!
"
# $ % & ' & (
) * +,,+
(
"
!
" #
$ !% ! & $
' ' ($
' # % % ) % * %
' $ '
+ " % &
' !#
$,
( $
- .
!
"- (
%
. %
% % % $
$ $ -
-
- -
// $$$
0
1"1"#23."
4& )*5/ +)
678%99:::& %
2 ;
) -
* &
/- <=1 % &%/ /
/- <7>:94& )*5/ +)
"3 " & 7>:9
Contents
PREFACE................................................................................................................................................................. 5
ORIGINS ................................................................................................................................................................. 7
1.
AGRICULTURAL COOPERATION IN THE USSR AND FORMER SOVIET UNION ............................................ 9
COOPERATIVES DURING THE SOVIET ERA ....................................................................................................................... 9
TRANSITION TO A MARKET ECONOMY ........................................................................................................................ 10
2.
SCOPE FOR COOPERATION IN THE FORMER SOVIET UNION .................................................................. 13
3. LAND REFORM AND THE FUTURE ROLE OF COOPERATIVES IN AGRICULTURE IN THE FORMER SOCIALIST
COUNTRIES IN EUROPE .................................................................................................................................. 16
COMMON HERITAGE OF SOCIALIST AGRICULTURE......................................................................................................... 17
Collectivization .............................................................................................................................................. 17
Land Ownership ............................................................................................................................................ 19
Need for Reform............................................................................................................................................ 20
LAND OWNERSHIP REFORMS.................................................................................................................................... 21
THE FUTURE OF LARGE-SCALE FARMS ........................................................................................................................ 24
LEASE COOPERATIVES AND SHAREHOLDER STRUCTURES ................................................................................................. 25
FIRST EXPERIENCES WITH PRIVATE FARMING AND FARM ENTERPRISE RESTRUCTURING ........................................................ 27
ROLE OF WESTERN-TYPE SERVICE COOPERATIVES ........................................................................................................ 29
CONCLUSION ......................................................................................................................................................... 31
REFERENCES.......................................................................................................................................................... 31
4.
TRANSFORMATION OF COOPERATIVE FARMS IN CENTRAL AND EASTERN EUROPE............................... 33
THE INHERITED SYSTEM ........................................................................................................................................... 34
PRIVATIZATION OF LAND.......................................................................................................................................... 35
INDIVIDUALIZATION OF AGRICULTURE ........................................................................................................................ 38
RESTRUCTURING OF FARMS...................................................................................................................................... 40
EMERGING FARM STRUCTURE .................................................................................................................................. 42
SECTORAL CHANGES DURING TRANSITION .................................................................................................................. 49
WHERE TO FROM HERE? ........................................................................................................................................ 53
A NOTE ON SOURCES OF DATA ................................................................................................................................. 55
5.
AGRICULTURAL COOPERATIVE ENTERPRISE IN THE TRANSITION FROM SOCIALIST COLLECTIVE FARMING
56
ECONOMIC ENVIRONMENT OF THE EARLY 1990S ......................................................................................................... 56
POTENTIAL FOR COOPERATIVES................................................................................................................................. 59
EXPERIENCES WITH NEW COOPERATIVES .................................................................................................................... 62
MARKETING AND INPUT-SUPPLY COOPERATIVES .......................................................................................................... 66
SUMMARY ............................................................................................................................................................ 69
REFERENCES.......................................................................................................................................................... 71
6.
AGRICULTURAL COOPERATIVES IN EURASIA .......................................................................................... 73
WHY AGRICULTURAL COOPERATIVES?........................................................................................................................ 73
THE GREAT DIVIDE WITHIN EURASIA ON AGRICULTURAL COOPERATIVES .......................................................................... 75
POLICY AND LEGISLATIVE SUPPORT FOR COOPERATIVES ................................................................................................. 78
AGRICULTURAL SERVICE COOPERATIVES IN CIS-G COUNTRIES ........................................................................................ 78
CONCLUSIONS ....................................................................................................................................................... 83
REFERENCES.......................................................................................................................................................... 85
1
7.
COOPERATIVE DEVELOPMENT IN CENTRAL ASIA ................................................................................... 88
CONCEPTUAL ISSUES OF AGRICULTURAL COOPERATIVE LEGISLATION IN CENTRAL ASIA ........................................................ 89
Smallholder Agriculture and the Rationale for Service Cooperatives ........................................................... 89
Western Classification of Cooperatives ........................................................................................................ 92
Classification of Cooperatives in Legislation in Central Asia ......................................................................... 96
Need for Consistent Definitions .................................................................................................................. 101
TAXATION OF COOPERATIVES ................................................................................................................................. 102
Exemption from Value Added Tax .............................................................................................................. 103
Exemption from Retail Sales Tax ................................................................................................................ 104
Exemption of Distributions to Members from Profit Tax ............................................................................ 104
OBSERVATIONS FROM THE FIELD: COOPERATIVES IN TAJIKISTAN AND KYRGYZSTAN ........................................................... 108
Fledgling Service Cooperatives in Tajikistan ............................................................................................... 108
Dominance of Production Cooperatives in Kyrgyzstan ............................................................................... 110
COOPERATIVE DEVELOPMENT POLICY FOR CENTRAL ASIA ............................................................................................ 117
World Practice and Central Asia ................................................................................................................. 117
Promoting Cooperatives: Information Campaign and Legal Framework for Cooperatives ........................ 119
Development of a Multi-level Cooperative System for Denser Coverage ................................................... 121
REFERENCES........................................................................................................................................................ 122
8.
COOPERATIVE DEVELOPMENT IN TAJIKISTAN ...................................................................................... 124
THE ROLE OF COOPERATIVES AS SERVICE PROVIDERS .................................................................................................. 124
CREATION OF COOPERATIVES ................................................................................................................................. 125
Western Classification of Cooperatives ...................................................................................................... 126
Classification of Cooperatives in Republic of Tajikistan Legislation............................................................ 129
RELATIONS AND CASH FLOWS BETWEEN MEMBERS AND THE COOPERATIVE .................................................................... 132
TAXATION OF COOPERATIVES ................................................................................................................................. 133
EXEMPTION FROM VALUE ADDED TAX ..................................................................................................................... 134
EXEMPTION OF DISTRIBUTIONS TO MEMBERS FROM TAX ............................................................................................. 135
EXEMPTION FROM RETAIL SALES TAX ....................................................................................................................... 137
PROMOTING COOPERATIVES................................................................................................................................... 137
9.
COOPERATIVES IN KYRGYZSTAN: FINDINGS FROM A SURVEY OF COOPERATIVES AND USERS ............. 140
WESTERN CLASSIFICATION OF COOPERATIVES............................................................................................................ 141
DATA SOURCES ON AGRICULTURAL COOPERATIVES IN KYRGYZSTAN ............................................................................... 143
FUNCTIONAL TYPOLOGY OF COOPERATIVES SURVEYED ................................................................................................ 144
SERVICE ACTIVITIES OF THE COOPERATIVES ............................................................................................................... 145
TAXATION AND FINANCIAL PERFORMANCE OF COOPERATIVES....................................................................................... 146
FARMERS’ ATTITUDES TOWARD COOPERATION.......................................................................................................... 147
EFFECT OF COOPERATION ON FARMERS’ WELLBEING .................................................................................................. 151
CONCLUSIONS ..................................................................................................................................................... 153
REFERENCES........................................................................................................................................................ 154
10.
AGRICULTURAL COOPERATIVE DEVELOPMENT IN KAZAKHSTAN AND UKRAINE .............................. 156
THE NEED FOR AGRICULTURAL SERVICE COOPERATIVES IN KAZAKHSTAN AND UKRAINE ..................................................... 158
UKRAINE AND KAZAKHSTAN POLICIES ON AGRICULTURAL SERVICE COOPERATIVES ............................................................ 159
Ukraine ....................................................................................................................................................... 159
Kazakhstan ................................................................................................................................................. 161
ENABLING ENVIRONMENT: CLASSIFICATION AND CHARACTERISTICS OF COOPERATIVES ...................................................... 162
UKRAINE AND KAZAKHSTAN LEGISLATION ON AGRICULTURAL SERVICE COOPERATIVES ....................................................... 164
The USSR Law on Cooperation .................................................................................................................... 164
Ukraine Cooperative Law ............................................................................................................................ 165
Kazakhstan Cooperative Law ...................................................................................................................... 166
TAXATION OF COOPERATIVES ................................................................................................................................. 167
Conceptual Issues of Cooperative Taxation ................................................................................................ 168
Ukraine: Taxation of Cooperatives ............................................................................................................. 170
2
Kazakhstan: Taxation of Cooperatives........................................................................................................ 171
CONCLUSION ....................................................................................................................................................... 172
REFERENCES........................................................................................................................................................ 173
11.
COOPERATIVES IN CIS AND GEORGIA: OVERVIEW OF LEGISLATION ................................................ 176
THE DICHOTOMY OF PRODUCTION AND SERVICE COOPERATIVES IN CIS .......................................................................... 178
INVENTORY OF COOPERATIVE LAWS IN CIS................................................................................................................ 181
CONTENT OF COOPERATIVE LAWS ACROSS CIS .......................................................................................................... 182
Existence of Cooperative Laws .................................................................................................................... 185
Cooperative Objective ................................................................................................................................. 188
Dichotomy Between Production and Service (“Consumer”) Cooperatives.................................................. 188
Cooperative Membership............................................................................................................................ 189
Member Participation in Cooperative Activity and in Labor Input.............................................................. 190
Transactions with Members and Non-Members ........................................................................................ 190
TAXATION OF COOPERATIVES ................................................................................................................................. 191
Value Added Tax (VAT) ............................................................................................................................... 191
Tax on Profits .............................................................................................................................................. 192
REGISTRATION REQUIREMENTS FOR COOPERATIVES .................................................................................................... 195
CONCLUSION ....................................................................................................................................................... 198
REFERENCES........................................................................................................................................................ 200
3
4
Preface
This volume is a collection of ten articles that I wrote with two colleagues,
Csaba Csaki and David Sedik, over a period of lasting collaboration from 1989 to
2016. The publishing policy of LAP – Lambert Academic Publishing has made it
possible to bring these articles together in a single book and thus present the
readers with a broad retrospective of the evolution of the idea of agricultural
cooperation in transition countries in Eastern Europe and Central Asia (the ECA
region) over nearly three decades. The origins of the ten articles are listed after
the Preface. The dates when the articles where written or conceived are also
shown in parentheses next to the authors’ names in each chapter in this volume.
The articles grew out of the authors’ work at the World Bank and the Food and
Agriculture Organization of the U.N. They were all part of a concerted effort to
provide policy advice to former Socialist countries in Europe and Central Asia in
an attempt to help governments navigate the complex transition from centrally
planned to market economy. We were witnesses to a process of truly historic
proportions that was affecting, and continues to affect, the wellbeing and fortunes
of the large rural populations in the region and, despite the unavoidable upheaval,
proceeded without major social unrest.
The work on agricultural cooperatives in transition countries is inseparable
from the study of land reform and farm restructuring in the region. The hallmarks
of the Soviet agricultural model – the large collective farms (kolkhozes) – were
in essence production cooperatives and they left a deep imprint on the agriculture
sector and the rural psyche, which has persisted since the beginning of the
transition in 1989-1991 to this day. Most of the chapters focus in depth on the
Soviet model of agriculture as it was implemented in the USSR, but we also deal
– albeit in less detail – with the somewhat different model of socialist agriculture
that evolved in Central Eastern Europe (“the Comecon countries”, see Chapters
3 and 4). The Soviet model in the USSR crystallized during the 1920s and began
to transform in 1990-1991, with the dissolution of the Soviet Union, while the
Central Eastern European model emerged in the 1950s, when communist regimes
took over, and its transformation began in 1989, with the first signs of
disengagement of the central powers in Moscow.
As is to be expected in a thematic collection of articles written at different times for
different audiences, there is unavoidable overlap between various chapters in this volume,
especially in chapters 5-10 devoted to the recent development of agricultural cooperatives
in former Socialist countries in the ECA region. We believe that the readers will not read
5
the book cover to cover but will mostly pick and choose particular chapters that interest
them. The repetitions across various chapters would make each chapter stand on its own
and allow us to dispense with cross-references to other chapters within the volume. We
have therefore decided not to edit out the repetitions, intentionally allowing some
redundancy that, hopefully, will be in the readers’interest. In the same spirit, the references
appear at the end of each chapter separately.
