79 Accessibility Morris Dumble Wigan Trans Res
79 Accessibility Morris Dumble Wigan Trans Res
79 Accessibility Morris Dumble Wigan Trans Res
0CtI0
@ Papmoa Pms L:d.. 1979. Prialtd ill OIUl Britain
both the supply side and the demand side of transport transport system that connects them (Wachs 1978). It so
services (Dalvi 1978). For the purpose of the present doing accessibility indicators are important descriptive
study. personal mobility is interpreted to mean the ability measures of urban spatial structure and performance.
of individuals to move from place to place: this depends With these broad applications in mind. let us now turn
principally upon the availability of different modes of to examine the various concepts and measures of ac-
transportation, including walking (see HiHman et aL 1973. cessibility which may be of value in transport planning.
1976). When defined in this sense. mobility is concep-
tually distinct from actual travel: and the argument over DEFINING AND MEAStlJlJNG ACCESSIBIUTY
mobility or accessibility as an objective in transport Accessibility measures are based on the premise that
planning is seen to be a futile exercise. Mobility and space constrains the number of opportunities available.
accessibility together influence an individual's capacity Beyond this point, definitions of the concept differ
to travel in daily life. It is important to recognise. widely. There is considerable variation in the other ele-
however, that perceilJed accessibility and perceilJed ments which may be included. and in how they are
mobility-the real determinants of behaviour-will be at measured and combined. As Gould (1969, 1964) has
variance with "objective" indicators of accessibility and noted, "accessibility •.. is a slippery notion ... one of
mobility. those common terms which everyone uses until faced
with the problem of defining and measuring it".
TralJeJ demand models To some desree. variations in accessibility measures
Accessibility indicators may also be used as input are inevitable since the appropriate definition will depend
variables in modelling travel choice situations. Travel upon the intended application. However. most of the
involves costs in time, money and human effort which confusion stems from fundamental differences of
must be borne directly by the community. Consequently. opinion. There is a basic dilemma in choosing between
accessibility not only influences the distribution of travel "process" indicators (measures of the supply charac-
costs within the community but may also affect levels of teristics of the system and/or individuals) and "outcome"
service use and participation in desired activities. It has indicators (such as actual use and levels of satisfaction).
been suggested that individuals make a set of mutually On the one hand accessibility may be interpreted as a
dependent choices or decisions which are highly depen- property of individuals and space which is independent
dent upon individual household members' perceived ac- of actual trip making and which measures the potential
cessibilities to various opportunities by a given trans- or opportunity to travel to selected activities. Alter·
portation system (Ben Akiva and Lerman 1975). Such natively, it may be held that "proof of access"lies in the
decisions include. for example. where to live. how many use of services and participation in activities. not simply
cars to own. and what trips to make at what times by in the presence of opportunities. Consequently there is a
which modes (Burns and Golob 1976). Accessibility, tendency to want to measure accessibility in terms of
therefore. represents an important element to be con- actual behaviour (Wachs 1978).
sidered in virtually all choice issues relevant to transport This basic conflict gives rise to a range of accessibility
planning. Once again. however, there is a fundamental measures which differ in terms of their behavioural
problem of measuring perceived values. component. And yet this represents only one of many
sources of variation in accessibility indicators. Since
Urban development models there is no concensus on an operational definition of
This third application of accessibility is closely accessibility. it is necessary to develop a broad
related to the second. although it represents a somewhat classification of accessibility measures before any
more longstanding interest held by transport planners. meaningful attempt can be made to evaluate them.
This concerns attempts to model the relationship be-
tween accessibility and urban development (Clark 19SI, A cltusi/icalion 0/ accessibility indicators
Hansen 19S9. Patton and Clark 1970. Davidson 1973, A useful classification of accessibility indicators is
1977, Beggs 1976). Here the focus is not so much on given in rIB. I. This is Jarsely an amalgamation of
modelling individual choices but on modeHing urban previous attempts to classify accessibility measures (In-
form in the aggregate. gram 1971, Briggs and Jones 1973. Wachs 1978). Exam-
ples of specific formulae and references for further dis·
Description cussion are presented for each terminal class shown in
Accessibility indicators provide possibly the most Fig. I.
useful and appropriate means of summarising a great The two principal bases of classification are the
deal of information on the location of households in behavioural dimension mentioned earlier. and a dis-
relation to the distribution of urban activities and the tinction between "relative accessibility" and " integral
accessibility" developed by Ingram (1971). Relative ac-
tThe term relative accessibility is sOmetimes used to descn'be cessibility describes the relation or degree of connection
an integral measure which has been normalised in order to between any two points. whereas integral accessibility
facilitate temporal or spallal comparisons. For instance, the
measure may be normalised to correct for changes over time in describes the relation or -degree of interconnection be·
the number of opportunities (sec Palton and Clark 1970) or for tween a given point and all others within a spatial set of
spatial variations in the competing pressures of demand for the pointst(see Fig. 2.}. Essentia11y. relative accessibility is a
relevant opportunities (Morris 1976). measure of the effort involved in making a trip;· while
Accessibility indicaton for transport planning 93
II • I I I I I I • • • I I I I
i s i • c w i IS
i
, r:: ~
- --
~
I
J i
r- .J of
I ~
~
.-- J-
~ II?
_II - ,il ~ II ~ _ iJ
lid - J
.8
~
r- II1I
1,1 t---
~
I
I! ~ 'r -
I~· ... r!
