Taxation
Taxation
Taxation
Purposes of taxation
During the 19th century the prevalent idea was that taxes should serve mainly to finance
the government. In earlier times, and again today, governments have utilized taxation for other
than merely fiscal purposes. One useful way to view the purpose of taxation, attributable to
American economist Richard A. Musgrave, is to distinguish between objectives of resource
allocation, income redistribution, and economic stability. (Economic growth or development and
international competitiveness are sometimes listed as separate goals, but they can generally be
subsumed under the other three.) In the absence of a strong reason for interference, such as the
need to reduce pollution, the first objective, resource allocation, is furthered if tax policy does
not interfere with market-determined allocations. The second objective, income redistribution, is
meant to lessen inequalities in the distribution of income and wealth. The objective of
stabilization—implemented through tax policy, government expenditure policy, monetary policy,
and debt management—is that of maintaining high employment and price stability.
There are likely to be conflicts among these three objectives. For example, resource
allocation might require changes in the level or composition (or both) of taxes, but those changes
might bear heavily on low-income families—thus upsetting redistributive goals. As another
example, taxes that are highly redistributive may conflict with the efficient allocation of
resources required to achieve the goal of economic neutrality.
Classes of taxes
Direct and indirect taxes
In the literature of public finance, taxes have been classified in various ways according to
who pays for them, who bears the ultimate burden of them, the extent to which the burden can be
shifted, and various other criteria. Taxes are most commonly classified as either direct or
indirect, an example of the former type being the income tax and of the latter the sales tax. There
is much disagreement among economists as to the criteria for distinguishing between direct and
indirect taxes, and it is unclear into which category certain taxes, such as corporate income tax or
property tax, should fall. It is usually said that a direct tax is one that cannot be shifted by the
taxpayer to someone else, whereas an indirect tax can be.
Direct taxes
Direct taxes are primarily taxes on natural persons (e.g., individuals), and they are
typically based on the taxpayer's ability to pay as measured by income, consumption, or net
wealth. What follows is a description of the main types of direct taxes.
Individual income taxes are commonly levied on total personal net income of the
taxpayer (which may be an individual, a couple, or a family) in excess of some stipulated
minimum. They are also commonly adjusted to take into account the circumstances influencing
the ability to pay, such as family status, number and age of children, and financial burdens
resulting from illness. The taxes are often levied at graduated rates, meaning that the rates rise as
income rises. Personal exemptions for the taxpayer and family can create a range of income that
is subject to a tax rate of zero.
Taxes on net worth are levied on the total net worth of a person—that is, the value of his
assets minus his liabilities. As with the income tax, the personal circumstances of the taxpayer
can be taken into consideration.
Personal or direct taxes on consumption (also known as expenditure taxes or spending
taxes) are essentially levied on all income that is not channeled into savings. In contrast to
indirect taxes on spending, such as the sales tax, a direct consumption tax can be adjusted to an
individual's ability to pay by allowing for marital status, age, number of dependents, and so on.
Although long attractive to theorists, this form of tax has been used in only two countries, India
and Sri Lanka; both instances were brief and unsuccessful. Near the end of the 20th century, the
“flat tax”—which achieves economic effects similar to those of the direct consumption tax by
exempting most income from capital—came to be viewed favourably by tax experts. No country
has adopted a tax with the base of the flat tax, although many have income taxes with only one
rate.
Taxes at death take two forms: the inheritance tax, where the taxable object is the bequest
received by the person inheriting, and the estate tax, where the object is the total estate left by the
deceased. Inheritance taxes sometimes take into account the personal circumstances of the
taxpayer, such as the taxpayer's relationship to the donor and his net worth before receiving the
bequest. Estate taxes, however, are generally graduated according to the size of the estate, and in
some countries they provide tax-exempt transfers to the spouse and make an allowance for the
number of heirs involved. In order to prevent the death duties from being circumvented through
an exchange of property prior to death, tax systems may include a tax on gifts above a certain
threshold made between living persons (see gift tax). Taxes on transfers do not ordinarily yield
much revenue, if only because large tax payments can be easily avoided through estate planning.
Indirect taxes
Indirect taxes are levied on the production or consumption of goods and services or on
transactions, including imports and exports. Examples include general and selective sales taxes,
value-added taxes (VAT), taxes on any aspect of manufacturing or production, taxes on legal
transactions, and customs or import duties.