I would like to take this opportunity to pay tribute to the late Bruce Gardner, a great
agricultural economist and policymaker with whom I had the distinct privilege of coauthoring Chapter 5 on agricultural cooperative enterprise during the transition from
Socialist collective farming. I worked with Bruce in close collaboration from 2000 to his
untimely death in 2008 on a multi-national project that studied factor market constraints
in Russia’s agriculture. The project results were published in a special issue of the journal
Comparative Economic Studies (Vol. 47, No. 1, March 2005) and in a volume that I edited
under the title Russia’s Agriculture in Transition: Factor Markets and Constraints on
Growth (Lexington Books, Lanham, MD, 2008), which fittingly ends with a summary
chapter by Bruce Gardner. These two publications are a modest contribution to Bruce’s
extensive scholarly legacy.
Zvi Lerman
Department of Environmental Economics and Management
The Hebrew University of Jerusalem, Israel
6
Origins
1.
Agricultural Cooperation in the USSR and Former Soviet Union
May 2002; earlier version presented in April 1996 at the conference on modernization and
democratization in former Soviet Central Asia, U. of Minnesota, Minneapolis, MN
2.
Scope for Cooperation in the Former Soviet Union
1990-1991; contribution to World Bank’s “Land Reform and Restructuring of Kolkhozes and
Sovkhozes in the Former USSR and Russia” (Review of Food Policy Options and Agricultural
Sector Reforms, Working Paper #3, July 1992)
3.
Land Reform and the Future Role of Cooperatives in Agriculture in the Former
Socialist Countries in Europe
Earlier version presented in April 1992 at the International Association of Agricultural
Economists’ Interconference Symposium, Ma’ale Hachamisha, Israel
4.
Transformation of Cooperative Farms in Central and Eastern Europe
June 2000; presented at the World Bank/EU Workshop on structural change in the farming
sectors of Central and Eastern Europe, Warsaw, June 1999.
5.
Agricultural Cooperative Enterprise in the Transition from Socialist Collective
Farming
Conceived in June 1995. Written in September 2006 for Center of Agricultural Economic
Research Discussion Paper Series, Rehovot, Israel. Earlier version published in Journal of
Rural Cooperation (2006).
6.
Agricultural Cooperatives in Eurasia
March 2014; part of the series Policy Studies in Transition, Food and Agriculture Organization
of the U.N., Regional Office for Europe and Central Asia (FAO/REU)
7.
Cooperative Development in Central Asia
April 2013; part of the series Policy Studies in Transition, FAO/REU
8.
Cooperative Development in Tajikistan
April 2012; background study for the Tajikistan Land Reform Working Group during the
development of a new law of cooperatives (FAO Tajikistan, Dushanbe)
9.
Cooperatives in Kyrgyzstan: Findings from a Survey of Cooperatives and Users
February 2014; analysis of a survey conducted by FAO/REU in the spring of 2012
10.
Agricultural Cooperative Development in Kazakhstan and Ukraine
October 2013; presented at the International Economic Association’s 17th World Congress,
Dead Sea, Jordan (June 2014).
11.
Cooperatives in CIS and Georgia: Overview of legislation
March 2014; part of the FAO/REU project to develop an online database of cooperative laws
in CIS
7
8
1. Agricultural Cooperation in the USSR
and Former Soviet Union
Zvi Lerman (1996-2002)
Agricultural cooperation has a long tradition in Russia and in many other
republics of the former Soviet Union. Agricultural cooperatives began to develop
in Russia in the period between the 1860s and the 1890s, soon after the
introduction of co-ops in Western Europe. By 1917, some 10 million Russian
peasants were members in 16,500 credit societies and over 2 million were
members in 12,000 other agricultural cooperatives.
Cooperatives during the Soviet era
The evolution of Russian cooperation in the 1920s was characterized by the
rapid emergence of national cooperative unions of specialized producers. These
national organizations often initiated and guided the “top-down” creation of local
and regional cooperatives. Another feature of the 1920s was the spontaneous and
completely voluntary emergence of agricultural production cooperatives. These
early collectives, created by peasants pooling together their small allotments of
land or sometimes joining without any land at all, were expected to act as the
primary link in the vertically integrated system of agricultural cooperation that
was developing in the Soviet Union at that time.
In 1929, Stalin’s collectivization campaign began. This campaign was
couched in cooperative terms, stressing the advantages of cooperation and
emphasizing voluntary membership. Yet in practice the drive had all the elements
of forced conscription, reinforced by political and physical intimidation. By 1980,
there were around 30,000 collective farms in the USSR, each with about 3000 ha
of land and 500 employees.
9
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
The Standard Charter of a collective farm is a model of cooperative principles.
It speaks in glowing terms of the kolkhoz as a “form of agricultural production
cooperative of peasants that voluntarily unite for the purpose of joint agricultural
production based on . . . collective labor.” It asserts that “the kolkhoz is managed
according to the principles of socialist self-management, democracy, and
openness, with active participation of the members in decisions concerning all
aspects of internal life.”
In practice, however, the collective farm that emerged after collectivization
did not have many characteristics of a true cooperative, except joint ownership of
non-land assets (land in the Soviet Union was nationalized in 1917) and
remuneration of residual profit in proportion to labor and not capital. The basic
principle of voluntary membership had been violated by the very process of
forced collectivization; members did not retain a right of free exit, and those who
managed to leave could not take their share of land and assets with them; and the
role of the “sovereign” general assembly and the “democratically elected”
management was reduced to rubber-stamping.
The collectivization of Soviet agriculture in the 1930s made redundant the tens
of thousands of credit, marketing, and service cooperatives that had developed
during the 1920s. They disappeared as the collective farms evolved into
multifunctional rural organizations that took care of large-scale agricultural
production and also interfaced directly with local and central government on
matters of farm input supply (which replaced “input purchasing”), product
deliveries (which replaced “marketing”), and residual financing from the state
budget (which replaced credit negotiations).
Transition to a Market Economy
The countries of the former Soviet Union continue to negotiate the difficult
transition from a centrally planned economy to a market-oriented economy based
on private property and individual initiative. There are two aspects to the
transition, which began in 1991: transfer of property rights in land, and
designation of ownership of farm assets.
Despite their newly found ownership of land and assets, people are not willing
to leave the collective organization. In recent surveys, 85% of collective farm
members in Russia and 78% in the Ukraine indicated they did not intend to leave
the collective and become private farmers. Members of former collective farms
are thus voting with their feet for perpetuation of the cooperative framework, at
least in the immediate future, probably because of the sense of security it affords
in a highly uncertain and rapidly changing environment.
10
1. Agricultural Cooperation in the USSR and Former Soviet Union
A typical restructuring procedure involves internal reorganization of the old
collective into a system of relatively small autonomous profit centers or units.
Because of the relatively small size of such units, which are organized as
partnerships, cooperatives, or small corporations, the active workers maintain the
sense of private ownership of production assets. The old management structures
of the collective may in turn reorganize to provide the necessary services and
support to these autonomous units. Agricultural production is thus concentrated
in units that are small enough to maintain a good sense of personal involvement
and accountability, while farm-support services and the interface with the
environment are provided by a relatively large and professionally experienced
cooperative structure. With time, as the constituent units gain experience, they
may become more independent of the former management, whose role is
gradually reduced to that of a service cooperative that member units use as
needed.
Some individuals nevertheless exercised their new right to establish an
independent private farm outside the cooperative framework. There were about
300,000 such individual farms in Russia and 30,000 in Ukraine by 2001. After an
initial flush of enthusiasm, private farmers began to realize that totally
independent individual farming is very difficult, especially in their current
economic environment. Private farmers need credit to satisfy their requirements
for working capital and long-term investments; they also need trade channels both
for purchasing farm inputs and for marketing their products. Both of these things
are generally missing. The credit and banking system, which traditionally
functioned as a window for transfer of funds from the budget to large collective
and state farms, was not designed to finance independent farming operations, and
the new commercial banks showed little interest in agricultural lending. The state
supply monopolies had been replaced with “privatized” monopolies, but a
network of rural outlets for selling inputs and implements to private farmers had
not yet developed.
One strategy to overcome these deficiencies was the establishment of central
cooperative unions and national associations of farmers. The governments in
Russia and Ukraine, for instance, encouraged and actively sponsored the
establishment in 1991 of a national association of private farmers and
cooperatives. The national association rapidly proceeded to establish a network
of local associations at the province and district level, whose function was to
develop “trading firms” to facilitate input purchases by member farms.
Another, perhaps even more effective, strategy to deal with difficulties caused
by imperfect markets is through grassroots cooperation among private farmers in
rural communities. Indeed, the fledgling private farm sector is developing some
11
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
cooperative structures. Private farmers are beginning to share machinery and
equipment, to cooperate in purchasing supplies and marketing of products, to pool
their land resources in order to achieve more efficient cultivation, and even to
establish joint “industrial” enterprises to augment their income from agriculture.
In some cases, this cooperation is strictly informal, encompassing a number of
members in a loose collaborative arrangement. In other cases, private farmers
form an association of agricultural producers: each farm retains its identity, but
all farms cooperate in provision of services, where economies of size and the
effect of pooling resources are most pronounced. In the Western paradigm, this is
an association of private producers supported by service cooperatives.
To be effective, local cooperation must encompass as a minimum the critical
areas of finance, marketing, and technical services. World Bank surveys
conducted in 1992–1994 have shown that around 80% of both Russian and
Ukrainian private farmers participated in some form of joint activity in provision
or use of farm services. The main areas of cooperation with other farmers were
production, marketing, input supply, use of machinery, and provision or receipt
of credit, where the participation rates were 30% to 40% of respondents in Russia
and only slightly lower in Ukraine. Cooperative processing is still undeveloped,
but the observations for two successive years in Russia seem to indicate that this
cooperation was increasing. More than half the private farmers in the surveys
cooperated in their use of consulting services, although this was not a major input.
The transition of the former Soviet agriculture to a market economy led
naturally to the creation of several kinds of cooperatives. Unlike the former
collective farms, these were true cooperatives in the sense that they were created
voluntarily, ensured free exit of the members, and were governed by a democratic
process relatively free of government intervention in operating decisions. The
emergent organizational forms covered a range of alternative structures, from new
production cooperatives that were created by reorganization of collective farms
into smaller units based on private ownership, through voluntary associations of
independent farmers seeking safety in cooperation, to service cooperatives
established by various local producers. This volume presents an overview of
cooperative development in some countries of the former Soviet Union, including
a description of the so-called Soviet model of agriculture that prevailed before the
onset of transition to market economy.
12
2. Scope for Cooperation in the Former
Soviet Union
Csaba Csaki and Zvi Lerman (1990-1991)
Privatization of agricultural production is one of the components of transition
to the market in the countries of the former Soviet Union. Yet there is strong
evidence in the press and from field interview that most Russian rural residents
say that they are not ready for independent farming. Their reluctance is
understandable in view of political uncertainty, the inadequacy of infrastructure,
and almost total absence of market structures. This appears to provide an
opportunity for the development of Western-style cooperative organizations,
whose function is often described in economic theory as correcting for market
failure, that is, enabling producers to function even in the absence of fully
developed markets.
In the West, service cooperatives, which specialize in provision of agricultural
inputs and marketing of agricultural products are the dominant form of this type
of organization. In addition to correcting for market failure, service coops also
strive to maximize economies of size by organizing their facilities on a regional
basis, and not village by village. Thus, an input-purchasing cooperative will
centrally purchase fertilizers for all the farmers in the region, and not just for one
village; a grain elevator will serve all the grain producers in the region; and a dairy
cooperative will send trucks to collect the milk from farms in many different
locations in its region.
Cooperatives are created to serve the needs of their member-owners. A unique
feature of the cooperative is the “one man, one vote” principle: the power of a
member is not a function of the member’s investment in the cooperative.
Moreover, the current benefits are distributed to members on the basis of
“patronage,” meaning the amount of business done with the cooperative, and not
on the basis of investment in the organization. This feature increases the incentive
13
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
for the member to use the cooperative. These features clearly differentiate
between the private firm and the cooperative. The objective of the latter is not to
earn profits but to provide member services. A cooperative can be characterized
as a “user-owned” organization, contrary to the traditional “investor-owned” firm.
Production cooperatives are not widespread in the World. Production should
be private: on private farms, in private dairy enterprises, and so forth. To avoid
misunderstanding, we should stress that when a group of former kolkhoz or
sovkhoz members take over a large-scale dairy or poultry complex through share
swapping, creating what is conventionally known in Russian terminology as a
“cooperative”, in fact they form a private partnership, in which the power of each
partner is proportional to that person’s investment (share of assets). But beyond
production, there is a large scope for the creation of cooperatives that will serve
all the villages within the scope of a former kolkhoz and sovkhoz organization.
