448 REFERENCES
—— 2000c, Issues for the Airport Reviews, Consultation Paper, London,
http://www.caaerg.co.uk (accessed 7 June 2001).
—— 2000d, Quality of Service Issues, Consultation Paper, London,
http://www.caaerg.co.uk (accessed 7 June 2001).
—— 2000e, The CAA Approach to Economic Regulation and Work Programme for
the Airport Reviews, Position Paper, London, http://www.caaerg.co.uk (accessed
1 June 2001).
—— 2000f, The ‘Single Till’ and the ‘Dual Till’ Approach to the Price Regulation
of Airports, Consultation Paper, London, December.
—— 2000g, The Use of Benchmarking in the Airport Reviews, Consultation Paper,
London, http://www.caaerg.co.uk/ (accessed 7 June 2001).
—— 2001a, Direct Contracting Between Airport Users: A Default Price Cap,
Consultation Paper, London, http://www.caaerg.co.uk (accessed 7 June 2001).
—— 2001b, Pricing Structures and Economic Regulation, Consultation Paper,
London, http://www.caaerg.co.uk (accessed 7 June 2001).
—— 2001c, Heathrow, Gatwick, Stansted and Manchester Airports’ Price Caps
2003–2008, Preliminary Proposals, Consultation Paper, November.
CC (Commerce Commission, New Zealand) 2001a, Price Control Study of Airfield
Activities, Critical Issues Paper, Wellington, March.
—— 2001b, Price Control Study of Airfield Activities at Auckland, Wellington, and
Christchurch International Airports, Draft Report, Wellington, July.
—— 2001c, Airport price control report to be finalised in 2002, Media Release
no. 2001/108, 2 November.
Chanticleer 2001, ‘Airport bids growth conundrum’, Australian Financial Review,
12 June, p. 72.
Cheesman, B. 2001, ‘Malaysia’s aviation goal up in the air’, Australian Financial
Review, 1 August, p. 9.
CIAL (Christchurch International Airport Limited) 2001, Response to Commerce
Commission Draft Report, August.
Commonwealth of Australia 1998a, Airport lease for Townsville airport.
—— 1998b, Crown lease, Airport lease for Canberra airport.
Costello, P. (Treasurer) 1997, Prices monitoring at privatised airports, Press
Release no. 69, 27 June.
—— 1998, Prices oversight of privatised airports, Press Release no. 55, 25 May.
REFERENCES 449
—— and Anderson, J. (Minister for Transport and Regional Services) 1999,
International air services, Joint Media Release no. A79/99, 3 June.
Cotterill, R.M. 1999, Experience of price caps in UK airport regulation, Speech
presented at the Incentive Regulation and Overseas Developments Conference,
ACCC, Sydney, 18–19 November.
CPA (Cairns Port Authority) 2000, Annual Report 1999-00, Cairns, Queensland.
Crew, M.A. and Kleindorfer, P.R. 2001, Regulation for Privatized Airports: Single-
Till Versus Multi-Till Pricing Methodologies for Sydney Airport, Paper
submitted to the ACCC’s review of Sydney Airport’s aeronautical pricing
proposal.
Davidson, K. 2001, ‘Essendon’s value is not as an airport’, Age, 19 April, p. 17.
Doganis, R. 1992, The Airport Business, Routledge, London.
DoTRD (Department of Transport and Regional Development) 1996, Pricing
Policy Paper, Canberra, November.
DoTRS (Department of Transport and Regional Services) 2000a, Air Transport
Statistics, International Scheduled Air Transport, 1999-00, AVSTATS,
Canberra.
—— 2000b, Air Transport Statistics: Regular Public Transport Services, Airport
Traffic Data, 1989-90 – 1999-00, AVSTATS, Canberra.
—— 2000c, Australian airport operations in the context of privatisation,
Presentation to the ICAO ANS conference, Montreal, June.
—— 2001, Domestic Airlines Monthly Activity Report, March 2001, AVSTATS,
Canberra.
Europe Economics 2001, Airport Cost Allocation: Report for the CAA by Europe
Economics, London, April.
Ewers, H. et al 2001, Possibilities for the Better Use of Airport Slots in Germany
and the EU: A Practical Approach, Commissioned by Hochtief AirPort GmbH,
Berlin, January.
FAC (Federal Airports Corporation) 1996, Annual Report 1995-96, Sydney.
—— 1997, Annual Report 1996-97, Sydney.
—— 1998, Annual Report 1997-98, Sydney.
Federal Court of Australia 2001a, Canberra International Airport Pty Ltd v
Australian Competition and Consumer Commission [2001] FCA 289, 23 March.
