LAND POLICY AND FARM EFFICIENCY: THE LESSONS OF MOLDOVA
Dragos CIMPOIES
Faculty of Economics
The State Agricultural University of Moldova, Chisinău, Moldova
dcimpoies@uasm.md
Zvi LERMAN
Department of Agricultural Economics and Management,
The Hebrew University, Rehovot, Israel
lerman@agri.huji.ac.il
Plenary paper prepared for presentation at the joint IAAE - 104th EAAE Seminar
Agricultural Economics and Transition:
„What was expected, what we observed,
the lessons learned."
Corvinus University of Budapest (CUB)
Budapest, Hungary. September 6-8, 2007
Copyright 2007 by Dragos Cimpoies and Zvi Lerman. All rights reserved. Readers may make
verbatim copies of this document for non-commercial purposes by any means, provided that this
copyright notice appears on all such copies.
1
INTRODUCTION
Since 1991, Moldova has carried out a wide range of radical reforms affecting its social and
economic system. The reforms have been aimed at the creation of political, legal and economic
foundations for a market economy based predominantly on the private sector. Within this general
framework, agrarian reform proceeded in the following main directions:
-
Mass privatization of agricultural land, culminating in physical distribution of land plots
and issue of land titles to individual owners;
-
Transformation of traditional collective and state farms into new forms of marketoriented organizations.
Over 1 million residents became landowners as a result of this process, which ended between
1998 and 2000. Many of them used their privately owned land to establish independent family
farms, while others entrusted their land to managers of newly created corporate farms
(partnerships, limited liability companies, agricultural cooperatives, joint stock companies, etc.).
As of today, 50% of agricultural land in Moldova is used by individual producers. This is in stark
contrast to the pre-reform situation, when individuals cultivated only 2% of agricultural land.
Meanwhile, the progress in land privatization does not led to the individualization of agriculture.
Half of agricultural land in Moldova is farmed by the corporate sector. Although this is a positive
result, comparing with other transition countries like Russia and Ukraine, it is far from being
satisfactory, while compared with market economies, where the share of corporate farms in the
total area of agricultural land is much smaller.
One of the main features of the Moldovan agriculture is its structural duality, expressed by the
existence of a reduced number of large corporate farms - at one pole, and a large number of
small and very small peasant (family) farms and rural households – at another one. Almost do
not exist the so-called “medium-sized” family farms, the main organization form in market
economies’ agriculture. At the same time, the relationship between the organization form and
farm size is not always the same. Usually, family farms are small farms, but some of them fall in
the category of large farms. A similar picture is observed with corporate farms, which are
typically large, but not all of them. Therefore, the structural duality in agriculture in transition
will be analyzed in two dimensions: the organizational form dimension and the farm size
dimension.
2
INDIVIDUAL VERSUS CORPORATE FARMS
The emergence of two well-defined categories of organizational forms as a result of the postsocialist land and farm structure reforms has triggered an ongoing debate among policy makers
and economists concerning the efficiency and performance advantages of corporate farms versus
individual farms in transition countries. The traditional socialist thinking believed in economies
of scale and thus gave preference to large corporate farms. The Western market-oriented
thinking attaches more importance to individual incentives and thus emphasizes the advantages
of smaller family farms. GORTON and DAVIDOVA (2004) note that, contrary to prior expectations,
there is no clear-cut empirical evidence in transition economies that family farms are more
efficient than corporate farms in all farming activities. While significant differences have been
found in favor of family farms against the average corporate farm, the best corporate farms still
tend to perform as well as the best family farms. Yet these findings clearly support the previous
conclusion (LERMAN et al., 2004) that, contrary to the economies-of-scale school of thought,
large corporate farms do not have a significant performance advantage over individual farms.
We use national statistics and survey data to examine the comparative performance of individual
and corporate farms in Moldova.