Service cooperatives can be organized if former kolkhoz and sovkhoz
members decide to pool asset shares, instead of swapping them with others. In
this way, all the farmers in the region can form, for example, a trucking
cooperative. The function of this cooperative would be to collect the produce from
the member farms and to take it to the nearest distribution center or market in the
city. In the absence of distribution centers or organized food markets, the
cooperative may actually undertake to sell the produce to the end users in the
cities (a “marketing cooperative”). The same trucks can be used to carry
agricultural inputs from suppliers to the rural region (a “supply cooperative”). All
this would relieve the waste of farming time that farmers usually associate with
marketing and purchasing. It also ensures more efficient use of trucks for carrying
larger loads. The trucking cooperative of course would need garages for the
vehicles, as well as storage facilities for produce collected from the farms and
especially for inputs purchased from suppliers. These also can be created by the
pooling of “building shares” distributed to the members or alternatively by buying
the required assets for cash. A farmer without any “truck shares” can join the
cooperative by paying a certain entrance fee - “buying a share” in the cooperative.
In principle, such cooperatives should be allowed to coexist with private trucking
companies formed by individuals through share swapping with others.
Competition between cooperatives and private firms in the same line of business
would be beneficial to the producers and would ensure the most efficient use of
resources.
Cooperatives also can be established to develop local and regional
infrastructure, especially if it is not developed by the state. One of the major needs
in rural areas is the construction of farm access roads. Building roads is, of course,
a responsibility of the state, but as an interim solution this function may be
14
2. Scope for Cooperation in the Former Soviet Union
fulfilled by a road construction and maintenance cooperative that could be
organized by all the farmers in the region. It is important to stress that even
farmers in central villages that have all-weather access roads would be invited to
join this cooperative: their roads will soon need maintenance and repair, which
could be accomplished by the cooperative.
In the cooperative paradigm, the reorganized agricultural system that would
emerge from the former kolkhozes and sovkhozes can be viewed as an extension
and a modification of the Israeli moshav model. Private agricultural production,
based both on family farms and on larger multifamily enterprises, would be
supported by a range of service cooperatives whose function will be to correct for
market failure and to exploit economies of size. These cooperatives may be
responsible for agricultural machinery, for purchase and delivery of agricultural
inputs, and for shipping out and marketing of agricultural products. The service
cooperatives may be organized regionally by function and enterprise, as is
common in Western countries: dairy cooperatives, poultry cooperatives, grain
cooperatives, fruit and vegetable cooperatives, and so forth.
Another very important function of the cooperatives would be to provide
accounting, financial, and professional services. If not done by private
individuals, as described in the previous section, these services would have to be
provided by a “consulting” cooperative, which would be established by the
producers, like any other regional service cooperative. The main difference,
however, is that instead of paying for inputs, trucking, or use of machinery, the
producers would pay for professional and administrative services provided by
experts, who in turn would receive a salary or a retainer from this cooperative.
The experts themselves are not members of the cooperative: they are resources
employed by the cooperative.
In the present environment of high uncertainty and inadequate market
structures, regional service cooperatives may provide the necessary reinforcement
and backing to the emerging private sector in Russian agriculture by imbuing the
new farmers with a sense of collective strength and shielding them to a certain
extent from market imperfections. The establishment of service cooperatives
should not rule out the establishment of private firms in the same lines of business.
Competition between the two forms of organization would only improve the
economic efficiency of the system by providing the producers with a greater
variety of options.
15
3. Land Reform and the Future Role of
Cooperatives in Agriculture in the Former
Socialist Countries in Europe
Csaba Csaki and Zvi Lerman (1992)
The former European socialist countries, including the Soviet Union and the
countries of Central and Eastern Europe, are undergoing a fundamental economic
and political transformation. Far-reaching changes that surpass all previous
reform attempts are taking place in the agrarian economy of these countries,
where the creation of a new agricultural structure based on private ownership, true
cooperatives, and a market economy has begun. All the countries in the region are
striving to overcome serious economic difficulties with comprehensive political
and economic reforms. They are in a process of transition: many details have yet
to be clarified, especially in the former Soviet Union, and there is much
uncertainty regarding the future. These changes will fundamentally reshape
agriculture in the region and deeply affect its functioning and its role in
international agrarian relations.
The transition from socialist to market-based agriculture is a complex and
multi-faceted process that raises many difficult questions. The major issues
include privatization of land and other productive assets, development of a new
incentive framework, establishment of a market-controlled system with a working
market for agricultural inputs and products, redefinition of the role of government
in agriculture, and implementation of appropriate institutional changes and
reforms. These topics have been examined in the literature in various forms and
contexts (see a selection of relevant sources in References), but there are no
textbook solutions and the process of transition is shrouded in uncertainty. The
next few years will be characterized by fluidity and change as the former socialist
countries move toward new goals and structures while simultaneously searching
for their own solutions, possibly taking account of the diverse world experiences.
16
3. Land Reform and Future Role of Cooperatives in Former Socialist Countries in Europe
Analysis of alternative trajectories of change is an important and timely task that
can help decision-makers to formulate relevant policies.
The objective of this paper is much more modest. We focus on the process of
change as it is actually unfolding in the former socialist countries and provide a
comparative review of two main issues: an account of the land reform process and
an overview of the attempts to restructure and privatize the collective and state
farms, with a special reference to the future role of cooperatives.
Common Heritage of Socialist Agriculture
Agriculture in all former socialist countries in Europe was organized on similar
principles of a centrally planned economy, with a pervasive administrative
command system. All these countries shared the same philosophy of managing
agriculture, with an emphasis on low prices and correspondingly low wages. The
philosophy of controlling agriculture by plans and administrative commands
created a farming structure based on dominance of large-scale farms, although the
concrete solutions differed across countries.
Collectivization
The agrarian structure of the region was shaped by the collectivization process.
It began in the Soviet Union in 1928-1929 and was copied to the countries of
Central and Eastern Europe after World War II. Table 3.1 shows some major
indicators of large-scale socialized farming in the European socialist countries.
Table 3.1. Number and average land size of socialized agricultural organizations (1985 data)
State farms
Farms
Average area, ha
Farms
Albania
70
2,400
420
Bulgaria*
536
9,692
NA
CZSK
226
6,204
1,677
GDR
465
945
3,904
Hungary
128
1,270
4,195
Poland
1,258
2,665
2,342
Romania
419
4,895
4,363
USSR
22,690
16,051
26,660
* Total number of agricultural units in 150 agroindustrial complexes.
Source: Cochrane (1989).
Collective farms
Average area, ha
1,270
NA
2,605
1,370
7,598
297
2,093
6,370
Collectivization of agricultural production was promoted as a means of
achieving central management (it also, of course, ensured political control). In the
Soviet Union, farm enterprise collectivization was originally designed to extract
food from rural areas for increasingly industrialized urban centers at low cost; a
17
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
corollary purpose was to allow mechanization to capture supposed economies of
scale in farming. While 97% of all agricultural land in the Soviet Union was
farmed individually between 1917 and 1928, rapid collectivization after 1928
virtually eliminated individual farming; by 1940, 97% of all farms in the USSR
were worked collectively. The only remnants of individual farming were the tiny
household plots that collective farm members were allowed near their dwellings
for “individual subsidiary farming”.
Table 3.2. Percentage of socialized agricultural land in the former socialist countries (1985 data,
including household plots)
Country
Percent of total agricultural land
Albania
100.0
Bulgaria
99.6
Czechoslovakia
94.9
GDR
95.0
Hungary
92.5
Poland
27.9
Romania
90.5
USSR
99.9
Source: Cochrane (1989).
Collectivization in the socialist countries of Central and Eastern Europe after
World War II pursued similar objectives. In most countries in the region, 90100% of all agricultural land was ultimately (mid-1980s) organized in socialized,
state and collective, farms (Table 3.2), although there were local differences in
execution and different structures emerged across the region. In GDR,
Czechoslovakia, Bulgaria, Romania, and Albania the socialist reorganization of
agriculture adhered to the Soviet model: the typical form of agricultural enterprise
was the large-scale state or collective farm of several thousand hectares. In
Bulgaria, state and collective farms were subsequently merged into agroindustrial
complexes. In mid-1980s, 150 giant complexes were operating in Bulgaria,
spanning most of the agricultural land. In GDR, a particular characteristic of
collectivized agriculture was the separation of crop and livestock production
systems. In Albania, collectivization was even more extreme than in the Soviet
Union: all private activity in agriculture, even household farming, was banned
and remained forbidden for a long time. In Hungary, on the other hand,
collectivization was characterized by relative independence of the large-scale
agricultural cooperatives and small subsidiary household farms prospered within
the cooperative structures. Finally, Poland was the only socialist country in
Europe that escaped total collectivization: here less than 30% of land had been
collectivized and private farms retained their predominance, but the government
impeded their progress for a long time.
18
3. Land Reform and Future Role of Cooperatives in Former Socialist Countries in Europe
Outside of Poland, few classical private farms survived the reorganization of
agriculture. The private sector was driven to the fringes of the economy.
However, despite the virtually total absence of a traditional private farming sector,
individual production survived in all countries (except Albania) in the form of
household farms with part-time farming. The subsidiary household farms in the
former Soviet Union and in Hungary consistently accounted for around 30% of
total agricultural product. In Bulgaria, individual farming contributed about 25%
of total agricultural product. The rate of private production was the lowest in
Czechoslovakia and the former GDR (about 10%). No reliable figures are
available for Romania. The small private producers specialized primarily in laborintensive enterprises, such as livestock and vegetables, while grain and other scale
crops were concentrated almost exclusively in the capital-intensive socialized
farms. The political attitude toward these semi-private farming activities changed
frequently. It is only in Hungary that subsidiary household farming was tolerated
continuously and often even supported by the socialist system.
Land Ownership
Collectivization of agriculture was implemented against a backdrop of
changes in land ownership relations and policies. In the Soviet Union, all land
was nationalized within days of the October 1917 revolution. After that, state land
was given to farmers in lifetime use and no private land ownership was
recognized. Albania also nationalized land following its transition to a socialist
regime after World War II. In general, however, land in Central and Eastern
Europe was not nationalized after World War II, although it was subsequently
collectivized. In addition to state property, cooperative or collective land
ownership thus emerged, while private land also continued to exist in various
forms, especially in Hungary, Poland, and Czechoslovakia. Traditional municipal
ownership of rural land for common pasture and social infrastructure totally
disappeared.
Although private land ownership was preserved in some countries, property
rights became a mere formality over the years. Land markets were abolished and
agricultural land lost its character as a means of production with a clear money
value. The value of land was not listed in the registry of agricultural implements,
nor was the price of land calculated among the production costs.
19
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
Need for Reform
Decades of socialism manifested in central planning and administrative
commands produced a similar legacy for agriculture in the Soviet Union and in
the countries of Central and Eastern Europe:
N large, inefficient farms with high production costs, suffering from lack of
individual initiative and “free rider” attitudes;
N elimination of all incentives for efficiency improvement through institution
of cost-based procurement prices and deeply subsidized unrestricted
credits;
N food price subsidies, producing an excess demand for food at the subsidized
prices and a high level of food consumption relative to countries of
comparable prosperity in market economies;
N pervasive monopoly of the state in food processing and distribution and in
farm input supply, leading to destruction of economic intermediation
mechanisms and total dependence of producers on centrally allocated
inputs;
N macroeconomic distortions, including a chronic budget deficit, inflation,
and mounting foreign debt.
This negative legacy is a natural consequence of the ideological goal of
controlling all agricultural production, distribution, and consumption. The
economic distortions introduced by the administrative command system became
apparent fairly early and triggered periodic reform attempts across the region.
However, the weakness was endemic to the system: the various reform attempts
failed to resolve the major shortcomings of the system and to produce the desired
improvements in agricultural performance. Instead of creating a better system of
socialist agriculture, the central command system collapsed between 1989-1991.
Following the political changes in socialist Europe in 1989-1991, efforts to
create a completely new agrarian structure replaced the superficial, cosmetic
reform attempts. The political tide that swept Central and Eastern Europe in 19891990 and the August 1991 events in the Soviet Union signaled the beginning of a
new era also for agriculture. The change is most discernible in the former GDR,
Hungary, Poland, and Czechoslovakia, where the introduction of a true multiparty system ended the communist monopoly. Changes are also occurring in
Romania, Bulgaria, and Albania, but agricultural development is more uncertain
in these countries because the post-communist parties, although still fairly stable,
appear to be losing their power. The dissolution of the Soviet Union has created
the political conditions for a real change in agriculture. However, a detailed
20
3. Land Reform and Future Role of Cooperatives in Former Socialist Countries in Europe
agenda for the transformation of Soviet agriculture began to emerge in the former
republics only in the first half of 1992, and consistent strategies for agricultural
transformation still do not exist.