General sales taxes are levies that are applied to a substantial portion of consumer
expenditures. The same tax rate can be applied to all taxed items, or different items (such as food
or clothing) can be subject to different rates. Single-stage taxes can be collected at the retail
level, as the U.S. states do, or they can be collected at a pre-retail (i.e., manufacturing or
wholesale) level, as occurs in some developing countries. Multistage taxes are applied at each
stage in the production-distribution process. The VAT, which increased in popularity during the
second half of the 20th century, is commonly collected by allowing the taxpayer to deduct a
credit for tax paid on purchases from liability on sales. The VAT has largely replaced the
turnover tax—a tax on each stage of the production and distribution chain, with no relief for tax
paid at previous stages. The cumulative effect of the turnover tax, commonly known as tax
cascading, distorts economic decisions.
Although they are generally applied to a wide range of products, sales taxes sometimes
exempt necessities to reduce the tax burden of low-income households. By comparison, excises
are levied only on particular commodities or services. While some countries impose excises and
customs duties on almost everything—from necessities such as bread, meat, and salt, to
nonessentials such as cigarettes, wine, liquor, coffee, and tea, to luxuries such as jewels and furs
—taxes on a limited group of products—alcoholic beverages, tobacco products, and motor fuel
—yield the bulk of excise revenues for most countries. In earlier centuries, taxes on consumer
durables were applied to luxury commodities such as pianos, saddle horses, carriages, and
billiard tables. Today a main luxury tax object is the automobile, largely because registration
requirements facilitate administration of the tax. Some countries tax gambling, and state-run
lotteries have effects similar to excises, with the government's “take” being, in effect, a tax on
gambling. Some countries impose taxes on raw materials, intermediate goods (e.g., mineral oil,
alcohol), and machinery.
Some excises and customs duties are specific—i.e., they are levied on the basis of
number, weight, length, volume, or other specific characteristics of the good or service being
taxed. Other excises, like sales taxes, are ad valorem—levied on the value of the goods as
measured by the price. Taxes on legal transactions are levied on the issue of shares, on the sale
(or transfer) of houses and land, and on stock exchange transactions. For administrative reasons,
they frequently take the form of stamp duties; that is, the legal or commercial document is
stamped to denote payment of the tax. Many tax analysts regard stamp taxes as nuisance taxes;
they are most often found in less-developed countries and frequently bog down the transactions
to which they are applied.
History of taxation
Administration of taxation
Although views on what is appropriate in tax policy influence the choice and structure of
tax codes, patterns of taxation throughout history can be explained largely by administrative
considerations. For example, because imported products are easier to tax than domestic output,
import duties were among the earliest taxes. Similarly, the simple turnover tax (levied on gross
sales) long held sway before the invention of the economically superior but administratively
more demanding VAT (which allows credit for tax paid on purchases). It is easier to identify,
and thus tax, real property than other assets; and a head (poll) tax is even easier to implement. It
is not surprising, therefore, that the first direct levies were head and land taxes.
Although taxation has a long history, it played a relatively minor role in the ancient
world. Taxes on consumption were levied in Greece and Rome. Tariffs—taxes on imported
goods—were often of considerably more importance than internal excises so far as the
production of revenue went. As a means of raising additional funds in time of war, taxes on
property would be temporarily imposed. For a long time these taxes were confined to real
property, but later they were extended to other assets. Real estate transactions also were taxed. In
Greece free citizens had different tax obligations from slaves, and the tax laws of the Roman
Empire distinguished between nationals and residents of conquered territories.
Early Roman forms of taxation included consumption taxes, customs duties, and certain
“direct” taxes. The principal of these was the tributum, paid by citizens and usually levied as a
head tax; later, when additional revenue was required, the base of this tax was extended to real
estate holdings. In the time of Julius Caesar, a 1 percent general sales tax was introduced
(centesima rerum venalium). The provinces relied for their revenues on head taxes and land
taxes; the latter consisted initially of fixed liabilities regardless of the return from the land, as in
Persia and Egypt, but later the land tax was modified to achieve a certain correspondence with
the fertility of the land, or, alternatively, a 10th of the produce was collected as a tax in kind (the
tithe). It is noteworthy that at a relatively early time Rome had an inheritance tax of 5 percent,
later 10 percent; however, close relatives of the deceased were exempted. For a long time tax
collection was left to middlemen, or “tax farmers,” who contracted to collect the taxes for a share
of the proceeds; under Caesar collection was delegated to civil servants.