Figure 1:
Increasing role of individual sector
1
Gross Agricultural Product
Agricultural land
100%
100%
90%
Corporate
Farms
80%
80%
70%
60%
Corporate
Farms
60%
50%
40%
40%
Individual
Farms
30%
20%
20%
Individual
Farms
10%
20
06
20
04
20
02
20
00
19
98
19
96
19
94
19
92
19
90
20
06
20
04
20
02
20
00
19
98
19
96
19
94
0%
19
92
19
90
0%
Source: Statistical Yearbooks of Moldova of various years;
State Cadastre, end of year data
The shift of agricultural land from corporate to individual farms has led to significant changes in
the production structure of Moldovan agriculture: the output of the corporate farm sector
decreased, while the output of the individual sector shows a steady growth. At the beginning of
agricultural reforms in the early 1990s, the individual sector was producing 20% of agricultural
output on less than 10% of agricultural land; in 2003 individual farms produce three-quarters of
agricultural output on half the agricultural land (Figure 1). The discrepant shares of the two farm
sectors in land and output clearly show that the individual farms use their land more productively
than the corporate farms. This phenomenon has persisted since 1990, as the share of individual
output has always been greater than the share of land in individual tenure.
The partial productivities of land and labour decreased over time in both corporate and
individual farms, and the results are summarized in next figure as averages for the entire period
1990-2003 and for two subperiods.
The land productivity of individual farms is statistically significantly higher than that of
corporate farms. The difference in labor productivity, on the other hand, is not statistically
significant, although the mean for the entire period 1990-2003 is observed to be higher for
individual farms (Figure 2). In other transition countries we also observe that the productivity of
land is higher for individual farms, but the productivity of labor is actually higher for corporate
farms. For Moldova, the labor productivity of corporate farms is indeed higher in the later
subperiod 1997-2003, but again the difference is not statistically significant. Thus, the two
partial productivity measures for land and labour do not give a consistent picture: while land
productivity is definitely higher for individual farms, the results for labor productivity are
ambiguous. To resolve the ambiguity, we have to calculate a measure of Total Factor
Productivity (TFP).
Figure 2:
20
Agriculture land and labour productivity for corporate and individual farms
'000 lei/ha (2000 prices)
35
'000 lei/worker (2000 prices)
30
15
25
Corporate
Individual
10
Corporate
Individual
15
10
5
2
0
1990
20
1992
1994
1996
1998
2000
2002
5
0
1990
1992
1994
1996
1998
2000
2002
a) Agricultural land productivity
b) Labour productivity
In the absence of market prices for valuing the cost of inputs (such as the price of land), TFP is
usually determined by estimating a production function and then using the estimated input
coefficients as the weights to calculate the value of the bundle of inputs. From considerations of
data reliability, we have decided to calculate production functions using two inputs only: land
and labour.
A qualitative picture of TFP changes over time was obtained from national statistics by assuming
a conventional Cobb-Douglas production function with stylized factor shares of 0.7 for land and
0.3 for labour (these are the factor shares that we consistently obtained in production functions
estimated using various farm surveys in Moldova). Next figure presents the TFP results
calculated with these land and labour weights using the full time series. The TFP for individual
farms is higher than for corporate farms over the entire period 1990-2003. The respective means
for 1990-2003 are 11.5 for individual farms and 4.4 for corporate farms (the difference is
statistically significant).
Figure 3:
Total factor productivity for individual and corporate farms 1990-2003
Notes: Inputs from national statistics (see Table 2) aggregated using hypothetical factor shares of 0.7 to land and
0.3 to labour.