—— 2001b, Canberra International Airport Pty Ltd v Australian Competition and
Consumer Commission [2001] FCA 1172, 24 August.
450 REFERENCES
Ferguson, A. and Meyrick, M. 2001, ‘Ansett II hovering’, Business Review Weekly,
18 October, p. 37.
Forsyth, P. 1997, ‘Price regulation of airports: principles with Australian
applications’, Transportation Research-E, Great Britain, vol. 33, no. 4, pp. 297–
309.
—— 1999, Regulating access to airport facilities, Paper presented at the Air
Transport Research Group Conference, City University of Hong Kong,
6–8 June.
—— 2001, Privatisation and regulation of Australian and New Zealand airports,
Paper presented at 4th Hamburg Aviation Conference, ‘Regulation versus
Competition? Strategic Airport Management’, Hamburg University,
14–16 February.
Harris, P. (First Assistant Secretary, Aviation Policy, Department of Transport and
Regional Development) 1997, Post privatisation regulatory environment,
Synopsis of presentation to ‘Airports 97 Future Perspectives Conference’,
Melbourne, 11 August.
Heasley, A. 2001, ‘Railing against air chaos’, Age, 26 September, p. 4.
Hockey, J. (Minister for Financial Services and Regulation) 2001, Prices oversight
arrangements at airports, Media Release no. FSR/081, 5 October.
HoR (House of Representatives, Australia) 1995, Debates, vol. HR202, pp. 2793–
2800.
—— 1996, Debates, vol. HR206, pp. 1305–1311.
Huttner, D. 2001, Virgin Blue raises concerns about Gold Coast Airport charges
having an adverse effect on tourism, Media Release, Virgin Blue, Brisbane,
10 October.
IATA (International Air Transport Association) 2001, About Us: Mission and
Goals, http://www.iata.org/missgoal.htm (accessed 11 April 2001).
IC (Industry Commission) 1992, Intrastate Aviation, Report no. 25, AGPS,
Canberra.
ICAO (International Civil Aviation Organization) 1996, Manual on the Regulation
of International Air Transport.
Innis, M. 2001, ‘Lucky break’, Sydney Morning Herald, 10 October, p. 6.
Juan, J. 1995, Airport Infrastructure: the Emerging Role of the Private Sector —
Recent Experiences Based on 10 Case Studies, Cofinancing and Financial
Advisory Services Discussion Paper Series no. 115, World Bank, Washington.
REFERENCES 451
Kahn, A.E. 1988, The Economics of Regulation: Principles and Institutions,
vols 1–2, MIT Press, Cambridge, Massachusetts.
—— 1991, Statement on Behalf of United Kingdom of Great Britain and Northern
Ireland in US/UK Arbitration Concerning Heathrow Airport User Charges,
April.
—— 2001a Evidence on Behalf of Sydney Airports Corporation, NERA, New
York, January.
—— 2001b, Statement on Behalf of Auckland International Airport Ltd, August.
Kanafani, A. and Lan, L. 1988, ‘Development of pricing strategies for airport
parking — a case study at San Francisco Airport’, International Journal of
Transport Economics, vol. 15, no. 1, pp. 55–76.
Kemp, R. (Assistant Treasurer) 2000, Productivity Commission inquiry into prices
oversight arrangements at airports, Press Release no. 056, 21 December.
Kew, I. 2001, ‘Why airport car park fee increased’, Northern Territory News, Letter
to the editor, 6 November, p. 10.
King, S. 2000, ‘Access: what, where and how’, in Productivity Commission and
Australian National University, Achieving Better Regulation of Services,
Conference Proceedings, AusInfo, Canberra, pp. 63–93.
Kunz, M. 1999, ‘Airport Regulation: the Policy Framework’, in Pfähler, W.,
Niemeier, H. and Mayer, O.G. (eds), Airports and Air Traffic: Regulation,
Privatisation and Competition: [Economic Forum of the Free and Hanseatic
Hamburg], Peter Lang, Frankfurt, pp. 11–55.
—— 2001, Airport regulation: lessons from the UK, Paper presented at the
4th Hamburg Aviation Conference, ‘Regulation versus Competition? Strategic
Airport Management’, Hamburg University, 14–16 February.
Layard, P.R.G. and Walters, A.A. 1978, Microeconomic Theory, McGraw Hill
Book Company, New York.
Law Council of Australia 2001, Legislation Review of Clause 6 of the Competition
Principles Agreement and Part IIIA of the Trade Practices Act 1974, Submission
to the Productivity Commission’s Review of the National Access Regime,
Sub. 37, January.