Land Ownership Reforms
One of the most debated political and economic questions in the region
concerns land ownership and the creation of land markets. The land reform
process involves three distinct issues:
N the establishment of a legal framework for private land ownership and land
markets;
N the decision on actual eligibility and allocation of land to new owners;
N the creation of a new farming structure, including the restructuring of
existing large-scale farms in line with the new ownership patterns and the
principles of a market-based economy.
At the very beginning of the transition to new political and economic
conditions in the region, several proposals were made to change the inherited land
ownership and tenure structure. The main alternative proposals were the
following:
N retain the state ownership of land and allow individual use of land through
leasing;
N make the land the property of those who wish to pursue agricultural
production, while limiting the right to sell and lease out the land during a
certain transition period;
N allow private ownership of land by farmers without any restrictions on
immediate sale or leasing;
N grant land ownership based on pre-collectivization property rights to those
who want to farm and compensate financially the previous owners who are
not active farmers;
N restore pre-collectivization land ownership relations without any
restrictions;
N treat land ownership as an integrated element of an overall compensation
and privatization package.
These multiple possibilities are further complicated by the issue of payment
for land: should land be granted free to eligible individuals or should they be
required to pay. Issues of former ownership and restitution are relevant mainly
for the “western” countries in the region, where private land ownership existed
21
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
until after World War II and the original land owners or their descendants are
identifiable to this day. In the former Soviet republics, where the traditions of
private ownership were never strong, the major issue is eligibility and the pattern
of distribution: should land be given to everybody or only to those who currently
work the land; should there be a ceiling on land holdings or should an individual
be allowed to own any amount of land.
During 1991-1992, land ownership has been the focal point of heated political
debate throughout Central and Eastern Europe and in the former Soviet Union.
Legislation related to land has been passed in Romania, Bulgaria, Hungary,
Czechoslovakia, and Albania. All these laws recognize private land ownership.
In the USSR, the 1991 Union-level land legislation was followed by detailed
“land codes” in the former republics, but full unrestricted private land ownership
has not yet been fully accepted in most republics (including the trail-blazing
Russia). The legislation outside the former Soviet Union also recognizes the rights
of landowners immediately prior to collectivization, and the laws establish a
procedure, which differs across countries, for reinstating property rights. Among
the former Soviet republics, reinstatement of pre-collectivization ownership and
compensation of former landowners is in process only in the Baltics; the issue is
being debated also in Western Ukraine and Belorus.
In Romania and Bulgaria, households can claim a limited area of land based
on certain supporting evidence. In Romania, the restitution of former land
ownership was implemented fairly quickly, without any intention of creating
farms of optimal size or determining how farmers will produce after the land is
distributed. The Bulgarian approach attempts to construct appropriate holdings
through administrative assignment. Although this method is intrinsically slow,
political tension delayed almost any implementation for a long time. It is only
after September 1992 that the new non-communist Bulgarian government decided
to speed up the process. In Albania, most of the nationalized land was distributed
to individuals in 1991, although the legal framework of land ownership is still not
fully in place.
In Hungary, the initial attempt in 1990 to return agricultural land to prior
owners was blocked by the Constitutional Court, which ruled that land ownership
must be treated like other assets. In 1991, landowners and dispossessed owners of
other property received vouchers redeemable for agricultural land and other
assets, which essentially gave monetary compensation to prior owners. Land
auctions are being organized by government agencies, providing voucher holders
and others with an opportunity to purchase land. This strategy may lead to
accumulation of farmland in the hands of non-farmers and even non-rural
residents. Landowners who continued to hold title to land managed by
22
3. Land Reform and Future Role of Cooperatives in Former Socialist Countries in Europe
cooperatives were granted unconditional restitution of their ownership rights. In
Czechoslovakia, the law mandates return of agricultural land to prior owners who
are willing to cultivate it. Only modest interest in reclaiming land has been
reported thus far. In Poland, where most of the land has always remained in
private ownership and use, the future of state farmland (about 20% of the total) is
only now beginning to be discussed.
Land ownership issues are more complicated in the former USSR, where land
was nationalized back in 1917 and farming was subsequently collectivized. In
Russia, the presidential decree on the continuation of land reform (December
1991) took substantial steps toward the establishment of private land ownership.
Other republics have adopted similar decrees. However, further legislation is still
needed in most republics, including Russia, to establish full-fledged private land
ownership with unrestricted rights to sell and lease out land. Russian legislation
recognizes three categories of land ownership: state, private, and municipal land.
Some republics, however, have an additional category of collective or
cooperatively owned land. This unusual ownership category is justified by the
requirements of the transition from state to private property, but there is a danger
that it will be perpetualized and thus obstruct full-fledged privatization of land
and development of market relations.
The existing legislation and government policy in most former Soviet
republics intends to keep private agriculture as a supplementary component of a
farming structure based on large-scale farms. The establishment of private
agriculture and the implementation of land reforms are proceeding along these
lines. Land-reform legislation in Russia and other republics recognizes two
sources of land for distribution: state reserve land for establishment of new private
farms and the land of large-scale farms for expansion of subsidiary household
holdings and for allocation to members. Substantial land reserves, however, exist
only in Russia, where 14 million hectares are available from this source. In other
republics, there is virtually no uncultivated land and reserves had to be created by
expropriating 15-20% of the farmland from collective and state farms.
In the former Soviet Union, an individual can receive a parcel of up to 50 or
100 hectares of land simply by writing an application to the local authorities
(some evidence of agricultural background or education is required as an
eligibility criterion). Land is distributed without any payment, but with a fairly
long moratorium (five to ten years) on the right to sell and lease it out. Since the
per-capita available land in collective and state farms is much less (4-10 hectares
per person depending on local conditions), this distribution policy creates
potential equity problems between new farmers and members of large-scale
farms, who are entitled in law only to their share of the socialized farm land. Land
23
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
is divided between members of collective and state farms in the form of
“conditional shares.” This process normally does not involve physical allocation
of land, although in some exceptional cases large-scale farms have been known
to divide their land in physical form to the members. To get his land, the
individual normally must leave the collective or state farm and become an
independent private farmer.
The Future of Large-Scale Farms
The land reform process has focused the attention on the restructuring of
collective and state farms, which are the main source of land in all countries of
the region, except Poland. The large-scale socialized farms are not suited for
efficient operation under market conditions, and their reorganization is a
necessary step in the transition to a market-based economy.
Structural and organizational reforms in the collective and state farm sector
began independently of land reform legislation almost a decade ago. With time
these changes became more inventive and diverse, and they are now taking
several different forms, all of which can be observed simultaneously:
(a) expansion of individual subsidiary farms within the existing structure
of large-scale collective and state farms and their organization into
“small cooperatives” of several neighboring families;
(b) creation of “lease cooperatives” as comparatively independent profitoriented subdivisions of existing collective and state farms;
(c) conversion of collective and state farms into associations of farmers,
agrofirms, and joint-stock societies;
(d) separation of individual peasant farms or cooperatives from the existing
large-scale farming structure;
(e) complete dismantling of large-scale farms followed by total
privatization of their land and assets.
Although the reorganization began as a spontaneous process, later legislation
adopted in 1990-1992 made the restructuring of large-scale farms compulsory in
most cases. The legislation provided a general framework for the distribution of
land and assets in large-scale farms, but left the responsibility for making the final
choice of new structure with the members. In principle, none of the specific forms
of farming structure is imposed by legislation upon the members.
Restructuring of the farm sector is an ongoing process and its final results will
be different in different countries. In Central and Eastern Europe, this process will
radically reshape the farming structure, although the majority of members
24
3. Land Reform and Future Role of Cooperatives in Former Socialist Countries in Europe
probably will not opt for fully independent private farming. In the former Soviet
Union, the latest statistics indicate that a large proportion of collective and state
farms are undergoing some form of reorganization and restructuring, but very few
large-scale farms actually dissolve and break up into totally independent private
farms. Most of them continue to exist as “federated” structures or “associations
of producers”. Here one of the factors keeping the individuals together is the
developed social infrastructure created and maintained by the collective and state
farms. Further economic reorganization of the agricultural sector in the former
Soviet republics must find acceptable solutions to the problem of social assets,
for instance, by entrusting them to the care of local municipal authorities,
supported by sufficient budgets and taxes.
Lease Cooperatives and Shareholder Structures
Back in the 1980s, the collective and state farms began to entrust well-defined
productive “subdivisions” to the virtually complete responsibility of workers’
teams. This created a direct link between the workers and the results of their labor
and increased the motivation and involvement of the individuals in the final
outcome of the enterprise. These new agricultural structures gradually developed
into independent cost centers within large-scale farms, and some of them recently
began incorporating as independent legal entities. This process automatically
induces a natural de facto transformation of the traditional centralized large-scale
farm into a “federated” structure or an “association of enterprises”, even without
deciding any of the ownership issues.
The intrafarm lease groups, even when incorporated as independent legal
bodies, continue using the central office for a variety of professional services,
including accounting and finance. Since independent purchasing and marketing
is often impracticable within the existing system, the independent groups “sign
contracts” with the central office for these services. The central office usually
receives a certain share of the group profit as a “management fee”.
The privatization legislation and pressures to reorganize have spurred the
creation of independent lease cooperatives as legal entities outside the existing
farming structure. These cooperatives are formed by a number of persons who
lease some of the land and other assets of a collective or state farm. They
sometimes extend their activities beyond traditional livestock and field crop
operations by establishing regional services, such as a repair shop, a garage, a
transport service, a construction team, or even a road-building team. These
services are particularly important for independent farmers in the area, but are
also useful to collective and state farms that may face difficulties as a result of
breakdown of state-monopolized services.
25
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
In the former Soviet republics one of the current options for farm enterprise
restructuring is by division of land and other assets into “conditional shares.”
These are certificates attesting the share of the individual in the total assets of the
farm, without attempting physical division of the assets. The introduction of asset
shares strengthens the independent business orientation and profit motivation of
the intrafarm lease groups. The workers of each group naturally pool their shares
and invest them in the “common business.” Thus, in addition to getting their
wages from current proceeds, they also receive a share of the group’s residual
profit at the end of the year. Other members, in particular pensioners, can “invest”
their shares in productive subdivisions of their choice and thus enjoy “dividends”
while remaining “passive shareholders.” In the future, this form of organization
may actually develop into a common-stock corporation once share tradability and
management issues are resolved.
Meanwhile, however, many collective and state farms in the former Soviet
republics are reorganizing as “joint-stock societies,” although their shares are not
tradeable and not transferable. These joint-stock societies are similar in concept
to the labor-managed firms in Yugoslavia or to the companies that were managed
by so-called enterprise councils in Hungary. These labor-managed structures,
once very popular outside the agricultural sector, have largely failed in Eastern
European countries. While better than the traditional administrative-command
structure, this form of organization is inefficient in the long run because of
pervasive free riding and lack of a real feeling of ownership and involvement.
Also, the short-term consumption preferences of the worker-owners may prevail
and long-term capital investments may be neglected. The decision processes in
such organizations are diffuse, it is impossible to assign individual responsibility,
and the worker-owners continually press the “friendly” management for higher
salaries and greater social benefits without greater personal productivity. The
relative popularity of joint-stock societies among the reorganizing collective and
state farms in the former Soviet Union thus gives reason for concern.
In Central and Eastern Europe, on the other hand, the implementation of recent
legislation creates clear personal ownership of all collective farm assets, including
land. The new owners are free to make decisions concerning their property, and
they may decide to pool their property in the form of a corporate shareholding
structure. These new enterprises bear all the features of Western-type shareholder
corporations with transparent and open ownership structure and separation of
management and employment.
Because of the size of the agricultural sector in the region and the sheer number
of enterprises involved, the reform is slow and difficult. Yet the restructuring of
large-scale farms is a sweeping process that seems to be moving forward at an
26
3. Land Reform and Future Role of Cooperatives in Former Socialist Countries in Europe
accelerating rate. Recent statistics on leasing indicate that 63% of all collective
and state farms in Russia employ some form of lease contracts with producers and
as many as 9% of the farms have instituted lease arrangements in all their
enterprises as of January 1, 1991 (up from 3.8% on January 1, 1990).
Leaseholders in all categories account for 25% of workers in collective and state
farms in Russia as of January 1, 1991 (up from 15% on January 1, 1990). By April
1, 1992, 15% of Russian collective farms and 6% of state farms had decided on
their reorganization mode in line with recent legislation: most of them chose to
reorganize as associations of farmers or as joint-stock societies, without
dismantling. In the Ukraine, nearly one-quarter of collective and state farms had
reorganized in one form or another by mid-1992, and it was expected that over
50% of collective farms and 30% of state farms will have gone through some form
of reorganization by the end of 1992. Restructuring of farm enterprises is also
advancing in all other countries across the region.