The TFP results in Figure 3 are derived by production-function methodology using national
statistics and they reflect Total Factor Productivity in a sectoral perspective. A different
methodology can be used to estimate the efficiency of specific farms from survey data (at a point
in time). The efficiency of input use for a particular farm is measured in relation to the
production frontier, which is the locus of “best attainable” points, i.e., points where the
maximum output is achieved for every given bundle of inputs. Once the production frontier has
been constructed, we can calculate the technical efficiency of each farm by measuring its relative
distance from the frontier. Points on the frontier are technically efficient; their distance from the
frontier is 0, and their technical efficiency (TE) score is 1. As the distance of a particular point
from the frontier increases, its TE score decreases. Each TE score is the fraction of the “best
performer” output that a given farm achieves with the same bundle of inputs.
Next presents the mean TE scores obtained for farms of different types in two samples from
2003 surveys in Moldova.1 While all farms surveyed are relatively inefficient (compared to the
efficiency benchmark of TE = 1), individual farms achieve higher TE scores than corporate
25
lei output per unit aggregated inputs
20
15
Individual
Corporate
10
5
0
1990
1992
1994
1996
1998
2000
2002
farms (the difference is statistically significant in both samples). This indicates that the
individual farms on average utilize the two inputs (land and labour) more efficiently than the
corporate farms: for any given bundle of inputs, they produce on average more than the
1
The TE scores were derived by Stochastic Frontier Analysis (SFA), an econometric production frontier technique
that is conceptually close to production function estimation. For details, see COELLI et al. (2005).
3
corporate farms. These results are consistent with the TFP results: individual farms are more
productive and more efficient than corporate farms.
Table 1:
TE scores obtained by Stochastic Frontier Analysis (SFA)
WB 2003 survey
(n = 198)
0.46a (n = 22)
0.64a (n = 176)
Corporate
Individual
Notes:
a
b
WB 2003 survey pooled with
PFAP 2003 corporate farm
survey (n = 719)
0.67b (n = 543)
0.70b (n = 176)
Difference statistically significant at p = 0.10 by parametric and nonparametric tests.
Difference statistically significant at p = 0.10 by nonparametric test only.
Source: Authors’ calculations based on DUDWICK et al. (2005) for WB 2003 survey; MURAVSCHI and BUCATA
(2005) for PFAP 2003 survey.
3
LARGE VERSUS SMALL FARMS
The second dimension of farm-structure duality involves farm sizes – large versus small. The
optimum farm size is difficult to define because opinions about the farmers’ objective function
differ and because the same determinants can affect farm size in different ways across different
farms or countries (KOESTER, 2003). The optimality of farm size for a given country is largely an
empirical question (SWINNEN, 2006). In general, the optimal farm size is a relative notion that
depends on the local conditions, such as the share of rural population and the land endowment.
In the absence of a universal optimum, average farm sizes can be meaningfully compared only
for countries with similar natural conditions. In this context, an appropriate benchmark for
Moldova is provided by the relatively densely populated and land-poor European countries, such
as Portugal, Greece, and Italy. These three countries actually have the smallest family farms
among the EU-15 – 5-10 hectares, compared with an average farm size of around 20 hectares for
EU-15 as a group (Eurostat data from EUROPEAN COMMISSION (2005)). The family farms in
Portugal, Greece, and Italy are thus not dramatically larger than the average peasant farm in
Moldova (2 hectares national average, 4-5 hectares in various surveys – see Table 5), but they
are certainly much smaller than the average corporate farm in Moldova.
Next table presents the size characteristics and the partial productivity measures for small and
large farms in four recent surveys in Moldova. While the large farms as a group are substantially
larger than the small farms by all measures – output, land, and labour, the partial productivities
show a mixed picture:
• The partial productivity of land (output per hectare) is higher for small farms.
• The partial productivity of labour (output per worker) is lower for small farms.
• The number of workers per hectare is much higher in small individual farms than in large
corporate farms (the “labour sink” effect of individual farms).
