Indifference Curve Indifference Curve
Indifference Curve Indifference Curve
Indifference Curve Indifference Curve
Indifference Curve
There are infinitely many indifference curves: one passes through each combination. A
collection of (selected) indifference curves, illustrated graphically, is referred to as an
indifference map.
Contents
[hide]
• 1 History
• 2 Map and properties of indifference curves
• 3 Assumptions of consumer preference theory
o 3.1 Application
o 3.2 Examples of indifference curves
• 4 Preference relations and utility
o 4.1 Preference relations
o 4.2 Formal link to utility theory
o 4.3 Examples
4.3.1 Linear utility
4.3.2 Cobb-Douglas utility
4.3.3 CES utility
• 5 See also
• 6 Footnotes
• 7 Notes
• 8 References
• 9 External links
[edit] History
The theory of indifference curves was developed by Francis Ysidro Edgeworth, Vilfredo
Pareto and others in the first part of the 20th century. The theory can be derived from
ordinal utility theory, which posits that individuals can always rank any consumption
bundles by order of preference.
[edit] Map and properties of indifference curves
An example of how indifference curves are obtained as the level curves of a utility
function
[edit] Application
To maximise utility, a household should consume at (Qx, Qy). Assuming it does, a full
demand schedule can be deduced as the price of one good fluctuates.
Consumer theory uses indifference curves and budget constraints to generate consumer
demand curves. For a single consumer, this is a relatively simple process. First, let one
good be an example market e.g. carrots, and let the other be a composite of all other
goods. Budget constraints gives a straight line on the indifference map showing all the
possible distributions between the two goods; the point of maximum utility is then the
point at which an indifference curve is tangent to the budget line (illustrated). This
follows from common sense: if the market values a good more than the household, the
household will sell it; if the market values a good less than the household, the household
will buy it. The process then continues until the market's and household's marginal rates
of substitution are equal.[7] Now, if the price of carrots were to change, and the price of all
other goods were to remain constant, the gradient of the budget line would also change,
leading to a different point of tangency and a different quantity demanded. These price /
quantity combinations can then be used to deduce a full demand curve.[8]
In Figure 1, the consumer would rather be on I3 than I2, and would rather be on I2 than I1,
but does not care where he/she is on a given indifference curve. The slope of an
indifference curve (in absolute value), known by economists as the marginal rate of
substitution, shows the rate at which consumers are willing to give up one good in
exchange for more of the other good. For most goods the marginal rate of substitution is
not constant so their indifference curves are curved. The curves are convex to the origin,
describing the negative substitution effect. As price rises for a fixed money income, the
consumer seeks less the expensive substitute at a lower indifference curve. The
substitution effect is reinforced through the income effect of lower real income (Beattie-
LaFrance). An example of a utility function that generates indifference curves of this kind
is the Cobb-Douglas function . The negative slope of the
indifference curve incorporates the willingness of the consumer to means to make trade
offs.[9]
If two goods are perfect substitutes then the indifference curves will have a constant slope
since the consumer would be willing to switch between at a fixed ratio. The marginal rate
of substitution between perfect substitutes is likewise constant. An example of a utility
function that is associated with indifference curves like these would be .
If two goods are perfect complements then the indifference curves will be L-shaped.
Examples of perfect complements include left shoes compared to right shoes: the
consumer is no better off having several right shoes if she has only one left shoe -
additional right shoes have zero marginal utility without more left shoes, so bundles of
goods differing only in the number of right shoes they includes - however many - are
equally preferred. The marginal rate of substitution is either zero or infinite. An example
of the type of utility function that has an indifference map like that above is
.
The different shapes of the curves imply different responses to a change in price as
shown from demand analysis in consumer theory. The results will only be stated here. A
price-budget-line change that kept a consumer in equilibrium on the same indifference
curve:
In the language of the example above, the set is made of combinations of apples and
bananas. The symbol is one such combination, such as 1 apple and 4 bananas and is
another combination such as 2 apples and 2 bananas.
The statement
is described as ' is weakly preferred to .' That is, is at least as good as (in preference
satisfaction).
The statement
is described as ' is weakly preferred to , and is weakly preferred to .' That is, one is
indifferent to the choice of or , meaning not that they are unwanted but that they are
equally good in satisfying preferences.
The statement
is described as ' is weakly preferred to , but is not weakly preferred to .' One says
that ' is strictly preferred to .'
The preference relation is complete if all pairs can be ranked. The relation is a
transitive relation if whenever and then .
Consider a particular element of the set , such as . Suppose one builds the list of all
other elements of which are indifferent, in the eyes of the consumer, to . Denote the
first element in this list by , the second by and so on... The set forms
an indifference curve since for all .
In the example above, an element of the set is made of two numbers: The number of
apples, call it and the number of bananas, call it
In utility theory, the utility function of an agent is a function that ranks all pairs of
consumption bundles by order of preference (completeness) such that any set of three or
more bundles forms a transitive relation. This means that for each bundle there is a
unique relation, , representing the utility (satisfaction) relation associated with
. The relation is called the utility function. The range of the
function is a set of real numbers. The actual values of the function have no importance.
Only the ranking of those values has content for the theory. More precisely, if
, then the bundle is described as at least as good as the
bundle . If , the bundle is described as strictly
preferred to the bundle .
Consider a particular bundle and take the total derivative of about this
point:
(Eq. 1)
The indifference curve through must deliver at each bundle on the curve the
same utility level as bundle . That is, when preferences are represented by a
utility function, the indifference curves are the level curves of the utility function.
Therefore, if one is to change the quantity of by , without moving off the
indifference curve, one must also change the quantity of by an amount such that, in
the end, there is no change in U:
Thus, the ratio of marginal utilities gives the absolute value of the slope of the
indifference curve at point . This ratio is called the marginal rate of substitution
between and .
[edit] Examples
[edit] Linear utility
Observe that the slope does not depend on or : the indifference curves are straight
lines.
and