What will be the future of collective and state farms in the transforming
agricultural economy of the former socialist countries in Europe? In their
traditional form, these farms are not suited for the market economy: they are too
large and lack profit orientation. In the early stages of the transition, these largescale farms were expected to dissolve and disappear. It is now clear that a high
proportion of collective-farm members do not wish to pursue completely
independent farming, at least not in the short run. They want well-defined and
freely transferable ownership rights and autonomy, as long as these are supported
by the protective net of cooperation. Thus, probably only a small proportion of
large-scale farms will be completely dismantled. New forms of cooperatives will
emerge, focused not on production but primarily on services, processing, and
marketing. This looser form of cooperation will probably pave the way for the
ultimate shift to individual farming at a later stage.
First Experiences with Private Farming and Farm Enterprise
Restructuring
A new phenomenon in agriculture in the former socialist countries is the
development of peasant farms outside the traditional framework of large-scale
collective and state farms. As indicated previously, the creation of these
non-collective farms was enabled by special legislation adopted by different
countries in 1990-1991. They are widely promoted by the governments and
receive generous financial support.
The number of individual peasant farms is increasing at an impressive rate.
Thus, in Russia the number of individual peasant farms increased from 231 farms
27
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
in April 1990 to nearly 35,000 farms in November 1991 and over 120,000 farms
in June 1992. In Ukraine, the number of private farms increased from 2000 in
1991 to 10,000 in the autumn of 1992. These farms are quite small, however: an
average of around 40 hectares in Russia and 20 hectares in Ukraine (compared to
several thousand hectares in an average collective or state farm). Despite the
impressive growth, they still account for a minute percentage of agricultural
product in most countries. Apart from Poland, the only exceptions are countries
like Albania, Armenia, and Romania, where the level of collective agriculture had
never been very advanced and the collective farms were completely dismantled
soon after the change of the political regime. In these countries, however, the
private farms exist on the level of subsistence agriculture, similarly to the private
farms in China.
New farms are often created by persons not immediately employed in
agriculture. In Russia, according to June 1991 data, only about 30% of all private
farmers are former members of collective and state farms; the remaining 70% are
from the cities, although the law requires that to be eligible for allocation of
farming land they must have some agricultural background or at least training.
Thus, in Russia as in other countries of the region, farmers are not rushing to take
advantage of the new legislation which allows them to receive land for
independent individual farming.
The conditions for fully independent private farming beyond the level of
subsistence agriculture and local markets still do not exist in most countries.
Indeed, difficulties with availability of agricultural machinery, input supply, and
product marketing are cited as the main reasons for the reluctance of members of
collective and state farms to switch to independent farming. There are practically
no input supply and product marketing channels outside the rigid state monopoly.
There is no network of rural shops that sell inputs and implements to private
farmers and no system for farm-level purchase or wholesale of agricultural
products. The existing auctions, exchanges, and farmers’ markets, and insufficient
to handle the full volume of agricultural product. The transportation system is
inadequate. Technical services and equipment are hardly available for private
farmers. There is no commercial credit and banking system to finance
independent farming operations. Above all, cooperative members and state farm
employees have a very limited knowledge of business operations, financing,
accounting, taxation, and risk management. Because of these obstacles,
cooperation among private farmers is essential - in finance, in marketing, in
technical services.
The model of division of large-scale farms into smaller profit-motivated
functional units supported by cooperative services appears to provide a fairly
28
3. Land Reform and Future Role of Cooperatives in Former Socialist Countries in Europe
faithful generalization of the diversity of reorganization modes which are
occurring in the agricultural sector all over the region. The fledgling private farm
sector, which basically represents the extreme form of division to the stage of total
separation from the large-scale farm, is also beginning to develop some
cooperative structures. Private farmers begin to realize that totally independent
individual farming is very difficult, especially in the present economic
environment. They begin to share machinery and equipment, to cooperate in
purchasing of supplies and marketing of products, to pool their land resources in
order to achieve more efficient cultivation, and even to establish joint “industrial”
enterprises to augment their income from agriculture. We are thus witnessing a
confluence of two streams in agriculture: large-scale farms split into smaller units
supported by cooperative structures, while small-scale individual farmers go
through a process of cooperativization creating functionally similar support
structures. This suggests that Western-type service cooperatives will play an
important role in the future of the farming sector in the region.
Role of Western-Type Service Cooperatives
While full privatization of agricultural production is legally and economically
feasible, there is strong evidence that most rural residents in the former socialist
countries admit that they are not ready for independent farming. Their reluctance
is understandable in view of political uncertainty, the inadequacy of
infrastructure, and almost total absence of market structures. This appears to
provide an opportunity for the development of Western-style cooperative
organizations, whose function is often described in economic theory as correcting
for market failure, that is, enabling producers to function even in the absence of
fully developed markets.
Production cooperatives are almost unknown in the West (with the notable
exception of Israel). Indeed, European experience suggests that production
cooperatives are not a very successful and efficient form of organization.
Production should be private: on private farms, in private dairy enterprises, and
so forth. But beyond production, there is a large scope for the creation of
cooperatives that will serve all the villages within the scope of a former largescale farm.
Service cooperatives, which specialize in provision of agricultural inputs and
marketing of agricultural products, are the dominant form of cooperation in the
West. In addition to correcting for market failure, service coops also strive to
maximize economies of size by organizing their facilities on a regional basis, and
not village by village. The establishment of service cooperatives relieves the
29
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
farmers from the responsibility for marketing and purchasing activities and
enables them to concentrate on production. Service cooperatives often establish
processing facilities, which avoid exploitation of farmers by private enterprises
and improve members’ welfare through vertical integration into value-added
processing.
Cooperatives also can be established to develop local and regional
infrastructure, especially if it is neglected by the state. Another important function
of cooperatives may be to provide accounting, financial, and professional
services. These “consulting” cooperatives will build on the considerable
knowledge and experience of the qualified experts and managers currently
employed by the large-scale farms. Instead of paying for inputs, trucking, or use
of machinery, the producers will pay for professional and administrative services
provided by experts, who in turn will receive a salary or a retainer from the
cooperative. The experts themselves are not members of the cooperative: they are
the resources employed by the cooperative.
In the cooperative paradigm, the reorganized agricultural system that would
emerge from the former large-scale farms can be viewed as an extension and a
modification of the Israeli moshav model. Private agricultural production, based
both on family farms and on larger multifamily enterprises, will be supported by
a range of service cooperatives whose function will be to correct for market failure
and to exploit economies of size. These cooperatives may be responsible for
agricultural machinery, for purchase and delivery of agricultural inputs, and for
shipping out and marketing of agricultural products. The service cooperatives
may be organized regionally by function and enterprise, as is common in Western
countries: dairy cooperatives, poultry cooperatives, grain cooperatives, fruit and
vegetable cooperatives, and so forth. New private service cooperatives can be
based on the core of the existing cooperative farms. Farmers should be free,
however, to choose the forms of cooperation they prefer, and the new cooperation
must be based on private ownership and competition.
In the present environment of high uncertainty and inadequate market
structures, regional service cooperatives may provide the necessary reinforcement
and backing to the emerging private sector in the former socialist countries by
imbuing the new farmers with a sense of collective strength and shielding them
to a certain extent from market imperfections. The establishment of service
cooperatives should not rule out the establishment of private firms in the same
lines of business. Competition between the two forms of organization would only
improve the economic efficiency of the system by providing the producers with a
greater variety of options.
30
3. Land Reform and Future Role of Cooperatives in Former Socialist Countries in Europe
There is no experience with private cooperatives in the former socialist
countries and only limited information is available on this subject. The
establishment of the new cooperatives therefore should be supported by the
government as a public good. International aid may be appropriate in this area in
the form of training programs and direct technical assistance. Promotion programs
(advice, technical assistance, etc.) also should be organized to help farmers who
opt for fully independent farming.
Conclusion
Land-reform and privatization legislation in the former Soviet Union and in
Central and Eastern Europe has opened possibilities for the development of
private family farming. Members of collective and state farms, however, are not
rushing to leave the large-scale socialized structures and establish independent
farms on private land. Instead, the large-scale farms are reorganizing into smaller
and more efficient productive subdivisions whose assets and profits are owned by
the team members and which continue to rely on cooperative supply, marketing,
and financial services provided by the central farm structures. The new
independent farmers are also forming cooperative organizations to help them
overcome the difficulties caused by nonexistence of input and product markets.
The farming structure is developing toward private production, both in family
farms and in larger multifamily enterprises, which may be supported by a net of
service cooperatives.
The process of private farm development in the former Socialist countries is
taking a course which seems to be different from the original expectations of
many Western observers. It is already quite clear that rapid full-fledged
privatization will not take place in the region, with the exception of only few
countries. It is also quite probable that Western-type family farms will not be the
major farming structure for a long time to come. Private farms in the former
Socialist countries will probably evolve toward two extremes: either small
subsistence farms with little commercial agriculture or relatively large diversified
agribusinesses with several hundred hectares of farmland and processing
facilities. The major agricultural structure in these countries in all probability will
be based on various forms of private-owned cooperatives.
References
Braverman A. and J.L. Guasch. 1990. “Agricultural Reform in Developing
Countries: Reflections for Eastern Europe,” American Journal of Agricultural
Economics, 72(5): 1743-1751.
31
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
Brooks K. 1991. “Decollectivization and the Agricultural Transition in Eastern
and Central Europe,” Policy, Research, and External Affairs Working Papers
WPS 793, The World Bank, Washington, D.C.
Brooks K., J.L. Guasch, A. Braverman, and C. Csaki. 1991. “Agriculture and the
Transition to the Market,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 5(4): 149-161.
Cochrane N.J. 1989. Agricultural Statistics of Eastern Europe and the Soviet
Union, 1965-85, USDA Economic Research Service, Statistical Bulletin No.
778, Washington, D.C., July.
Csaki C. 1990. “Agricultural Change in Eastern Europe at the Beginning of the
1990s,” American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 72(5): 1733-1742.
Csaki C. 1991. “Agriculture and Agricultural Policy in Eastern Europe,” in:
Agricultural Economics and Policy: International Challenges for the Nineties,
Elsevier, Amsterdam.
Kovacs, J.M. and M. Tardos, eds. 1992. Reform and Transformation in Eastern
Europe: Soviet-Type Economies on the Threshold of Change, Routledge,
London.
OECD. 1991. The Soviet Agro-Food System and Agricultural Trade: Prospects
for Reform, Paris, Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development.
Wadekin K.E. and J.L. Brada, eds. 1988. Socialist Agriculture in Transition,
Westview, Boulder. Co.
World Bank. 1992. Food and Agricultural Policy Reforms in the Former USSR:
An Agenda for the Transition, Studies in Economics of Transformation Paper
Number 1, The World Bank, Washington, D.C.
32
4. Transformation of Cooperative Farms
in Central and Eastern Europe
Zvi Lerman and Csaba Csaki (2000)
Agriculture has been at the center of attention of politicians and policy makers
in Central Eastern Europe (CEE) since the beginning of transition in 1989. This
is attributable, at least in part, to the relatively high importance of the agricultural
sector in this region as measured both by its share in GDP and, perhaps most
significantly, by its share in total employment. Thus, during the 1980s, the last
decade before transition, agriculture contributed nearly 20% of GDP and
employed more than 20% of the labor force in most CEE countries.
Czechoslovakia and Slovenia were the only exceptions, but even in these “nonagrarian” countries the agriculture’s share was around 10% of GDP and total
employment. To put these numbers in perspective, they should be compared with
the 15 EU countries, where the share of agriculture during the same decade was
around 4% of GDP and 8% of employment. And yet the lobbying power of EU
farmers is such that agricultural policy is always in the limelight of EU politics.
Because of the special role of agriculture in CEE and the political prominence of
this sector in the EU, it is appropriate to carry out an assessment of the changes
in the structure of the farm sector in transition countries.
Because of agriculture’s large share in the economy and especially in rural
employment, improvements in agricultural productivity through market-oriented
reforms were originally expected to act as an engine of change and growth for all
sectors in the CEE countries. The transition of agriculture from plan to market is
a complex multidimensional process. Land reform and restructuring of large
socialized farms – the topic of our paper – are perhaps the most visible and widely
discussed components of this process. Yet agricultural transition includes other
essential dimensions, such as development of functioning market services (both
upstream for input supply and downstream for product marketing and processing),
reduction of government intervention, emergence of rural credit institutions,
33
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
technological improvement, new capital investment patterns, agricultural labor
adjustment. These dimensions of change are both affected by, and impact on, the
process of land reform and farm restructuring. They are moreover interrelated
with political forces, democratization of society, and other profound adjustments
that accompany the transition from the pre-1990 reality to the world of the 21st
century. The present paper provides a status report of land reform and farm
restructuring in ten CEE countries that are candidates for accession to the EU in
the near future and, at the end, briefly examines the intriguing interrelationships
between land reform, growth, and political factors.