Table 2:
Size characteristics and productivity measures for small and large farms
in Moldova: survey data
WB 2003 survey
Number of
observations
Ag land (ha)
Workers
Ag output (‘000 lei)
PFAP 2003 surveys
WB 2000 baseline
survey
Small
Large
farms
farms
Small
farms
Large
farms
Small
farms
Large
farms
176
22
1,166
521
170
180
4.48
4.51
25.8
971
332
3,230
4.02
6.27
25.3
918
150
2,038
5.7
1.6
75.4
533
43.7
1,642
4
Output/ha (lei)
Output/worker (lei)
TFP
Workers/ha
Note:
6,765
6,857
6,426
1.42
2,745
17,135
4,745
0.26
9,535
5,145
7,424
3.25
2,085
17,824
3,464
0.19
6,414
55,304
8,420
3,145
54,393
4,010
All differences between small and large farms are statistically significant at p = 0.1 (except the differences
in productivity of labour – output/worker – in the WB 2000 survey).
Source: DUDWICK et al. (2005) for WB 2003 survey; MURAVSCHI and BUCATA (2005) for
LERMAN (2001) for WB 2000 survey.
PFAP 2003 surveys;
The ambiguity in partial productivity measures is resolved by calculating total factor
productivity (TFP). TFP calculations conclusively show decreasing returns to scale: large farms
produce less per unit of inputs in the margin than small farms.
We have shown that in Moldova individual farms are more productive than corporate farms and
that small farms are more productive than large farms. Typically, individual farms are small
while corporate farms are large, and there is a fairly sharp size gap between the farms of two
organizational forms (WORLD BANK, 2005). It could therefore be argued that the farm size effect
observed in our analysis is simply a result of the organizational form effect, or vice versa. To try
and disentangle the two effects, we have looked at two homogeneous samples: a sample of
corporate farms (without any individual farms) and a sample of peasant farms (without any
corporate farms).
Table 3:
TFP of corporate farms by land size categories: PFAP 2003 survey
Number of farms
Land productivity (output/ha, lei)
Labour productivity (output/worker, lei)
TFP (lei per unit of aggregated inputs)
<500 ha
(1)
238
1,927
18,660
3,162
500-2000 ha
(2)
225
2,162
16,580
3,603
>2000 ha
(3)
58
2,430
19,219
4,167
Source: Authors’ calculations from MURAVSCHI and BUCATCA (2005).
The homogeneous sample of 521 corporate farms from the 2003 PFAP survey (MURAVSCHI and
BUCATCA, 2005) was grouped into three size categories (Table 3). The productivity of land
clearly increases with farm size, whereas the productivity of labour does not. Most importantly
for our purposes, total factor productivity calculated by aggregating land and labour with
appropriate weights from the production function shows a definite increase with farm size in the
homogeneous sample of corporate farms.
The World Bank Survey 2000 findings conclusively show that farm income increases with farm
sizes. As we see from the next figure, a substantial increase in farm income is observed for farms
larger than 10 ha. Also, the findings denote that as larger the farmer is, the level of its
commercialization is higher, or they consume less than sell, whish is quite the opposite to very
small farms.
Figure 4:
Family income increasing and its structure
5
160
thousand lei
100%
140
80%
120
100
60%
Personal
Consumption
Sales
80
40%
60
40
20%
20
0
Up to 2
2-10
10--100
0%
>100 Up to 1
1-2
2-5
5-10
>10
farm size, ha
farm size, ha
Source: World Bank Survey, 2000
In a homogeneous sample of peasant farms from the 2005 WB survey (WORLD BANK, 2005), the
standard of living of rural families was observed to increase with farm size. Here, a qualitative
variable characterizing different levels of family well-being (“comfortable”, “subsistence”,
“poverty”) was used as a proxy for farm performance in the absence of TFP estimates for this
sample. Among peasant farms, a comfortable standard of living is associated with much larger
family farms than lower standards of living. Peasant farmers reporting a comfortable standard of
living had 11 hectares on average, compared with less than 5 hectares for farms in the two lower
categories – poverty, when family income is not sufficient to buy food, and subsistence, when
family income is sufficient to buy food and daily necessities (the difference between farm sizes
is statistically significant at p < 0.01).