'i
I .~
0
r----
-I I-
II i
Jllh Iii I!
• P-
:=
~ i~
I IIII!
j~
l- I I 'I t!
r----
e
I...--
~ I- iI ~i IIf ~~
.B
B n
II! ~~
i~'
:s
--
.5 ~
'--
f 1,1
-
:is
J
i--
1
I
'- i~I~ I
I
, !
~E- - - - - - - - - - - -.....
stlOJ.WIGNI
UlI:xJIIcI
_,c
8tIOJ.WlCOO
..
lIfIOo.&110
94 J. M. MORRIS, P. L. DUMBLE and M. R. WIOAH
Relative Accessibility IntesroJ ACCOI8IbIllty from administrative restrictions on the use of services or
participation in activities (see Oberg 1976). The problem.
then, is to choose the most appropriate form from the
mass of alternatives.
I
AcceaalbUlty Protlle:
100
_""" 75
'!loG'
~tln so
2S
Cumuloth,o-opportunlty Indox:
-- 01
1
IthcU. . . . . 0'
ckaI~"11on ~omlU.'1n
• •UnaUon zone
ISII
30
omlta Gf _1111
_"lion
IromotlQlftl
ICQI
1
AI- ,,~fl
"c:.no.
"c:.no. -- 1.2.AI-
AI- 30
" c.n.. 3. AI - 200
;0
Gravity-type Index:
110
,Z 40
110 ,2 AI - I SI.'ICQI
I'Wlf_ _ 11'511IfICIII- ~
4 40 2 dP
.', AI- !1I+!1I+i!I +!11
1 4 II 4
- 30 + 10 + 10 + 10
- eo
Fig. 3. Sample calculations of some accessibility indicators.
Nevertheless, the similarities between the various appraisal of the spatial differences, and is based on a
types of composite indicators are more notable than their weighted ranking of life cycle, age group, immigration,
differences (see Weibull 1976). Indeed, Black and Conroy household and public facilities, car ownership, employ-
(1977) have devised an accessibility measure which ment and socio-economic characteristics. The higher the
combines the relative advantages of graphical and score, the greater the disadvantaged nature of the dis-
numerical indicators; specifically, a numerical value or trict.
index of accessibility may be derived by integrating the By comparing the different diagrams in Fig. 4 it
area under the cumulative opportunity curve bounded by becomes evident that a disadvantaged area would suffer
a given spatial separation limit. Unlike other cumulative- heavy restraint under supplementary licensing (requiring
opportunity indicators this index preserves information an extra licence to operate a vehic:le in the central area or
on the distribution of opportunities within the chosen "the railway triangle"). This is not a simple result to
separation band. The index also conforms with the six interpret. H the resident did not own cars (likely, in this
axioms of accessibility postulated by Weibull (1976), and area), then the sharp traffic reduction would be a key
has been shown to give empirical results which agree benefit, but if all the employment in the area was unsuit-
c:Iosely with those produced by a Hansen-type index able for the residents, they would be suffering a large
(Conroy 1978). But the index is still based on an artificial reduction in accessibility to their jobs. Further questions
boundary; and, as presently applied, does not allow for then arise on the degree of balance between residents
variations in demand at the supply points. and jobs in the area, and the average length of journey to
work.
An applied access/bUity indicator The detailed result of matching the different diagrams
The complications in definition and application of provides several illustrations of these distributional
different accessibility indicators should not be allowed to questions. Supplementary licensing and parking produce
confuse the issue: accessibility even 'as a simple relative, a very wide range of effects, and consequently pose
or uncomplicated integral, measure (see Fig. I) is an numerous awkWard distributional questions (W'Jg811 et aI.
effective addition to our assessment armoury. A practical 1974). In both cases the central area is the worst hit, and
example is siven to illustrate this point. FJBUte 4 shows it is interesting to note that this is the area most socially
four different diagrams on a common geographical basis, disadvantaged. It might therefore be argued that the
that of the city of Coventry in the U.K. The results are triangle restraint area (which forms the boundary for the
drawn from work (Wigan el al. 1974) done for the U.K. application of all the policies discussed) Is too large as it
Department of the Environment (1977) Traffic Restraint extends into areas beyond the central business district of
Study, where a wide range of different traffic restraint Coventry (a small area at the bottom of the triangle).
policies were examined using an equilibrium model (in- The accessibility changes for the cordon policy show
cluding elastic travel demand for private and public the lowest generalised costs (i.e. best accessibility) of the
passenger travel and goods transport). policies applied to the railway triangle, and even lower
The key point to be drawn from the diagram is that costs under restraint in the central area than in the
while two of the policies shown produce closely similar unrestrained state. This is a result of greater freedom of
net benefits, the spatial accessibility impacts have very movement for trips solely within the triangle, which
different forms. The diagrams illustrate simple measures therefore escape charging at the cordon.
of total separation (i.e. ICii. as shown in Fig. 1). The The parking costs show cost reductions for a very
social indicators diagram provides a basis for the social , large primary residential area to the north and west of
PARKING CORDON
:i
Benefit Benefit
£1400/hr £s2Oo/hr
GENERALISED GENERALISED
COST CHANGES COST CHANGES
IN ACCESSIBILITY IN ACCESSIBILITY
o- 1-31
1-31-1-141
Itr:ttl
l1li
0-1-41
(-51 - 1-91
1<.;>',1
Bl
!