In the Middle Ages many of these ancient taxes, especially the direct levies, gave way to
a variety of obligatory services and a system of “aids” (most of which amounted to gifts). The
main indirect taxes were transit duties (a charge on goods that pass through a particular country)
and market fees. In the cities the concept developed of a tax obligation encompassing all
residents: the burden of taxes on certain foods and beverages was intended to be borne partly by
consumers and partly by producers and tradesmen. During the later Middle Ages some German
and Italian cities introduced several direct taxes: head taxes for the poor and net-worth taxes or,
occasionally, crude income taxes for the rich. (The income tax was administered through self-
assessment and an oath taken before a civic commission.) Taxes on land and on houses gradually
increased.
Taxes have been a major subject of political controversy throughout history, even before
they constituted a sizable share of the national income. A famous instance is the rebellion of the
American colonies against Great Britain, when the colonists refused to pay taxes imposed by a
Parliament in which they had no voice—hence the slogan, “No taxation without representation.”
Another instance is the French Revolution of 1789, in which the inequitable distribution of the
tax burden was a major factor.
Wars have influenced taxes much more than taxes have influenced revolutions. Many
taxes, notably the income tax (first introduced in Great Britain in 1799) and the turnover or
purchase tax (Germany, 1918; Great Britain, 1940), began as “temporary” war measures.
Similarly, the withholding method of income tax collection began as a wartime innovation in
France, the United States, and Britain. World War II converted the income taxes of many
countries from upper-class taxes to mass taxes.
It is hardly necessary to mention the role that tax policies play in peacetime politics,
where the influence of powerful, well-organized pressure groups is great. Arguments for tax
reform, particularly in the area of income taxes, are perennially at issue in the domestic politics
of many countries.
Modern trends
The development of taxation in recent times can be summarized by the following general
statements, although allowance must be made for considerable national differences: The
authority of the sovereign to levy taxes in a more or less arbitrary fashion has been lost, and the
power to tax now generally resides in parliamentary bodies. The level of most taxes has risen
substantially and so has the ratio of tax revenues to the national income. Taxes today are
collected in money, not in goods. Tax farming—the collection of taxes by outside contractors—
has been abolished, and taxes are instead assessed and collected by civil servants. (On the other
hand, as a means of overcoming the inefficiencies of government agencies, tax collection has
recently been contracted to banks in many less-developed countries. In addition, some countries
are outsourcing the administration of customs duties.)
There has also been a reduction in reliance on customs duties and excises. Many
countries increasingly rely on sales taxes and other general consumption taxes. An important late
20th-century development was the replacement of turnover taxes with value-added taxes. Taxes
on the privilege of doing business and on real property lost ground, although they have persisted
as important revenue sources for local communities. The absolute and relative weight of direct
personal taxation has been growing in most of the developed countries, and increasing attention
has been focused on VAT and payroll taxes. At the end of the 20th century the expansion of e-
commerce created serious challenges for the administration of VAT, income taxes, and sales
taxes. The problems of tax administration were compounded by the anonymity of buyers and
sellers, the possibility of conducting business from offshore tax havens, the fact that tax
authorities cannot monitor the flow of digitized products or intellectual property, and the spate of
untraceable money flows.
Income taxation (of individuals and of corporations), payroll taxes, general sales taxes,
and (in some countries) property taxes bring in the greatest amounts of revenue in modern tax
systems. The income tax has ceased to be a “rich man's” tax; it is now paid by the general
populace, and in several countries it is joined by a tax on net worth. The emphasis on the ability-
to-pay principle and on the redistribution of wealth—which led to graduated rates and high top
marginal income tax rates—appears to have peaked, having been replaced by greater concern for
the economic distortions and disincentives caused by high tax rates. A good deal of fiscal
centralization occurred through much of the 20th century, as reflected in the kinds of taxes levied
by central governments. They now control the most important taxes (from a revenue-producing
point of view): income and corporation taxes, payroll taxes, and value-added taxes. Yet, in the
last decade of the 20th century, many countries experienced a greater decentralization of
government and a consequent devolution of taxing powers to subnational governments.