The Inherited System
The CEE countries embarked in 1989 on a program of land reform and farm
restructuring as a part of an overall strategy of transition to the market. Table 4.1
lists the main features of the inherited socialist system in agriculture, which set it
apart from market-oriented agriculture and were responsible for its chronic
inefficiency. Figure 4.1 illustrates the structure of land holdings in the socialist
farm sector, clearly highlighting the dominance of production cooperatives and
state farms and the low share of individual farming (except in Poland). The CEE
farming structure on the eve of transition sharply deviated from that observed in
market economies, where individual farms dominate and corporate farms are
substantially smaller than the socialist cooperatives. Thus, in the USA, individual
or family farms control 80% of agricultural land. Moreover, 90% of corporate
farms are classified as family-held corporations, i.e., extensions of family farms
incorporated mainly for tax reasons. The average farm size in the USA is less than
200 hectares, and the corporate farms (about 5% of all farming units) average
about 600 hectares. The farm sizes in the EU are much smaller, with farms in the
UK (the EU country with by far the largest farms) averaging 70 hectares.
Table 4.1. Inherited features of socialist agriculture
Attribute
Shortcomings
Confused ownership of
land
Collective organization
of production
Large farms (2,000 ha,
500 workers)
Lifetime employment
policy for farm members
Centrally prescribed
production targets
Soft budget constraints
Private ownership without real property rights; dominant state and
cooperative ownership
Inefficient due to free riding, moral hazard, lack of individual incentives
Inefficient due to high monitoring costs, anonymity, lack of transparency
Inefficient due to inability to control costs by adjusting labor
Inefficient due to lack of consumer orientation, insensitivity to market
signals
Inefficient due to lack of profit orientation, reliance on writeoffs and
subsidies
34
4. Transformation of Cooperative Farms in Central and Eastern Europe
100%
80%
60%
40%
20%
0%
Pol
Czs
Hun
State farms
Rom
Lit
Cooperatives
Lat
Est
Bul
Figure 4.1. Structure of land
holdings in socialist farms
prior to 1990.
Individual
The structure and organization of socialist agriculture were thus basically
incompatible with a market-oriented economy. The main economic goal was to
transform the agricultural sector from a centrally planned command system to a
more efficient market-oriented system. This involved the need for macroeconomic and sectoral adjustments including elimination of central controls and
introduction of hard budget constraints, as well as privatization of land ownership,
a shift from collective to individual agriculture, and general downsizing of farms
in line with the evidence of farm organization and farm sizes in market economies.
In fact, the reform program was driven by a mixture of economic and political
objectives. The purely economic goal of efficiency improvement was augmented
by a set of political objectives, which were motivated by the desire to break with
the Soviet-dominated past and do justice to the former owners, who lost their
property rights after World War II. Both sets of objectives predicated a transition
from collective agriculture managed through central planning to agriculture based
on private property, where producers control their farming decisions in response
to market incentives. The economic objectives focused on restructuring of the
traditional large farms. The political objectives, in addition to justifying the
elimination of production cooperatives and state farms, tilted the land
privatization strategy toward restitution to former owners (rather than distribution
to workers). The CEE land reform program thus involved two intertwined strands
of privatization and farm restructuring, which were expected to improve the
efficiency and productivity of agriculture and at the same time wipe out the main
features of a politically undesirable heritage.
Privatization of Land
Private land ownership did not cease in most CEE countries after World War
II. The only exceptions were the three Baltic states, where land was fully
nationalized when Estonia, Latvia, and Lithuania were absorbed in the Soviet
35
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
Union. (Albania also nationalized the land by its 1952 constitution, but this
country remains outside the scope of our discussion.) Yet even in countries
outside the Baltic states, the land was predominantly cultivated by cooperatives
and state farms all through the socialist era (see Figure 4.1). Despite collective
cultivation, much of the land (outside the Baltics) remained nominally in private
ownership, and the owners’ property was actually registered in the old cadastre,
which survived the war and the socialist takeover. Some of the land reverted to
cooperative ownership as former owners or their heirs left the cooperative and
moved to the city (this phenomenon was particularly common in Hungary). Some
of the land – primarily the land controlled by state farms – was nationalized
through expropriation from large estates, the Church, Nazi collaborators, or other
politically suspect individuals.
Privatization of land was one of the first items on the reform agenda of all CEE
governments after 1989. Who may own agricultural land in CEE? All countries
allow private ownership of land by individuals, i.e., physical persons who are
nationals of the country in question. Some CEE countries (Estonia, Lithuania,
Hungary) prohibit land ownership by legal entities. Cooperatives, corporations,
and other private companies may own non-land assets, but must lease their land
resources from individual land owners or the state. Finally, most countries
prohibit ownership of agricultural land by foreign residents, or severely restrict
the ownership rights of foreigners. This restriction of foreign ownership is a
serious obstacle in the process of EU accession, as EU laws require that there can
be no discrimination in land ownership rights for all nationals of member states.
The CEE countries chose to privatize land mainly by restitution to former
owners. Poland is an exception to the restitution strategy, as the previous postWorld War II land reform in this country distributed most of the estate lands to
smallholders. Any demand for the Polish smallholders to give up their allotments
in favor of former large estate owners would be politically and socially untenable,
and the state accordingly focused on privatizing, through auctions and sale, the
20% of land that had been nationalized and transferred to state farms. For similar
social reasons, the CEE countries did not extend their restitution programs to
ownership rights before World War II and accepted the outcomes of the land
reform that was implemented immediately following the liberation from Nazi
occupation after World War II. Among the CEE countries with a restitution
agenda, only Hungary and Romania recognized the rights of the current tiller who
was not a former land owner and thus was not eligible to restitution: in the interest
of social equity, land from cooperative and state reserves was also distributed
without payment to agricultural workers in these two countries. In all other CEE
36
4. Transformation of Cooperative Farms in Central and Eastern Europe
countries, the current tillers had to pay for land, although they received “firstrefusal” rights to the land that they were cultivating at the time.
Restitution affected land that had shifted after World War II to cooperative or
state ownership. It did not affect land that had always remained in private
ownership. The actual restitution strategies differed among countries, ranging
from flexible restitution in the form of transferrable value-denominated
certificates in Hungary to rigid restitution of the original physical plots in Estonia.
Yet in all countries the restitution process ran into considerable delays due to
technical difficulties of identifying the claims, registering the privatized plots, and
issuing titles to beneficiaries. Political indecisiveness and frequent course changes
in some of the countries were not conducive to smooth progress of restitution
either. At the end of the decade, the restitution process has been largely completed
in practice, although final ownership titles have been issued to a relatively small
proportion of claimants. In some cases, much of the state-owned land have not
been claimed by former owners, and governments have targets for further
reduction of state land reserves through continuing privatization (Table 4.2).
Even in Poland, where more than three-quarters of land remained privately owned
after World War II and only about 20% in total had to be privatized, the progress
with privatization has been less than satisfactory and the state still owns 15% of
land.
Table 4.2. Privatization of Agricultural Land in Selected CEE Countries (1997-1998 status)
Lithuania
Estonia
Romania
Czech Rep.
Poland
Privatized (final title)
37%
57%
71%
81%
85%
State-owned
63%
43% (target 36%)
29%
19% (target 9%)
15%
Despite the lack of formal titles and deficiencies in registration of ownership,
all countries have procedures that allow users to lease plots from the large pool of
state-owned land. Many corporations take advantage of this option by leasing land
from the state. Many individuals use land that they have received through the
restitution process although they still do not have a final title to this land and it is
not counted as privatized in the official statistics. The available figures for
privatization of agricultural land (Table 4.2) therefore understate the actual use
of land by private producers. It is quite clear that, at present, state-owned land is
not cultivated by the state. Most of the land still registered as state-owned is in
fact cultivated by private individuals and private corporate farms (companies),
37
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
because the formerly powerful state farms have been dismantled or transformed
into private organizations.
Individualization of Agriculture
There is a sharp distinction between ownership of land and tenure or use of
land. This distinction applies everywhere in the world, but especially in the
context of transition, where land privatization suffers from technical and political
delays, while use of land continues. To differentiate between the processes
associated with these two distinct concepts in transition economies we use two
terms, “privatization of land” to describe transfer of land into private (as opposed
to state or collective) ownership, regardless of its use, and “individualization of
farming” to describe transition to individual (as opposed to collective) cultivation,
regardless of the ownership of cultivated land. Farming companies and corporate
farms, even if run as private businesses with private ownership of land and assets,
are not regarded as individual farms, primarily because of their management and
share-ownership structure.
Individual agriculture is possible without land privatization, and land
privatization does not necessarily create individual farmers. Restitution usually
involves allocation of physical land plots to beneficiaries (heirs of original
owners), either through direct assignment or ultimately through auction
mechanisms. Yet whether or not the physical allocation of plots leads to
individualization of farming depends on what the owners decide to do with their
newly recovered land. Some land owners – mainly rural residents – may take
possession of their land and switch from collective to individual farming. Other
individuals may lease their land to large corporate farms or enterprising farmers.
Different motivations are possible for the mutually exclusive decisions to
cultivate privately owned land individually or lease it out. Individual risk
preferences provide one explanation: some land owners prefer the safety of the
collective or corporate umbrella, with its professional management, to the
unfamiliar risks of individual farming. Another explanation is that many
beneficiaries left farming long ago and now have jobs and property in urban areas.
Some restitution claimants may even have left the country: Hungary, for instance,
recognizes the rights of heir of former owners who live abroad. All these
individuals have no immediate personal use for their restituted land, and
entrusting it to a larger corporation or cooperative makes good economic sense.
These new land owners, of course, also have the option of leasing their land to
other individuals who are actively engaged in farming and seek to increase their
holdings. Leasing to private individuals, however, may look more risky than
38
4. Transformation of Cooperative Farms in Central and Eastern Europe
leasing to a large organization, which is regarded as a more reliable source of
lease payments.
Individually cultivated land has increased dramatically in all countries of the
region since the beginning of transition (Figure 4.2). In Slovenia, Poland, and
Latvia practically all land is in individual tenure and there are no large collective
or corporate farms. The change has been particularly striking in Latvia, where,
prior to 1990, less than 5% of agricultural land was in individual tenure (Slovenia
and Poland never had a large collective farm sector). In most other CEE countries,
the share of individually cultivated land is around 50%-60%, up from 5%-10%
before 1990 (only the two components of former Czechoslovakia lag in this
respect). Overall, the available data show that 65% of agricultural land across the
CEE countries is in individual tenure (as of 1997).
100
80
60
40
20
0
Svn
Pol
Lat
Lit
Est
Rom
1990
Hun
Bul
Cz
Svk
ECE*
Figure 4.2. Land in
individual tenure 1990 and
1997.
1997
* Without Poland and Slovenia
Our emphasis on the distinction between individualization and privatization is
attributable to two main sets of factors. First, individual farming is the dominant
organizational form in market economies. As long as production is managed
collectively or cooperatively, the organization is exposed to the dangers of moral
hazard, shirking, and free-riding that may severely impair its economic
performance. This is the standard argument against production cooperatives and
collectives, which are seldom observed in market economies. Private companies
and corporations, even when not organized as cooperatives, suffer from
transaction costs associated with principal agent arrangements and labor
monitoring difficulties, and their spread in market agricultures is also limited due
to elusiveness of scale economies in farming. As noted previously, corporate
farms control not more than 20% of agricultural land in USA, and only about onetenth of these farms are true investor-owned corporations; the rest are basically
family farms that incorporated for a variety of tax reasons.
39
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
Second, farms in market economies are not restricted to operator’s own land,
and farmers increasingly rely on land that they lease in from others. Thus, in
Belgium, France, and Germany, over 60% of land in farms is leased, and not
owned by the farmer. On average across the 15 countries of the EU, farmers lease
in 40% of land that they cultivate. In the USA, only one-third of farm land is fully
owned by the operator, and this percentage has been declining steadily since 1950,
while the percentage of leased land in farms has been increasing. Analysis of the
EU data shows that individual farms using a higher percentage of leased land are
on average larger: farms using more than 30% of leased land average 39 hectares
across the 15 EU countries, while farms using less than 30% of leased land
average only 18 hectares. In the USA, farms in which land is fully owned by the
operator average about 100 hectares, while farms in which owned land is
augmented by leased land are more than three times as large (340 hectares on
average). Surveys conducted by the World Bank and Phare/ACE in some CEE
countries also show that individual farms with leased land are significantly larger
than farms using own land only. Thus, in Hungary individual farms that lease land
average 20 hectare compared with 3 hectares for farms without leased land, in
Bulgaria 5 hectares compared with 1 hectare, and in Romania 4 hectares
compared with 3 hectares. The frequency of land leasing among individual farms
in CEE countries, however, is still very low, much lower than the frequency of
leasing among farms in EU and USA.