:u
r
f
GENERALISED
COST CHANGES
---
IN ACCESSIBILITY PDINTS AGAINST
56-41
~ 80-65
41-32
rat 35-30
32-23
23-16
.,
ID 12-9
8-0
o
~
~
o
15-7 ~
7-0 IJIlII]
, Fig. 4. Spatial impacts of various transport policics in Coventry (After Wigan et aL 1974).
Accessibility indicators for transport plonnins 99
the triangle (as a direct consequence the number of trips tive opportunities index, as one dimension of the cate-
rise in this area). This has implications not only for land gory analysis matrices produced (Don 1975); the cell by
use but also for the public transport system which would cell (household) trip production rates varied with the
suBer reciprocal decline in passengers. level of accessibility, but in no consistent manner. Both
It may be concluded that: studies, however, adopted an aggregate approach to ac-
(I) Supplementary licensing produces the least pro- cessibility measurement (i.e. all persons in an origin zone
gressive effect; inducing the greatest accessibility shift in were assigned the same level of accessibility). Ac-
the three central wards (i.e. the triangle), and the least in cessibility, as pointed out earlier, will vary from in-
the peripheral areas to the north, east and west. dividual to individual and zonal aggregation provides an
(2) Parking charges produce the same general patterns inadequate basis for reproducing variations between in-
as supplementary licensing but the range of accessibility dividual circumstances. Individuals, or relatively homo-
shifts is not so large, and in some areas, the charges geneous groups of individuals, should be adopted as the
actually induce traffic. basic unit throughout the modelling process and should
(3) Cordon charging actually produces progressive not be introduced solely at the evaluation stage.
effects, and might therefore be rated more highly as a Several relatively succesful attempts have been made
result. The less advantaged areas retain their mobility to formulate models of travel behaviour based upon the
and are affected least, while the outer areas suffer the principles of micro-economic consumer demand theory,
revenue. particularly in the realms of travel choice (see McFadden
The general social distributional impacts are clearly (1973) for an excellent treatment). Some of these
highlighted by this analysis. The change in emphasis of represent explicit attempts to formulate trip generation
the assessment produced by the extra information pro- sub-models on micro-economic bases. For example
vided by a simple accessibility indicator is substantial, in Koenig (1977), after accepting that the exponential for-
the light of the close economic comparability between mulation of the gravity model was the correct model for
cordon and supplementary licensing. trip distribution, demonstrated that the trip generation
However, it is clear that none of the established rate was a function of accessibility. Bums and Golob
measures of accessibility satisfy all of the requirements (1976) demonstrated how an accessibility measure can be
for transport evaluation. Typically, simple measures fall incorporated into several of the travel choice areas.
down on behavioural grounds, while indicators with Niedercorn and Bechdolt (1969) and Cochrane (1975), in
stronger behavioural foundations are complex and attempts to give the gravity model a micro-economic
difficult to apply in practice. More importantly, even basis (using vastly different assumptions and ap-
though some indicators have a stronger behavioural basis proaches), produced trip generation sub-models which
than others, none are completely acceptable on incorporated what could be considered to be accessibility
behavioural grounds. This is because the established measures. Lastly, Williams (1977) in a rigorous
measures do not explain why increased accessibility theoretical treatment of travel demand models once
should lead to increased trip-making. Since this probably - . deduced the same result by indirect means.
represents the major stumbling block for accessibility Each of these direct or indirect approaches to ac-
indicators, the following section gives detailed con- cessibility and its importance in travel demand modelling
sideration to the theoretical underpinnings of accessibility . can be classified into one of the four approaches identified
indicators. by Koenig (1977):
(a) Common sense (e.g. Hansen 1959)
MJCJlO.ECONOMlC THEORY, TRAVEL DEMAND AND (b) Axiomatic (e.g. Weibull 1976)
ACCISSIBILITY (e) Consumers surplus (e.g. Neuberger 1971)
A perceived change in accessibility either affects travel (d) Behavioural utility (e.g. Koenig 1977).
behaviour directly or alters levels of satisfaction with the Distinctions between the approaches are blurred. parti-
transport/land-use system. Various theories, founded on cularly between the latter two, and often, depending on
models of micro-economic consumer behaviour have the vitial assumptions, lead to the same result. It is not,
been specified to express this implied causal relationship however, the aim of this paper to indulge in a theoretical
mathematically. Empirical results in support of these and abstract discussion on the merits of each of the often
theories are reviewed here together with the essentials of highly mathematical treatments given to some of these
the theories themselves. approaches. Rather the intention is to demonstrate that
Specifically, we concentrate on the trip generation there are accepted theories of micro-economics which
sub-model. This represents an area where it has long suggest that trip generation is likely to be influenced by
been recognised that accessibility (or supply) conditions accessibility. In particular we will examine the attempts
have a genuine inftuence, although previous attempts to of Koenig (1977), Niedercorn and Bechdolt (1969) and
model this relationship have not been particularly Cochrane (1975) to demonstrate this point. These are
encouraging. Daor (1975), for example, concluded that supported here with some empirical results.
the level of accessibility to relevant activities (when Some analyses were carried out on a household travel
measured by a Hansen-type index) produced insufficient survey executed in Ballarat in 1970 as part of the Ballarat
improvement in the trip generation sub-model to warrant Transportation Study (Harris Lange-Voorhees 1971).