Proponents of decentralization argue that it can contribute to greater fiscal autonomy and
responsibility, because it involves states and municipalities in the broader processes of tax
policy; merely allowing lower-level governments to share in the tax revenues of central
governments does not foster such autonomy.
Although it is difficult to make general distinctions between developed and less-
developed countries, it is possible to detect some patterns in their relative reliance on various
types of taxes. For example, developed countries usually rely more on individual income taxes
and less on corporate income taxes than less-developed countries do. In developing countries,
reliance on income taxes, especially on corporate income taxes, generally increases as the level
of income rises. In addition, a relatively high percentage of the total tax revenue of industrialized
countries comes from domestic consumption taxes, especially the value-added tax (rather than
the simpler turnover tax). Social security taxes—commonly collected as payroll taxes—are much
more important in developed countries and the more-affluent developing countries than in the
poorest countries, reflecting the near lack of social security systems in the latter. Indeed, in many
developed countries, payroll taxes rival or surpass the individual income tax as a source of
revenue. Demographic trends and their consequences (in particular, the aging of the world's
working population and the need to finance public pensions) threaten to raise payroll taxes to
increasingly steep levels. Some countries have responded by privatizing the provision of
pensions—e.g., by substituting mandatory contributions to individual accounts for payroll taxes.
Taxes in general represent a much higher percentage of national output in developed
countries than in developing countries. Similarly, more national output is channeled to
governmental use through taxation in developing countries with the highest levels of income
than in those with lesser incomes. Indeed, in many respects the tax systems of the developing
countries with the highest levels of income have more in common with those of developed
countries than they have with the tax systems of the poorest developing countries.
Principles of taxation
Adam Smith, paste medallion by James Tassie, 1787; in the Scottish National Portrait
Gallery, …
The 18th-century economist and philosopher Adam Smith attempted to systematize the rules
that should govern a rational system of taxation. In The Wealth of Nations (Book V, chapter 2)
he set down four general canons:
I. The subjects of every state ought to contribute towards the support of the government, as
nearly as possible, in proportion to their respective abilities; that is, in proportion to the revenue
which they respectively enjoy under the protection of the state.…
II. The tax which each individual is bound to pay ought to be certain, and not arbitrary. The time
of payment, the manner of payment, the quantity to be paid, ought all to be clear and plain to the
contributor, and to every other person.…
III. Every tax ought to be levied at the time, or in the manner, in which it is most likely to be
convenient for the contributor to pay it.…
IV. Every tax ought to be so contrived as both to take out and keep out of the pockets of the
people as little as possible over and above what it brings into the public treasury of the state.…
Although they need to be reinterpreted from time to time, these principles retain remarkable
relevance. From the first can be derived some leading views about what is fair in the distribution
of tax burdens among taxpayers. These are: (1) the belief that taxes should be based on the
individual's ability to pay, known as the ability-to-pay principle, and (2) the benefit principle, the
idea that there should be some equivalence between what the individual pays and the benefits he
subsequently receives from governmental activities. The fourth of Smith's canons can be
interpreted to underlie the emphasis many economists place on a tax system that does not
interfere with market decision making, as well as the more obvious need to avoid complexity and
corruption.
Horizontal equity
The principle of horizontal equity assumes that persons in the same or similar positions
(so far as tax purposes are concerned) will be subject to the same tax liability. In practice this
equality principle is often disregarded, both intentionally and unintentionally. Intentional
violations are usually motivated more by politics than by sound economic policy (e.g., the tax
advantages granted to farmers, home owners, or members of the middle class in general; the
exclusion of interest on government securities). Debate over tax reform has often centred on
whether deviations from “equal treatment of equals” are justified.
Economic efficiency
The requirement that a tax system be efficient arises from the nature of a market
economy. Although there are many examples to the contrary, economists generally believe that
markets do a fairly good job in making economic decisions about such choices as consumption,
production, and financing. Thus, they feel that tax policy should generally refrain from
interfering with the market's allocation of economic resources. That is, taxation should entail a
minimum of interference with individual decisions. It should not discriminate in favour of, or
against, particular consumption expenditures, particular means of production, particular forms of
organization, or particular industries. This does not mean, of course, that major social and
economic goals may not take precedence over these considerations. It may be desirable, for
example, to impose taxes on pollution as a means of protecting the environment.