Leasing, and not land ownership, appears to be the important mechanism for
increasing farm sizes in market economies. Farms need not be constrained by the
limited availability of own land: farm sizes can adjust through land leasing as long
as farmers are guaranteed secure tenure and market institutions are available for
reasonably smooth transfer of land use rights. Thus, there is no reason to be
concerned about excessive fragmentation of land produced by various land reform
strategies. Initial fragmentation that may arise through certain allocation and
distribution procedures will be quickly corrected by market mechanisms if land
markets are indeed allowed to function.
Restructuring of Farms
Prior to 1990, production cooperatives and state farms cultivated around 90%
of agricultural land in the CEE countries (except Poland and Slovenia). After a
decade of transition, the share of large farms that succeeded the traditional
socialized farm is down to 40% of agricultural land (Figure 4.3). The decline in
the share of land controlled by large farms has been accompanied by significant
reorganization and restructuring of the sector. In addition to the significant
increase in the amount of individually cultivated land, the process has led to
40
4. Transformation of Cooperative Farms in Central and Eastern Europe
virtual elimination of state farms, drastic reduction in the importance of
cooperatives, and creation of a new category of private corporate farms
(companies). The farms in all organizational categories are now substantially
smaller than the former cooperatives and state farms. The individual farms, on the
other hand, are larger (see Table 4.3 below).
100%
80%
Individual
Corporate
Cooperative
State
60%
40%
20%
Figure 4.3. Distribution of
farm land by organizational
form before and after 1990.
0%
Pre-1990
Post-1990
As the share of traditional production cooperatives and state farms declined
through restitution and restructuring, new corporate farm structures began to
emerge in the CEE countries. Unfortunately, no comprehensive data are available
on the operation and management of these new entities, but case studies suggest
that in Hungary, the Czech Republic, and Estonia many of the large farms have
transformed into market-driven corporations. In Romania, at least some of the
large farms are new associations or cooperatives created voluntarily by individual
landowners after the completion of land privatization. The large corporate or
cooperative farms in CEE are now often forced to operate under hard budget
constraints, with a real threat of bankruptcy proceedings in case of default.
Figure 4.4 is a schematic diagram of farm restructuring in CEE, illustrating
the processes that have led to the growth of the individual sector and the
reorganization of the socialized farm sector. The changes in farm structure are
driven primarily by three processes: restitution of land ownership, privatization
of state property, and reorganization of cooperatives into new private companies.
Restitution is the main channel for the growth of the individual sector, as it shifts
land resources from former cooperatives and state farms to new individual
owners. Land not claimed by individuals remains in state ownership. Privatization
of non-land assets of state farms through open auction and sale mechanisms (i.e.,
through channels other than restitution to former owners) leads to creation of new
corporations or companies, which may be classified as state-controlled (with
minority private interests) or private (with majority private shareholders). Finally,
cooperatives may reorganize creating new private corporations or new,
41
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
sometimes smaller cooperatives. In some countries (Estonia, Lithuania,
Hungary), the various corporate forms (“legal bodies”) cannot own land: they
lease their land resources from physical persons.
Initial structure
State farms
Privatization of
state property
Reorganization
New structure
Statecontrolled
corporations
Adjustment
by leasing
Leasing to
legal entities
Private
corporations
Cooperatives
Cooperatives
Restitution of
land ownership
Individual
farms
Non-farming
land owners
Leasing from
non-farmers
Leasing to
individuals
Individual
farms
Leasing
among
farmers
Figure 4.4. Schema of the process of farm restructuring in CEE.
The transition from the initial inherited structure to a new structure is just the
first stage in the overall process. The changes in farm structure continue as a
dynamic adjustment of farm sizes through land transactions. These are mainly
leasing transactions, as buying and selling of land is reported fairly seldom.
Individual recipients of restituted land who are not interested in farming may lease
their allotments to corporations or other individuals. On the other hand,
enterprising individuals may seek to increase their holdings by leasing surplus
land from cooperatives and corporations (in countries where corporate land
ownership is allowed). Land markets thus sustain transfer of land resources to
more active and more efficient producers, leading to gradual optimization of the
farm sector through restructuring.
Emerging Farm Structure
Large-scale cooperatives or corporate farms continue to play an important role
in agriculture in CEE outside Latvia, Poland, and Slovenia. In seven CEE
42
4. Transformation of Cooperative Farms in Central and Eastern Europe
countries (Hungary, Bulgaria, Romania, Czech Republic, Slovakia, Estonia, and
Lithuania) about 40% of agricultural land is in large-scale non-individual farms.
However, the diversity of large farm structures today is much greater than prior
to 1990, when the Soviet-style cooperative and state farm were the only two
organizational forms in socialist agriculture. While traditional cooperatives and
state farms persist (in greatly reduced numbers), new corporate farming structures
are registering as joint-stock societies, limited-liability partnerships, and private
companies. The new large farms in some CEE countries, certainly those in
Hungary and the Czech Republic, are profit-motivated business corporations with
freedom to adjust their labor force to operating needs and to reward labor
according to performance. Moreover, these farms operate under hard budget
constraints that impose strict financial discipline and rule out reliance on
government bailouts.
Changes are also observed in the average farm size in CEE countries. We have
noted previously that the socialized agriculture was characterized by substantially
larger farms than the market economies. Although large farms continue to
dominate the agriculture in most transition economies, a definite downsizing is
observed since 1990. Large collectives, cooperatives, and state farms have been
losing land through restitution and privatization. Internal restructuring of large
farms in an attempt to achieve better market orientation has often led to division
of the original enterprise into two or three smaller units. As a result of these
processes, cooperatives and state farms in CEE are now substantially smaller than
in the pre-1990 period (Table 4.3). The new corporate farms created in the
process of farm transformation in CEE countries are also smaller on average than
the traditional cooperatives and state farms, although they are still large by the
standards of market economy (Figure 4.5). Unfortunately, the available data
make it impossible to determine if the downsizing of large farms is a continuing
dynamic phenomenon, or if it was a one-time adjustment. Experience in market
economies definitely suggests that further downsizing of large farm enterprises in
CEE is desirable.
While the very large socialist farms have become smaller, the average size of
individual holdings, be it household plots or other family farms, has increased
substantially across the region. The increase of individual farms in CEE is clearly
shown in Table 4.3. There is some evidence that the individual farms in CEE are
gradually differentiating into two distinct groups: very small units cultivated by
part-time farmers (successors of the subsistence-oriented household plots from
the pre-1990 era) and larger commercially oriented full-time individual farms,
which are in fact responsible for the observed increase of the average farm size in
the individual sector in CEE. As a result of the opposing processes that reduce the
43
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
size of collectives and augment the individual holdings, while creating a new
intermediate layer of larger individual farms, the agriculture in transition
economies may be gradually losing the sharply bimodal structure that
traditionally characterized the farms in the socialist era. This in itself will be a
change in the direction of greater compatibility with farm structures observed in
market economies.
Table 4.3. Average Farm Sizes by Organizational Form in CEE Countries (in hectares)
Individual farms
New
corporate
forms
Pre-1990
Current
Pre-1990
Current
Current
Pre-1990
Current
Bulgaria
4,000
637
1,615
735
–
0.4
1.4
Czech Rep.
2,578
1,447
9,443
521
690
5.0
34.0
Slovakia
2,667
1,509
5,186
3,056
1,191
0.3
7.7
Hungary
4,179
833
7,138
7,779
204
0.3
3.0
Poland
335
222
3,140
620
333
6.6
7.0
Romania
2,374
451
5,001
3,657
–
0.5
2.7
Estonia
4,060
–
4,206
–
449
0.2
19.8
Latvia
5,980
–
6,532
340
309
0.4
23.6
Lithuania #
2,380
–
1,880
–
310
0.5
7.6
Slovenia
–
–
470
371
–
3.2
4.8
# Average size of collective, state, and corporate farms in Lithuania is based on unpublished OECD
data.
Source: Agricultural Situation and Prospects in the Central and Eastern European Countries:
Summary Report, European Commission, Directorate-General for Agriculture (DG VI), Brussels,
1998.
Collective/cooperative
farms
6
State farms
thou. ha
5
4
Pre-1990
Post-1990
3
2
Figure 4.5. Downsizing of
large farms during the
transition.
1
0
State
Cooperative
Corporate
To examine the extent of the adjustment in farm structures during transition,
it is useful to compare the farm size distribution in CEE with that observed in
market economies. In Figure 4.6, panel (a) shows the aggregated land
concentration curve for farms in the 15 countries of the European Union (EU15),
constructed from Eurostat data. Land concentration is presented by a standard
44
4. Transformation of Cooperative Farms in Central and Eastern Europe
“Lorenz inequality curve” in which the vertical axis gives the cumulative
percentage of land used in farms and the horizontal axis gives the cumulative
percentage of farms of all types, ranked by size. The straight diagonal line
represents the situation of “ideal equality,” when land is uniformly distributed
over all farms so that 50% of farms, say, account for 50% of land. The downwardbulging curve reflects the actual farm structure in the EU, with land use distributed
nonuniformly over small and large farms. From this curve, the bottom 50% of EU
farms (the smallest farms by size) account for 10% of land use, while the top 10%
of EU farms (the largest farms by size) account for 40% of land use. The land
concentration curves for USA and Canada are virtually identical with the EU
curve in Figure 6; this pattern of land concentration therefore may be accepted as
representative of market economies.
Other panels in Figure 4.6 present land concentration curves of the ten CEE
countries. The CEE land concentration curves are based on available official
statistical data on farm size distribution, which are unfortunately weak. In
constructing these curves, we always tried to estimate the number of farming units
that control all agricultural land in each country. In this way, the distribution
curves include household plots, semi-commercial and commercial family farms,
and the larger corporate structures. The land concentration curves are based on
the actual use of land, and are not directly related to land ownership. We should
stress that the land concentration curves define “small” and “large” in strictly
relative, and not absolute, terms; nor do they provide an indication of average
farm sizes in different countries. The absolute size of farms varies across countries
depending on the available land resources and the number of beneficiaries (i.e.,
the rural population). Land concentration curves abstract from these factors and
only present the relative pattern of distribution of farm sizes.
The land concentration curves in Figure 4.6 demonstrate the three main farm
structure patterns observed in CEE transition economies. Four countries –
Bulgaria, Hungary, Czech Republic, and Slovakia – sharply deviates from the
market pattern. Here 90% of farming units (the small household plots and family
farms) control less than 10% of land, and the top 10% of farming units – the
largest collective and corporate farms – control about 90% of land. This pattern
is a manifestation of a sharply dual farm structure, with millions or hundreds of
thousands of very small farms at the bottom end of the size scale and thousands
or merely hundreds of very large farms at the top end. The sharply dual farm
structure was a dominant feature of the Soviet model of agriculture in the pretransition era, with an even more dramatic concentration of land than what we
observe today: 98% of Soviet farms (the millions of small household plots in the
individual sector) controlled less than 2% of land, while 2% of the largest farm
45
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
enterprises controlled 98% of land. The encouraging changes in farm structures
discussed in previous paragraphs have measurably shifted the land concentration
curves for the CEE countries, but they have been insufficient so far to produce a
significant change in the sharply dual structure of traditional socialist agriculture
in the four countries of the first group.
(a) Concentration of Farm Land in the European Union (EU15)
percent of land
100
80
60
40
20
0
0
20
40
60
80
100
percent of farms
(b) Bulgaria
(c) Hungary
100
percent of land
percent of land
100
80
80
60
60
40
40
20
20
0
0
0
0
20
40
60
80
20
60
80
100
percent of farms
Based on 1.2 million farms
(e) Czech Republic
(d) Slovakia
100
40
100
percent of farms
percent of land
100
percent of land
80
80
60
60
40
40
20
20
0
0
0
0
20
40
60
percent of farms
80
20
40
60
80
100
percent of farms
100
Includes 500,000 household plots
Figure 4.6. Concentration of farm land in 15 countries of the European Union (panel a) and in ten
CEE countries (panels b-k).
46
4. Transformation of Cooperative Farms in Central and Eastern Europe
(f) Poland
(g) Slovenia
percent of land
100
100
80
80
60
60
40
40
20
20
0
percent of land
0
0
20
40
60
80
100
0
20
40
percent of farms
60
80
100
percent of farms
Based on 3.1 million farms from 1996 census
Based on 141,000 units, including estimated 50,000 household plots
(h) Romania
(i) Estonia
100
percent of land
100
80
80
60
60
40
40
percent of land
20
20
0
0
0
0
20
40
60
80
20
100
percent of farms
60
80
100
80
100
percent of farms
(j) Lithuania
100
40
Data by Kivistik and Elmet, Tartu Univ.