inclusion. The Victorian Ministry of Transport (MoT) Ballarat was chosen because the sample size was small
included levels of accessibility, measured by a cumula- enough to be manageable-1284 households containing
100 J. M. MoRllfS. P. L DlBIBLI! and M. R. WIGAN
3804 persons over the age of S-and the survey included It should be made clear that this derivation focusses
data on all trips made, including walk and bicycle modes. on the individual. Hence the accessibility measure to be
Systematic under-reporting of walk trips is expected to used should be the accessibility as perceived by the
have occurred, as only one mode was recorded for each individual (and therefore dependent on the mode upon
trip. Where two or more modes were used, the access which they rely).
mode (often walking) was eliminated at the trip linkage There is no real reason why accessibility should not
stage. Such conventions of "dominant mode" coding also vary between trip purposes. It is conceptually ape
ignores key information on access modes which is now pealing that both the measure of opportunity for inter-
being realised to be of central importance in mobility and action and the wiUingness of an individual to travel
market segmentation approaches to modal choice. should vary with trip purpose.
Figure S gives practical weight to this first derivation.
This shows graphs of daily home-based trips per person
The approach 0/ Koenig (all modes) vs accessibility to relevant opportunities for a
Koenig demonstrates (on the assumptions briefly out- particular person category for some French cities
lined above) that the net utility (i.e. benefit) Ul, derived (Koenig 1977). The graphs show an increase in the
from a trip is, average for an individual of type k living observed trip generation rate with an increase in ac-
in zone i. given by the expressiont: cessibility, when both are defined and calculated on the
basis of the individual.
I
U," =x log. Al +constant
(I)
It has not been possible to compute similar indices for
Ballarat (along the lines of those in Fig. I), but the effect
where of varying levels of accessibility has been approximated
by subdividing Ballarat into a series of concentric rings.
AI" -- I Sle -,,~t, an ' These were numbered sequentially 1-4, outwards from
I S," "integral" (normalised) Hansen
the CBD. The mean trip generation rates for groups of
index (2) individual were then estimated on the assumption that
accessibility, by all modes, to all activities considered to
and S,· is the number of potential destinations for in- be important trip attractors, declines with distance from
vividuals of type k in zone I. x' is the exponential the centre of Ballarat. In a city such as Ballarat which
parameter associated with the destination choice has a single centre this assumption appears to be valid,
decision for individual k. C1, is the "cost" of travel particularly as Koenig (1977) demonstrates that it holds
between i and J. for the individual of type k. From now for tertiary employment places in the more complex city
on the suffix k will be removed, but it is implicit in all of Marseilles.
formulae. Figure 6(a) shows the mean trip generation rate for
The reasoning behind this hypothesis implies that if various groups of individuals by the number of the
the individual at i were to rank all potential trips in concentric ring in which they reside. For this analysis,
decreasing order of perceived net utility, then he would individuals were grouped according to their employment
travel just enough to ensure that the gross utility derived status (Harris Lange-Voorhees 1971). The result is in-
from making the last trip was exactly offset by the conclusive: the hypothesis that accessibility affects trip
disutility of undertaking it. That is, as well as the usual generation is not fuHy supported; but neither can it be
assumption that the trip rate for an individual at zone I is rejected. as there are probably several other influences at
a function of his socia-economic characteristics, Eit work. Fltst, the method of stratifying the population is
expressed mathematically as: probably not detailed enough to account for factors such
as income, socio-economic status, number of cars
(3) owned, etc., which also vary systematically with distance
from central Ballarat (Harris Lange-Voorhees 1971), and
eqn (I) implies that it is also a function of the average net which have previously been found to be strongly related
utility. hence of accessibUity, to be gained from making a to trip generation rates. Second, the method of ap-
trip. Thus eqn (3) becomes: proximating the accessibility level by distance from cen-
tral Ballarat attributes the same accessibility level to
(4) every individual resident in any particular concentric
ring, contrary to Koenig's assertion that a person's ac-
cessibility is dependent on the mode they choose (or are
forald) to take (Oenig 1977).*
tKeoaig's formulation bas been sJiahdy modified to facilitate FIgUre 6(b) shows that the non-car trip generation rate
easier comparison with other researchers' work.
*WiDlams (1m) would araue that accesiibility is not to be is affected by accessibility as postulated. The falloff with
calculated solely on the basis of chosen mode. His measure is decreasing accessibility is most marked for walk trips,
based on composite generalised cost and is internally consistent whUe tram§ tripS falloff sliPdy. and bus triDs increase
with his travel demand model. If an Individual has (or perceiVes) margmally. t<igure 6(c) snows tne enect ot accessibility
no real alternative mode, then Williams' measure reduces to that
for the chosen mode. summed over all person types for trips stratified by
_ ISince the Ballarat Transportation Study Was carried out in mode. This clearly indicates that car travel is the main
1970 the tram service has been withdrawn. component which weakens the hypothesis.
Accessibility indicators for transport planning 101
PERSON CATEGORV:
8 9 10
AI-ACCESSIBIUTV TO TERTIARV EMPLOYMENT PLACES
-
PERSON CATEGORIES: MOOE OF TRAVEL
((a) and (b) ) (el
----
------- .......,
- - u-tGyocl TI11'II
~
A _A'-
7---"$.-=--------
,- "",:,...,
•.• -
-.---.