Littlechild, S.C. 1983, Regulation of British Telecommunications Profitability: A
Report to the Secretary of State for Trade and Industry, Department of Trade
and Industry, London.
Melbourne Airport 2001, Introduction of Taxi Parking Charge, March.
452 REFERENCES
NCC (National Competition Council) 1997, Applications for Declaration of Certain
Airport Services at Sydney and Melbourne International Airports: Reasons for
Decision, 8 May.
—— 2001, Legislation Review of Clause 6 of the Competition Principles
Agreement and Part IIIA of the Trade Practices Act 1974, Submission to the
Productivity Commission’s Review of the National Access Regime, Sub. 43,
January.
NECG (Network Economics Consulting Group) 2000a, ‘Dual Till’ at Sydney
Airport, Report prepared for the ACCC, Final Report, May.
—— 2000b, Land Valuation at Sydney Airport, Report prepared for the ACCC,
Final Report, May.
—— 2001a, Submission to the Productivity Commission’s Review of the
Radiocommunications Acts and the Role of the Australian Communications
Authority, Sub. 73, November.
—— 2001b, Virgin Blue Request for Determination: An Economic Analysis, Report
prepared for the ACCC — Final Report - July, in ACCC 2001l, pp. 29–49.
NERA (National Economic Research Associates) 2001a, Global Energy
Regulation, Newsletter, Issue no. 24, http://www.nera.com (accessed 30 June
2001).
—— 2001b, Price Control Study of Airfield Activities: A Critique, Report for
Auckland International Airport Limited, Sydney, August.
Niemeier, H. 2001, Regulating airports, Paper presented at the 4th Hamburg
Aviation Conference, ‘Regulation versus Competition? Strategic Airport
Management’, Hamburg University, 14–16 February.
NTTC (Northern Territory Tourist Commission) 2000, Territory Tourism Selected
Statistics 1999/2000, http://www.nttc.com.au/statistics/g_method_of_entry.htm
(accessed 20 June 2001).
OECD (Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development) 2000, Airline
Mergers and Alliances, Committee on Competition Law and Policy,
Competition Policy Roundtables no. 26, DAFFE/CLP (2001)1, Paris.
Ordover, J. and Saloner 1989, ‘Predation, Monopolization, and Antitrust’ in
Schmalensee, R. and Willig, R.D. (eds), Handbook of Industrial Organization
Volume 1, Elsevier Science Publishers B.V., Amsterdam, pp. 537–96.
Oum, T.H.O., Waters, W.G. and Yong, J. 1992, ‘Concepts of price elasticities of
transport demand and recent empirical estimates’, Journal of Transport
Economics and Policy, vol. 26, no. 2, pp. 139–54.
REFERENCES 453
PC (Productivity Commission) 1998a, International Air Services, Report no. 2,
AusInfo, Canberra.
—— 1998b, Regulation and its Review 1997-98, AusInfo, Canberra.
—— 2001a, Review of the National Access Regime, Report no. 17, AusInfo,
Canberra, (forthcoming).
—— 2001b, Review of the Prices Surveillance Act 1983 draft report public hearing
transcripts, 8 June, Melbourne.
—— 2001c, Review of the Prices Surveillance Act 1983, Report no. 14, Canberra,
(forthcoming).
—— 2001d, Telecommunications Competition Regulation, Report no. 16, Canberra.
—— 2001e, Structural Adjustment — Key Policy Issues, Commission Research
Paper, AusInfo, Canberra.
Pitchford, R. 2000, Sydney Airport Land Valuation: An Assessment, ACCC
Consultancy Report, http://www.accc.gov.au/airport/fs-air.htm (accessed 20
June 2001).
PSA (Prices Surveillance Authority) 1993, Inquiry into the Aeronautical and Non-
Aeronautical Charges of the Federal Airports Corporation, Report no. 48,
Melbourne.
—— 1995, Regulation of Airport Pricing — Is the New Zealand Approach
Applicable to Australia?, Discussion Paper no. 8, Melbourne.
Reed, R. 1999, ‘The Impact of Airline Deregulation on Costs and Efficiency’ in
Gaudry, M. and Mayes, R.R. (eds), Taking Stock of Air Liberalization (Centre
for Research on Transportation, University of Montreal, 25th Anniversary
Series, 1971–1996), Kluwer Academic Publishers, Boston, pp. 77–92.
SACL (Sydney Airports Corporation Limited) 2000, Sydney Airport Revised Draft
Aeronautical Proposal, September.
—— 2001, Sydney Airport, Aeronautical Pricing Proposal, Response to ACCC
Draft Decision, March.
Salazar de la Cruz, F. 1999, ‘A DEA approach to the airport production function’,
International Journal of Transport Economics, vol. 26, no. 2, pp. 255–70.