Figure 5:
Probability of achieving a given standard of living as a function of farm size
for peasant farmers.
1
probability
0.8
0.6
Poverty
Subsistence
Comfortable
0.4
0.2
0
0
10
20
30
40
50
land use, ha
Note:
Definition of standard of living levels: “poverty” – family income not sufficient to buy food;
“subsistence” – family income just sufficient to buy food and daily necessities;
“comfortable” – family income sufficient to buy food, daily necessities, and durables.
Source : Authors’ calculations based on WB 2005 survey (WORLD BANK, 2005).
The standard of living of peasant farmers is thus an increasing function of farm size, as is
commonly observed in farm surveys in CIS and other transition countries.
A different view of the relationship between standard of living and farm size for peasant farmers
is presented in Figure 5, which plots the probability of being in one of the three standard-ofliving levels as a function of farm size. The probability of being in the highest standard of living
(gray curve) increases with farm size, while the probability of being on the lowest “poverty”
level (thick black curve), sharply decreases with farm size.2 These results provide support for
2
The probabilities of achieving a given standard of living were obtained in a multinomial logistic regression with
the three-level standard of living as the discrete dependent variable and farm size as the continuous covariate.
6
increasing the average size of the individual farms through land market development and land
consolidation policies.
These results demonstrate that farm performance actually improves with increasing farm size for
farms of the same organizational form. The inverse productivity–farm size relationship is
observed for mixed samples that include farms of different organizational forms (both individual
and corporate). This suggests that the decrease of productivity with farm size is primarily an
organizational form effect, and not a farm size effect: individual farms are more productive than
corporate farms, and the size effect observed in our analysis appears to be simply a proxy for the
organizational form effect.
Common wisdom argues that consolidation of small disjointed parcels into contiguous holdings
is preferred by farmers and landowners. This kind of consolidation should reduce production
costs and improve net income for a farm of given size. Land consolidation that produces larger
farms (keeping the number of parcels fixed) is also believed to be beneficial, as it should reduce
the ratio of fixed costs per unit of land, allow more efficient use of technology, and ultimately
increase productivity and efficiency. These theoretical arguments, however, are difficult to
substantiate empirically and world experience does not unanimously support either position.
Figure 6: Partial productivity measures versus number of parcels for household plots in
Moldova
Source: 2003 WB survey of household plots
Some evidence that supports the advisability of reducing the number of parcels through land
consolidation is provided by a 2003 World Bank survey of household plot operators in Moldova.
This survey shows a clear negative relationship between productivity and the number of parcels
held by the operator. The partial productivities of land and labor are calculated from the survey
data as the value of farm income (including cash revenue from sales of farm products and value
lei/ha
lei/w ork day
7
1000
900
Farm income per ha
5
700
600
4
500
3
400
300
2
200
1
100
0
Farm income per work day
6
800
0
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
Number of parcels
Farm income per ha
Farm income per work day
of own consumption) per hectare of land and per work day (including family workers and
outsiders). The results presented in Figure 6 clearly show that both the productivity of land
(farm income per hectare) and the productivity of labor (farm income per work day) decrease as
fragmentation (i.e., the number of parcels) increases. The negative relationship between
productivity and fragmentation in Figure 6 is statistically significant by all standard measures.
This conclusion is supported by the analysis of individual farms in Georgia from the 2003 HUJ
survey.3 The Georgian survey also shows that productivity decreases with the increase of
fragmentation, controlling for a number of other relevant factors (LERMAN, 2005).