\
... , -----
..- ......\..- \
-- ---...------
~
" 3 3
"
"----
.... '.
:-- ---"'._---_._- ---.
\
-----..-
-- ~.... :::--'~-..<--,-"
'.-- '\. -'" ~
~ ------
3
RING No.
•
RING No.• RING No. •
(a) All modes (b) Non-Car Modes (e) All Tripe. All Persons
An attempt was made to overcome the effect of car which indicates a slight but significant decrease in trip
ownership on the overall trip generation rate by dividing generation with a decrease in the level of accessibility.
the population into licence holding and non-licence holding The category:
groups. This step approximated the range of person types
used by Koenig. Thus Koenig's person category of: "housewives licensed to drive"
"non-working, non-car owning and over 60 years old" is also shown. Socio-economic factors are again likely to
explain the increase in trip generation rate with tlie
decrease in level of accessibility. However, housewives
is approximated by our person category: with driving licences at all levels of accessibility make
significantJy more trips than those without. indicating
"retired and non-licence holding". that the former group is far more "mobile" in the sense
discussed earlier in this paper. The same conclusion can
be drawn for all employment status groups although the
Figure 7 shows that once again our analysis does not
unequivocally support the hypothesis; apin the result is results are not presented here.
inconclusive. However, also plotted in Fig. 7 are the Fundamental allumptioflS underlying Koenig's approach
results for the person category: There are some practical considerations and theoreti-
"housewife, without driving licence" cal assumptions in Koenig's formulation which may limit
102 J. M. MORRIs, P. L. DUMBLE and M. R. WIGA'I
PeRSON CATEGORIES:
_.. ---
---- -----
- - RoIlrad. Non-oriver
- - - Housewife. Non-Oriver
4
RING No.
Fig. 7. Furtber effects of accessibility on trip rates in Ballarat.
the effectiveness of the whole approach when attempting in Koenig's formulation (though shared with current
to incorporate it into a working trip generation sub- travel demand modelling practice) is that all travel is of a
model. simple nature, That is, travel is assumed to be composed
One practical consideration is that of the zoning sys- solely of two-stage journeys:* starting at home, going to
tem. According to micro-economic consumer choice a single destination for a single purpose and then return-
theory the individual perceives that a set of alternatives ing bome. As a large proportion of travel is accounted
is open to him (Henderson and Quandt 1971) and that each for by multi-stage journeys, this assumption is incorrect.
alternative possesses a certain level of utility.t In a work- This may undermine the behavioural veracity of most
ing model the alternative destinations are typically agg- trip generation models in current use, due to the difticulty
regated within a zonal framework. For the model to be in specification of mode and purpose in multi-stage
behaviourally sound it is therefore necessary that the journeys and the mutual inftuence of each stage on
individual perceives the spatial distribution of activities perceived accessibility relevant to preceding and suc-
as this discrete pattern of zones. This is perhaps unlikely ceeding stages.
except for trip purposes such as shopping for high order One deficiency specific to Koenig's model is that the
goods which are available only at a very limited' number theory involved in the formulation does not provide us
of locations. It has been shown that accessibility indices with a behaviourally based functional form. That is,
are sensitive to the zoning system used (Dalvi and Martin while we know that:
1976). Ben Akiva and Lerman (1978) further suggest that
unless the zoning system is carefully designed "the 1i =I(E" V,) = g(E" log. A,) (5)
measure of accessibility will in general be biased".
Another general problem may be caused by the we are left with no clues as to what the function may be,
necessity to construct separate indices for different It would seem that increasing accessibility leads to an
modes. This requires some previous knowledge of the increasing trip rate, ad Infinitum, as eqn (I) suggests that
chosen mode; knowledge which does not become avail- the net utility derived from making any particular trip is
able in the sequential approach to travel demand model- independent of the number of such trips already under-
ling until after the trip distribution (destination choice) taken in the time period under consideration. The
stage. Some commentators have suggested a mode- concept of satiation must somehow be introduced. In
specific approach to trip generation to overcome this micro-economic utility theory this corresponds to the
drawback (Vickerman 1974, Bums and Golob 1976), requirement that marginal utility be a positive, but
given the marked effect of car availability (defined at the decreasing function of the quantity consumed (Hender-
time the decision is made to make, not to make, or to son and Quandt 1971):
delay making, a trip). Figure 7 indicates the strength of
this effect assuming that licence/non-licence holding is a
(6)
proxy for car availability, Approximating assumptions
can also be employed if one wishes to avoid the adoption
of mode-specific trip generation values. Other derivations using the same framework as Koenig
One other important, yet tacitly accepted assumption (and thus containing the same general assumptions) have
been proposed which attempt to incorporate such a
satiation effect.
tit is ollly necessary that the individual be able to rank all the Nledeftom and Bechdolt's approach
perceived alternatives open to him (HendenoD and Quandt 1971, Niedercorn and 8echdolt (1966) adopt the approach of
Samuelson 1971), , lith tili' f' d' 'd aI·th th .
*A journey is detlned as a trip sequence startina and endins at maxun s n~ e u tyo. tn IVI U S WI respect to etr
the bome bue. A mUlti-stage journey involves more than one . travel requtrements subJect to the constraints of the total
intermediate destination. amounts of time and money that individuals are willing
Accessibility indicators for tI'aIIsport plannlna 103
to spend on travel. This arises in the context of deriving S -AlII
tbe gravity model from micro-economic theory. (2) a trip destribution term, IS,ee-x1/J'
As a first approximation they assume that the net
utility derived by an individual at i from travel, u" is a
function of the number of trips undertaken to eacb which is simply the gravity model as formulated by
destination j, Tilt and the potential for interaction at each Koenia (amongst others) but with travel time rather than
destination. Thus generalised travel cost as the impedance measure.