SATC (South Australian Tourist Commission) 2001, Tourism Research: Interstate
Travel to South Australia 2000, http://www.tourism.sa.gov.au/publications/
FastFacts/PDFDocument/Interstate_Data_Card_2000.pdf (accessed 5 December
2001).
Skulley, M. and Bolton, R. 2001, ‘Firms left to flounder but videophones boom’,
Australian Financial Review, 9 September, p. 8.
454 REFERENCES
Sommerfeld, J. 2001, ‘Airport site suits discount retailer’, Courier-Mail,
19 October, p. 39.
Starkie, D. 2001a, ‘Airport regulation and competition’, Journal of Air Transport
Management, vol. 7, no. 5, (forthcoming).
—— 2001b, ‘A new deal for airports’, in Robinson, C. (ed.), Regulating Utilities:
New Issues, New Solutions, Edward Elgar Publishing, Cheltenham, United
Kingdom.
—— 2001c, ‘Reforming UK airport regulation’, Journal of Transport Economics
and Policy, vol. 35, part 1, pp. 119–135.
—— and Thompson, D. 1985, Privatising London’s Airports, Institute of Fiscal
Studies, Report Series no. 16, London.
—— and Yarrow, G. 2000, The Single-Till Approach to the Price Regulation of
Airports, CAA, London, July, http://www.caaerg.co.uk (accessed 7 June 2001).
Stigler, G.J. 1969, The Theory of Price, 3rd edn, Macmillan, London.
Supreme Court of Victoria 2001, TXU Electricity Limited v Office of the
Regulator-General & Ors [2001] VSC 153, 17 May.
Taxis, M. 2001, ‘Airport will lose money’, Northern Territory News, Letter to the
editor, 25 October, p. 10.
Templeton, R. and Mills, A. 2001, ‘Higher tax hit upsets Virgin’, Gold Coast
Bulletin, 13 October.
Tirole, J. 1990, The Theory of Industrial Organization, MIT Press, Cambridge,
Massachusetts.
Toms, M.R. 1994, ‘Charging for airports: the new BAA approach’, Journal of Air
Transport Management, vol. 1, no. 2, pp. 77–82.
Tourism New South Wales 2001, Big Sky Country Region Tourism Profile, Year
end June 2000, Sydney.
Tourism Queensland 2000a, Fact Sheet — Brisbane, http://www.tq.com.au/
research/pdf/regional/brisbane.pdf (accessed 20 June 2001).
—— 2000b, Fact Sheet — Gold Coast, http://www.tq.com.au/research/pdf/
regional/goldcoast.pdf (accessed 20 June 2001).
—— 2000c, Fact Sheet — Queensland, http://www.tq.com.au/research/pdf/
regional/TotalQld.pdf (accessed 20 June 2001).
—— 2000d, Fact Sheet — Tropical North Queensland, http://www.tq.com.au/
research/pdf/regional/tnq.pdf (accessed 20 June 2001).
REFERENCES 455
Tourism Tasmania 2001, Tasmanian Visitor Survey 2000 Data Card,
http://www.tourismtasmania.com.au/research/dcard2000/ (accessed 20 June
2001).
Tretheway, M. 1996, ‘Giving airports an incentive’, Airport World, no. 3,
pp. 36–40.
TRL (Transport Research Laboratory) 2000a, Airport Performance Indicators 2000,
Crowthorne, United Kingdom.
—— 2000b, Review of Airport Charges 2000, Crowthorne, United Kingdom.
Vogelsang, I. 2001, A 20-year perspective on incentive regulation for public
utilities, Paper presented at the Regulation and Investment Conference, ACCC,
Sydney, 26–27 March.
—— and Finsinger, J. 1979, ‘A regulatory adjustment process for optimal pricing
by multiproduct monopoly firms’, Bell Journal of Economics, vol. 10, no. 1,
pp. 157–71.
Walters, A.A. 1978, ‘Airports: an economic survey’, Journal of Transport
Economics and Policy, vol. 12, no. 2, pp. 125–60.
WIAL (Wellington International Airport Limited) 2001, Submission to the
Commerce Commission on the Commission’s Draft Report and Draft
Recommendations Arising out of its Price Control Study of Airfield Activities,
Vol. 1: Main Submission and Appendices, August.
Willis, R. (Treasurer) 1994, Speech at Australian Labor Party function, Christie
Beach, Adelaide, 18 September, http://search.aph.gov.au/search/ParlInfo.ASP?
action=view&item=0&resultsID=FoKyY, (accessed 25 November 2001).
456 REFERENCES