3
The 2003 HUJ survey in Georgia was conducted by Ayal Kimhi, Department of Agricultural Economics and
7
4
CONCLUSIONS AND RECOMMENDATIONS
Analysis based on national statistics and survey data shows that individual farms are more
efficient than corporate farms. This conclusion does not necessarily mean that corporate farms
should be eliminated and replaced with family farms. Corporate farms do exist in market
economies, which proves that they are able to compete with individual farms. The small number
of corporate farms that do exist in market economies appear to be even more efficient than
individual farms as a group: in the United States, corporate farms control 2% of agricultural land
and generate 20% of output (in Moldova, the relationship is reversed: corporate farms control
50% of land and generate less than 30% of output). The market economies have achieved an
equilibrium farm structure, which includes a mix of individual farms (the dominant majority)
and corporate farms (a small minority) determined by resource availability, managerial capacity,
and personal preferences of farmers and investors. A similar process can unfold in Moldova, but
the development of corporate farms must be left to market forces, free from government
intervention and programming.
Analyzing the dichotomy between small and large farms, we conclude based on several surveys
that small farms are more productive and more efficient than large farms. This result is based on
a mixed sample of both individual and corporate farms, which overall show decreasing returns to
scale. On the other hand, a homogeneous sample comprising only corporate farms shows
increasing returns to scale, i.e., among farms of the same type size has a beneficial effect on
performance. Similarly, in a homogeneous sample comprising only individual farms, family
well-being increases with farm size. Based on these findings we tend to believe that the different
behaviour is determined primarily by organizational form: small farms do better than large farm
not because of a size effect, but because individual farms (which happen to be small) outperform
corporate farms (which happen to be large). In this context, the Government of Moldova should
abandon its preference for large-scale corporate farms and concentrate on improving the
operating conditions for small individual farms.
REFERENCES
COELLI, T., RAO, D. S. P., BATTESE, G. (1998): An Introduction to Efficiency and Productivity
Analysis, Kluwer, Boston.
DSS (2004a): Agricultural Activity of Households and Farms in the Republic of Moldova in 2003
(Results of the Statistical Survey). Department of Statistics and Sociology, Chisinau, Moldova.
DSS (2004b): Agriculture in Moldova 2004, Department of Statistics and Sociology, Chisinau,
Moldova.
DUDWICK, N., FOCK, K., SEDIK, D. (2005): A Stock-Taking of Land Reform and Farm
Restructuring in Bulgaria, Moldova, Azerbaijan, and Kazakhstan, World Bank, Washington, DC
(unpublished).
KOESTER, U. (2003): A revival of large farms in Eastern Europe? – How important are
institutions? Plenary paper presented at the Conference of International Association of
Agricultural Economists, Durban, South Africa, 16-22 August 2003.
LERMAN, Z., CSAKI, C., MOROZ, V. (1998): Land Reform and Farm Restructuring in Moldova:
Progress and Prospects, World Bank Discussion Paper 398, World Bank, Washington, DC.
LERMAN, Z. (2001): Moldova Baseline Farm Survey October-November 2000. Part I: Survey of
Corporate Farm Managers and Peasant farmers; Part II. Survey of Rural Families with
Household Plots, Draft analytical report, World Bank, Washington, DC (unpublished).
Management, The Hebrew University of Jerusalem (HUJ), Israel, with financial support from USAID/CDR.
8
LERMAN, Z., CSAKI, C., FEDER, G. (2004): Agriculture in Transition: Land Policies and Evolving
Farm Structures in Post-Soviet Countries, Lexington Books, Lanham, MD.
MURAVSCHI, A., BUCATCA, A. (2005): Agricultural Policy in Farmers’ Opinion. PFAP - Private
Farmers Assistance Program, East-West Management Institute and USAID, Chisinau, Moldova.
SWINNEN, J. (2006): Endogenous agricultural structures: Insights from transition countries. Paper
presented at the 96-th EAAE Seminar Causes and Impacts of Agricultural Structures, Taenikon,
Switzerland, 10-11 January 2006.
WORLD BANK (2005): Moldova Agricultural Policy Notes: Agricultural Land, Draft analytical
report, World Bank, Washington, DC (unpublished).
9