Equation (12) can be rewritten as eqn (16) by sub-
stituting for ;" as follows:
u, =a~AJ'(TII) (7)
(13)
where a is a constant of proportionality, and A, is the
perceived attractiveness of j for interaction. and
A simpler prObfein statemelil-is obt8iDe&i by iDodifYins -
the constrainl term slightly 10 cover only a time con-
straint (i.e. a travel time budget):
maximise (14)
(8)
subject to _ ~/IISlJe-ul/
(9) ,,=---- (IS)
~S,e-A.I/
The logarithmic assumption leads to the result Thus the total trip generation rate is an increasing
function of the level of accessibility, although not
HA directly proportional to it as might appear from a first
TII:;:~~ (II)
I, lA, glance at eqn (l7b).
The effect of the accessibility term (.4,) is dampened
by the denominator. Thus if A, increases due to a fall in
where ;; is the average travel time for trips taken by an any or all til'S, the denominator will also increase, but not
individual at i. If one then assumes that an individual's
by as much as A" hence T, will increase at a slower rate
perception of the attractiveness of j for interaction (.4,)
than .4,. Similarly if .4, increases due to a redistribution
is the accessibility of j with respect to I as defined by
Koenia, i.e. S, e-A'ij, then of opportunities in favour of locations closer to i, the
increase in the denominator will be dampened by the I."
which is smaller, hence carries less weight, for the closer .
H. §ie-uli
T.=.....! (12) zones than it is for the more distant zones.
II ;; IS, e-Aij One consequence of Niedercom and Bechdolt's ap-
which is composed of two terms proach is that each individual has a maximum amount of
time (and/or money), which he is willing to devote to
travel. The individual will use his maximum time, except
(I) a trip generation term, (HI;'); and in the unlikely event that he is able to make aU the
interactions he desires in less time. Therefore an im-
provement in the transport system will generally nol
me fuU derivation is not reproduced here: the reader is
referred to the orisinal article (Nledercom and Bechdolt 1969). cause an individual to spend more or less time travelling.
Slight differences have been introduced here to conform with Thus each individual's travel time budget is simply
Koenig's terminology. obtained by observing his travel behaviour. i.e. the
TR-A VoL 13A, No. 2-C
104 J. M. MORRIS, P. L. DUMBLB and M. R. WIOAN
amount of time he wishes to spend travelling equals the counted for by the discrepancy in car usage; i.e. when
amount he actually travelled. time spent travelling as a car passenger (not shown) is
The average time spent travelling daily by Ballarat added to that spent driving, men still spend more time
residents was analysed for different categories of in- travelling than women in all age· groups. A· second fea-
dividuals. In doing so it was possible to establish. ture is the drop in tot81 time spent travelling by women in
amongst other things, which grouping gave the greatest the 4O-5S age bracket 'Ibis may possibly be due to
between-groups variation. The results for all individuals women in this group no longer needing to accompany
are presented below in Table I. their children on trips. They may even send their chil-
A method of stratification which showed a large dr~n on errands as they become old enough to ac-
amount of between-group variation was a combination complish these tasks by Ihemselves. These and other
sex/age grouping. One group (males, between the ages of similar observations rapidly lead one to realise that the
18 and 24 inclusive) exhibited a daily travel time budget travel demand of individuals cannot be considered in
of almost 93 min (43% above the average), while another isolation from their role in the household.
group (males, less than 10 years) exhibited a daily travel Niedercom and Bechdolt's approach, whilst retaining
time budget of only 39 min (40% below average). FIgUre the desirable feature that accessibility be considered on
8 shows the results for aU sex/age groups. Included on an individual basist also manages to dampen down, but
Fig. 8, for interest mainly, are the daily travel times not prevent the ever-increasing trip rate effect of in-
allocated to car driving and walking by residents in the creasing accessibility in Koenig's model.
various sex/age groupings. However any general deficiencies and underlying
The graph for time spent walking is quite similar in assumptions inherent in Koenig's model will still be
shape to that obtained from an analysis of a National present.
Travel Survey (NTS) of the United Kingdom by Daor
and Goodwin (1976). In particular, the small amount of The approach 0/ Cochrane
time spent walking daily by men in the age range 20 to SO The approach of Cochrane (1975) could be considered
years is observable in both Ballarat and NTS results. The almost to be begging the question in relation to his
most obvious difference between the two analyses is the treatment of accessibility and trip generation. His under-
relatively low average amount of time spent walking in· lying assumptions are very similar to Koenig's as
Ballarat; 10.5 min compared to 18. This is partly expressed by eqns (IH5), but Cochrane introduces the
explained by the method of "dominant mode" coding concept of satiation, albeit in a somewhat arbitrary
adopted in Ballarat. manner, by assuming that the demand for trips between i
Some interesting sociological influences on observed and all j by an individual, is related to a factor 0, (which
mobility are apparent in Fig. 8. For instance, the ten- is really a saturation level of trip making) as well as to
dency of men, at all age levels, to spend more time A,.