Economists have developed techniques to measure the “excess burden” that results when
taxes distort economic decision making. The basic notion is that if goods worth $2 are sacrificed
because of tax influences in order to produce goods with a value of only $1.80, there is an excess
burden of 20 cents. A more nearly neutral tax system would result in less distortion. Thus, an
important postwar development in the theory of taxation is that of optimal taxation, the
determination of tax policies that will minimize excess burdens. Because it deals with highly
stylized mathematical descriptions of economic systems, this theory does not offer easily applied
prescriptions for policy, beyond the important insight that distortions do less damage where
supply and demand are not highly sensitive to such distortions. Attempts have also been made to
incorporate distributional considerations into this theory. They face the difficulty that there is no
scientifically correct distribution of income.
Clarity
Tax laws and regulations must be comprehensible to the taxpayer; they must be as simple
as possible (given other goals of tax policy) as well as unambiguous and certain—both to the
taxpayer and to the tax administrator. While the principle of certainty is better adhered to today
than in the time of Adam Smith, and arbitrary administration of taxes has been reduced, every
country has tax laws that are far from being generally understood by the public. This not only
results in a considerable amount of error but also undermines honesty and respect for the law and
tends to discriminate against the ignorant and the poor, who cannot take advantage of the various
legal tax-saving opportunities that are available to the educated and the affluent. At times,
attempts to achieve equity have created complexity, defeating reform purposes.
Stability
Tax laws should be changed seldom, and, when changes are made, they should be carried
out in the context of a general and systematic tax reform, with adequate provisions for fair and
orderly transition. Frequent changes to tax laws can result in reduced compliance or in behaviour
that attempts to compensate for probable future changes in the tax code—such as stockpiling
liquor in advance of an increased tariff on alcoholic beverages.
Cost-effectiveness
The costs of assessing, collecting, and controlling taxes should be kept to the lowest level
consistent with other goals of taxation. This principle is of secondary importance in developed
countries, but not in developing countries and countries in transition from socialism, where
resources needed for compliance and administration are scarce. Clearly, equity and economic
rationality should not be sacrificed for the sake of cost considerations. The costs to be minimized
include not only government expenses but also those of the taxpayer and of private fiscal agents
such as employers who collect taxes for the government through the withholding procedure.
Convenience
Payment of taxes should cause taxpayers as little inconvenience as possible, subject to the
limitations of higher-ranking tax principles. Governments often allow the payment of large tax
liabilities in installments and set generous time limits for completing returns.
Economic goals
The primary goal of a national tax system is to generate revenues to pay for the
expenditures of government at all levels. Because public expenditures tend to grow at least as
fast as the national product, taxes, as the main vehicle of government finance, should produce
revenues that grow correspondingly. Income, sales, and value-added taxes generally meet this
criterion; property taxes and taxes on nonessential articles of mass consumption such as tobacco
products and alcoholic beverages do not.
In addition to producing revenue, tax policy may be used to promote economic stability.
Changes in tax liabilities not matched by changes in expenditures cushion cyclical fluctuations in
prices, employment, and production. Built-in flexibility occurs because liabilities for some taxes,
most notably income taxes, respond strongly to changes in economic conditions. A more-active
approach calls for changes in the tax rates or other provisions to increase the anticyclical effects
of tax receipts.
Some economists propose tax policies to promote economic growth. This approach may
imply a qualitative restructuring of the tax system (for example, the substitution of taxes on
consumption for taxes on income) or special tax advantages to stimulate saving, labour mobility,
research and development, and so on. There is, however, a limit to what tax incentives can
accomplish, especially in promoting economic development of specific industries or regions. An
emphasis on economic growth implies the need to avoid high marginal tax rates and the tax-
induced diversion of resources into relatively unproductive activities.
A REASEARCH PAPER-TAXATION:
A REQUIREMENT TO THE SUBJECT BASIC
ECONOMICS AND TAXATION
SUBMITTED TO:
DR. ANECITO ARENDAIN
SUBMITTED BY:
MARK ANTHONY C. UMALI
#30 Holy Spirit Drive, Judge Puno Bldg., Quezon City Philipines
March 07, 2015