travelling than women. The difterence is more than &C- Cochrane then derives* the following expressions for
TIJ and T,:
r\
I \
CAACf!lV£A-FB.IAI.E
"\'EIWlE
CAA~ -
20._
- -
I \ - --
-1--"'\-
~,
J
':>.c-- "
A_ - ,""WALK-nwu: / '
10 WALK "Ioii:i:iiJ-{ - -',:::;'7- - - - 10
Once again, this trip generation sub-model is best veys, where trip stage and sequence tend to be ignored.
applied to relatively homogeneous groups of individuals The coding conventions themselves can cause the loss of
and can then be mode and purpose specific. An iterative critical data: the choice of a single dominant mode-
Ordinary Least Squares (OLS) procedure would typic- usually omitting the access mode-in a complex journey
ally be used to estimate G. and K. Rough estimates of G. is of special significance. Further information may be
and K were made for the results depicted in Fig. S for ignored at the analysis stage: for example undue aggre-
the City of Nice (1966): gation of purpose codings can result in significant loss of
detail within a trip sequence. Nevertheless information is
G, =4.7 (daily trips per person) retrievable by going back to the basic survey data.
and
K =0.068.
-Intttt-siago
Melbourne. The Institute of Engineers, Australia. Victoria SpeclJic Services and Regulations in Sydney. Unpublished •
Division, Transportation and Hishways Branch, 4-1 to 4-38. Ph.D. thesis. Urban Research Unit, The Australian National
Donald O. C. (1977) Health Care Delivery in Sydney, Unpub- University, Canberra.
lished Ph.D. thesis, Urban Researcb Unit, The Austra\ian Mitc:heU C. O. B. and Town S. W. (1977) Accessibility o/llarious
National University, Canberra. social groups to different act;lIities. TRRL Supplementary
Ewins O. O. (1974) Gravity and linear regression models of Report 25g, Transport and Road Research Laboratory. Crow-
spatial interaction: a cautionary note. EcollOmic Geognzphy thome, U.K.
50,8~. Morrill R. L. (1963) The distribution of migration distances.
Flowerdew A. D. J. (1976) An evaluation packll8e for a strategic Papen 01 th, Re,ional Scltnce Alloc/otion II, 75-84.
landuse transportation planning program. In Urban Trans- Morrill R. L. and Earickson R. (1968) Hospital variation and
portation Planning Conference (Edited by P. Bonsall, Q. DaJvi patient travel distances. Inquiry 5, 1-9.
IUId P. J. Hills) 161-176. Abacus Press, United Kingdom. Morris J. M. (1976) Access to community health facilities in
Freestone R. (1975) On urban resource allocation: the dis- Melbourne. POPtr3 of tile Fint Australia-New ZuJand
tn"bution of medical practitioners in Sydney. Geography Bu/- Regional Science Con/ermce, Brisbane. August 1976. 143-173.
letin 7, 14-25. Morris J. M., Dumble, P. L. and Wigan M. R. (1978) Accessibility
Gamer B. J. (1976 The etrect of local government reform on access . indicators for transport planning. Forum Papen. 4th Aus-
to public services: a case study from Denmark, Bristol Essays in tralian Transport Researcb Forum: Perth. May 1978. Director
Geography (Edited by P. Haagelt, M. Chisholm and R. Peel) General of Transport's Office, Perth, W.A.
319-338 Heinemann, London. Neuberger H. (1971) User benellt in the evaluation of transport
Gould P. (1969) Spatial Diffusion. Association of American and land use plans. J. Tran,. Econ. Policy 5(5).52-75.
Geographers Resource Paper No. 17, Commission on College Nledercorn J. H. and Bechdolt B. V. Jr. (1969) An economic
Geography, Washington, D.C. derivation of the "Gravity Law" o( spatial interation. J.
Great Britain Department of the Environment (1977) A Sillily 0/ Regional Sci. 9(2). 273-282.
Some Means of Traffic Restraint. Department of Environment Oberg S. (1976) Method, 0/ Dtscribln, Physical Access to Supply
Research Report 14, Department or Environment, London. Points. Lund Studies in Geography Series B. Human Oeo-
Hansen W. G. (1959). How accessibility shapes land-use. J. Am. grapby No. 43, Department of Geography, The Royal Uni-
IlISt. Planners 15,73-76. versity of Lund, Sweden.
HlUlson S. (1978) Urban travel linkages. Proc. 3rd Inter. ConI. OECD Road Research Programme (1977) Transport Require-
Behallioural Travel Modelling, Tanuda, South Australia. Croom ments for Urbau Communities: Planning for Personal Travel.
Helm, London. F"ma1 Report of Research Group Til. Paris Appendix D, 84-92
Harris Lange Voorhees (1971) Ballarat Transportation Stlllly. (unpublished).
Consultants Report to the Study Commiltee-Chief Planning Pallon T. and Clark N. (1970) Towards an accessibility model for
Engineer, Country Roads Board-Chairman. residential development Analysis 0/ Urban Development
Heggie I. G. (1976) Consumer Cholct and Urban Travel Dtmands (Edited by N. Clark), 266-288. (proceedinss of the Tewksbury
A RtIIlsed Theory. University o( Oxford. Transport Studies Symposium) Special Report No.5, Transport Section. Uni-
Unit. Working Paper No.4. venity of Melbourne.
Henderson J. M. and Quandt R. E. (1971) Micro-Economic Popper R. J. and Hoel L. A. (1976) Mobility evaluation (or urban
Theory: A Mathematical Approach. 2nd Edn. McGraw-Hili, public transportation. Transportotlon Plannins and Tecll-
Kogakushll. noloBY 3, 131-141.
Hensher D. A. (1976). The structure of journeys and nature of Samuelson P. A. (1971) Foundotions 0/ Economic Analysls.
. travel patterns. Environment and Planning A 8, 6S~72. Harvard University Press, Cambridge.
Hillman M, Henderson I. and Whalley A. (1973) Penonal Mobil- Sherman 1.., Barber B. and Kondo W. (1974) Method for evalu-
Ity and Transport Po/icy. Political and Economic Planning, ating metropolitan accessibility. Transportation Reseoreh
London. Record 499, 70-82.
Hillman M.. Henderson I. and Whalley A. (1976) Transport Turner C. O. (1972) A model framework (or transportation and
Rtalities and Plonnin, Policy. Political and Economic Plan- commWlity plan analysis. J. Am. Inst. Plonners 38, 325-330.
ning. London. U. D. P. A. Planners (1975) Alta Servim: Melbourne. Report
Ingram D. R. (1971) The concept of accessibility: a search for an prepared for the Australian Cities Commission by Urban
operational form. Regionol Studies 5. 101-107. Design and PlanDing Associates. Melbourne.
Jones P. M. (1976) Travel as 0 manifestation of actillity choicel: Vickerman R. W. (1974) Accessibility. attraction and potential: a
trip generation re-interpreted. University of Oxford. Transport review of some concepts and their use in determining mobility.
Studies Unit Workins Paper No. 14. Oxford. Enlliranment ond Planning A 6. 67~1.
Jones P. M. (1978) New approaches to understanding travel Wachs M. (Reporting Chairman) (1978) Report on Plenary Ses-
behaviour: the human activity approach. Proc. 3rd Inter. Con/, sion. Workshop H: Behavioural ModeUing, Accessibility,
Behavioural Travel Modelling. Tanunda, South Australia. Mobility and Travel Need. Proc. 3rd Inter. Con/, BehoDio/UQ1
Croom Helm. London. Trallel Modelling, Tanuncla, South Australia. Croom Helm,
Kaiser E. J., Butler W. W., McAllister R. J. and Thibeault R. W. London.
(1972) Some problems with accessibility standards: a com- Wachs M. and Kumagai T. G. (1973) Physical accessibility as a
parison of household preferences to standards (or work. social indicator. Socio-Economk Plannillg ScL 7,437-456.
shopping and school trips. Rtlliew of Regional Studies 3, WeibuU J. W. (1976) An axiomatic approach to the measurement
111-123. of accessibility. Regionol Science ond Urban Economics 6,
King R. (1975) Urban senicel and distributive Justice: a Sydney 351-379.
cose study. Centre for Environmental Studies Working Paper. Whitbread M. (1972) Ellaluation In the planning process-the
University of Melbourne, Melbourne. cose of accessibility. Plannins Methodology Research Unit.
Koenig G. (1977) Les indicateurs d'accessibilites dans les studes University College London., Workins Paper 10.
urbaines: de la theorie a la prac:tique. Rtllue Generale des Wickstrom G. V. (1971) Defining balanced transportation-a
Routes. July 1977 (English translation available). question of opportunity. Traffic (Jlltulerly 15, 337-349.
McFadden D. (1973) Conditional loglt analysis of qualitative Wigan M. R. (1971) Benefit IUsellmlllt lor networlc traffic models
choice behaviour. (Edited by P. Zaremka) Frantien in ond applicotion to raod priclns. TRRL Report LR 417, Trans-
Econometrics, 105-142. Academic Press, New York. port and Road Research Laboratory. Crowthome. U.K.
Mcintosh P. T. and Quarmby D. A. (1972) Generalised costs and Wigan M. R:, Bamford T. J. O. Broughton J., Paulley J. and
the estimation of movement costs and benefits in trans- Lynam M. (1974) Two scenarios for traffic restraint: the traffic
portation planning. Highway Releoreh Record 383, 11-26. social and environmental elfeets. Working paper (unpublished:
Manning I. (1972) An Economic Study of Some Location- available from the lint author at ARRB on request as: Dis-
Accessibility indicators for transport planning 109
• cussion Paper DN300). Enl1ironmenl and Planning A 9(3), 285-344.
Wigan M. R. and Richards E. (1978) The analYIi.r of journey Wilson A. G. (1971) A family of spatial interaction models, and
It",ctllrt: linkage between different stages of a journey. Aus- associated developments. Enrironment and Planning A3, 1-32.
• tralian Road Research Board Internal Report AIR 300-1. Wilson A. G. (1972) Developing issues in urban transport plan-
Wilbur Smith and Associates and Len T. Frazier and Associates ning. Memorandum in Second Report from the Expenditure
(1969) Mtlbournt Transportation StlUly, Volume I: Su""y. Committee, HCS7, Session 1972-73. Urban Transport Plan-
Melbourne Transportation Committee, Melbourne. ning 2, (HMSO, London).
Williams H. C. W. L. (1977) On the formation of travel demand Zakaria T. (1974) Urban transportation accessibili!}, measures:
models and economic evaluation measures for user beneftt. modifications and uses. Traffic Quarttrly 28, 467-479•
·.