(k) Latvia
precent of land
100
80
80
60
60
40
40
20
percent of land
20
0
0
0
20
40
60
80
100
0
20
percent of farms
Based on 220,000 private farms, 313,000 household plots
40
60
percent of farms
Includes 156,000 household plots
Figure 4.6 (continued).
47
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
Romania and Estonia and representatives of the second group of land
concentration patterns. These two countries, starting with a sharply dual Soviet
pattern, have developed in the process of transition farm structures that are close
to the market pattern of land concentration. Slovenia and Poland are also
characterized by “normal” land concentration curves, although this probably is
not a result of transition-related adjustment: the farm structure in these countries
has always been characterized by predominance of small and medium-size farms
and has not changed much since 1990. Latvia and Lithuania, on the other hand,
seem to have overshot in the process of adjustment, and their farm structures today
are over-fragmented compared with market economies.
Table 4.4 summarizes the differences in farm structures across CEE by
presenting our land concentration measure – the percentage of agricultural land
controlled by the top 10% of largest farms in each country. If we accept the market
pattern in Figure 6(a) as an efficiency-optimizing equilibrium farm structure, then
countries with sharply dual farm structures – Bulgaria, Hungary, Czech Republic,
Slovakia – can be expected to undergo further downsizing of large farm
enterprises and simultaneous consolidation of the very small farming units.
Countries with over-fragmented farm structure – Latvia, Lithuania – can be
expected to go through a phase of farm consolidation, as very small farms adjust
their holdings to operationally more efficient sizes and a certain proportion of new
large farms are re-created under suitable conditions. In countries in the “normal”
group the process of adjustment will probably continue as well, although less
dramatically. These countries will probably gradually move toward stronger
presence of mid-sized farms through consolidation of the smallest holdings and
further fragmentation of the large successors of state farms and cooperatives.
Table 4.4. Concentration of Land: Percentage of Agricultural Land in Top 10% of Largest Farms
Country
Latvia
Lithuania
USA
Canada
EU15
Slovenia
Poland
Romania
Estonia
Czech Republic
Bulgaria
Hungary
Slovakia
Percentage of
farm land
20
30
35
38
40
40
50
55
60
82
90
92
97
48
Characterization of farm structure
over-fragmented
“normal”
sharply dual
4. Transformation of Cooperative Farms in Central and Eastern Europe
Sectoral Changes During Transition
We started by recalling the relatively high importance of agriculture in CEE
countries in the pre-transition era. During the last decade the situation has
changed, and the CEE agriculture is undergoing a process of “marginalization,”
similar to that observed in the EU. Alternative sectors – especially services – are
gaining prominence, and the share of agriculture in the economy is dropping,
especially in GDP, less so in labor (Figure 4.7). Yet despite these trends,
agriculture remains a much more important sector in CEE than in the EU. It
continues to be a major source of employment in rural areas, employing over 15%
of the total labor force (compared to 5%-6% in the EU). The rural population is
particularly dependent on agriculture in Bulgaria, Poland, Romania, Latvia, and
Lithuania: in each of these countries the share of agriculturally employed is over
20%.
25
share of agriculture in GDP/total employment, %
20
15
10
5
0
CEE: GDP
CEE: labor
Pre-1990
EU: GDP
EU: labor
Figure 4.7. “Marginalization” of agriculture in CEE
during the transition.
Post-1990
Transition initially produced enormous dislocations and shocks in the
economy in general and in agriculture in particular. The elimination of central
planning, price liberalization, introduction of hard budget constraints – these were
entirely novel rules of the game and the countries needed time to adjust. Both
GDP and agricultural production declined dramatically during the first years of
transition, between 1989 and 1992-93. But as of 1993 we are witnessing a clear
stabilization of both indices. There are, of course, variations across countries, but
as a regional average the GDP index is actually growing again, and the
agricultural product index (GAO) has definitely stopped declining (Figures 4.8(a,
b)).
49
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
140
120
100 •
•
••
••
•
80
•
••
••
••
••
••
•
60
40
••
••
•
••
••
•
•
•
•
•
•
1993
•
•
••
•
•
•
••
•
•
•
•
•
•
•
•
1994
1995
1996
20
0
1989
1990
1991
1992
•
• •
•
•••
•
•
• •
•
••
•
•
• •
•
•
Bul
Cz
Est
Hun
Lat
Lit
Pol
Rom
Svk
Svn
CEE
1997
Figure
4.8(a).
Gross
Domestic Product index
(GDP) for CEE countries
(1989=100).
140
120
100 •
80
•
•
•••
••
•
•
•
••
•
60
•
•
•••
••
••
•
•
•
•
•••
•
40
•
•
••
•
•
•
•
•
•
•
•
••
••
•
•
•
•
••
•
••
•
•
•
•
•
1995
1996
•
••
•
•
•
20
0
1989
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1997
•
•
•
•
•
•
•
•
•
•
Bul
Cz
Est
Hun
Lat
Lit
Pol
Rom
Svk
Svn
CEE
Figure 4.8(b). Gross
Agricultural Output index
(GAO) for CEE countries
(1989=100).
The stabilization of agricultural production has not been accompanied by
dramatic changes in product mix or in yields. Only the three Baltic states, and to
a lesser extent Hungary, have significantly reduced the share of livestock in their
output (Figure 4.9) and today livestock production in CEE countries is on a par
with the rest of the EU (about half the total agricultural product). Wheat and milk
yields in CEE hardly changed during the last decade, and they continue to be
substantially lower than in the EU, where technological progress is continuously
driving the yields up (Figure 4.10).
The decreasing role of agriculture in the CEE economy is reflected also in the
decrease of absolute levels of agricultural employment. Five of the ten CEE
countries (Hungary, Latvia, Slovakia, Czech Republic, and Estonia) registered
sharp declines in agricultural employment since 1992 (Figure 4.11). In Lithuania
and Slovenia, the level of agricultural employment remained unchanged, and only
Romania, Bulgaria, and Poland show significant increases in agricultural
employment.
50
4. Transformation of Cooperative Farms in Central and Eastern Europe
80
70
60
50
Pre-1990
Post-1990
40
30
20
Figure 4.9. Share of livestock
in agricultural product of CEE
countries before and during
the transition.
10
0
Bul
6
Hun
Pol
Rom
Cz
Svk
Est
Lat
Lit
ton/ha or ton/cow
5
4
Pre-1990
Post-1990
3
2
Figure 4.10. Wheat and milk
yields in CEE countries and
the EU before and after 1990.
1
0
CEE: wheat
EU: wheat
CEE: milk
EU: milk
Rom
Bul
Pol
Lit(*)
Svn(*)
Hun
Lat
Svk
Czech
Est
-15
-10
-5
0
5
10
Figure 4.11. Changes in
agricultural labor for CEE
countries, annual rates in
percent (1992-1997).
(*) Change not significant at p=0.05
Changes in gross agricultural output and agricultural employment lead to
changes in productivity of labor in agriculture. Generally, the decrease in
agricultural employment more than offset the decrease in GAO, and the
productivity of labor tended to grow. Five countries (Estonia, Czech Republic,
Slovakia, Hungary, and Slovenia) register pronounced increases in productivity
of labor in agriculture, and these are clearly attributable to the decline in
51
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
agricultural employment (Table 4.5). In Bulgaria, Poland, and Romania, where
agricultural employment actually increased, the productivity of labor has not
declined because of matching growth in agricultural product. Only two countries,
Latvia and Lithuania, show a decrease in the productivity of labor since 1992,
mainly due to sharp decreases in GAO.
Since physical yields have not changed significantly during the last decade and
unfortunately reliable information is not available on the capital asset base in
agriculture, changes in productivity of agricultural labor provide a good proxy to
changes in the efficiency of agriculture in CEE countries. We may thus tentatively
conclude that, during the last decade, the efficiency of agriculture has increased
in the Czech Republic, Slovakia, Estonia, Hungary, and Slovenia (primarily due
to decline in agricultural employment) and has not improved in Romania,
Bulgaria, and Poland (where agricultural employment increased). Lithuania and
Latvia still have not recovered from the negative shocks to production and output,
and it is premature to evaluate the efficiency of their agricultural sector.
Table 4.5. Changes in Productivity of Agricultural Labor and Their Relationship to Reform Policy
Index*
Synthetic policy index
Change in
productivity of
country
group averages
agricultural
values
labor
Czech Rep.
-2.19
-10.9
9.78
7.74
7.5
Slovakia
0.54
-6.34
7.35
6.82
Estonia
-7.74
-13
6.05
6.89
Hungary
0.17
-3.91
4.25
7.92
Slovenia
4.89
0
3.76
7.88
Romania
4.1
4.27
-0.15
5.55
6.3
Poland
1.44
2.24
-0.78
7.49
Bulgaria
1.49
2.37
-0.86
5.50
Lithuania
-3.18
0
-3.18
6.45
Latvia
-11.49
-4
-11.49
6.47
* The changes are annual rates of change for 1992-97 calculated, in percent, from semi-logarithmic
growth regression. The synthetic policy index is on a scale of 1 to 10, with higher values
corresponding to greater progress toward market environment.
State
Change in gross Change in
agricultural
agricultural
product
employment
In addition to changes in GAO, changes in agricultural employment, and the
resulting changes in productivity and efficiency of agriculture, Table 4.5 gives a
synthetic policy index, which represents the cumulative progress of overall
reforms in each country. Our synthetic policy index is the average of five policy
indices available from international sources. It combines three World Bank
indices (the Country Policy and Institutional Assessment (CPIA) Index, the
Liberalization Index, and the Environmentally and Socially Sustainable
Development ECA Index), the Euromoney Creditworthiness Index, and the
52
4. Transformation of Cooperative Farms in Central and Eastern Europe
Freedom House Freedom Index. The CPIA Index is based on four groups of
policy variables that are not directly related to agriculture: macroeconomic
management and sustainability reforms; policies for sustainable and equitable
growth; policies for reducing inequalities; and public sector management. The 20
variables collected in these four groups are assessed by a mixture of expert
judgments and quantitative techniques to arrive at a measure of progress in
economic policy and institutional reforms. The ECA index is specifically geared
to agricultural reforms in transition economies: it includes assessments (based on
expert judgments) of the achieved progress in several areas, such as price and
market liberalization, privatization of agro-processing and input supply, rural
financial systems, development of market-oriented institutional frameworks, and
of course land reform. The three other indices, in addition to economic and
financial dimensions, incorporate various measures of political freedoms and
democratization that are an inevitable part of the transition to the market. For all
indices, higher values correspond to greater progress toward a market
environment.
We see from Table 4.5 that, on a scale of 1 to 10, the countries showing an
increase in the efficiency of agriculture have an average index value of 7.5, while
the other countries, where the efficiency of agriculture has not improved, have a
significantly lower average index value of 6.3. It thus seems that greater progress
with general reforms, including macroeconomic policies, financial institutions,
and democratization, is conducive to greater progress in agriculture, leading to
noticeable changes in efficiency. Privatization and individualization of agriculture
and changes in farm structures are necessary conditions for the recovery of
agriculture. And yet they are probably not sufficient without an overall reformminded environment and general reform-oriented policies and attitudes in
government and society.
Where To From Here?
The course of transition during the last decade has displayed at least two
surprising features. First, the process has been much slower than originally
anticipated. And second, the actual outcomes meet neither the optimistic
expectations of market liberals nor the dire predictions of conservatives.
The transition from command economy to market has been a long-drawn
process because of its intrinsic complexity, which was not fully appreciated at the
start. Yet it is clear that, despite difficulties and delays, all CEE countries are
moving steadily toward a market-oriented environment. The policy achievements
vary across the region, largely depending on political and social forces, but as we
53
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
see from Table 4.5 all countries have passed the half-way mark of 5.0 in their
transition from command economy to market.
The one attribute of the former system that has been totally and irrevocably
abolished is central planning. This is probably the one attribute that has made the
former economic and social structure possible. Now that it has been eliminated,
many of the traditional accepted patterns of behavior and operation in agriculture
and other sectors are unsustainable. There is no choice but to move forward with
market reforms.
The agricultural sector in CEE definitely has not embraced the family farm as
the dominant farming structure. This is contrary to the original expectations of
Western experts, who anticipated a quick and sweeping transition to individual
farming as in market economies. Yet the individual sector has grown dramatically
and it controls today 60% of agricultural land in CEE countries. Despite this
strengthening of the smallholder sector at the expense of the large farms,
agriculture did not collapse because of fragmentation and privatization, as
predicted by conservative doomsayers.
Farm structures in CEE today cover a spectrum of forms, which include small
subsistence-oriented household plots, medium-sized commercial family farms,
and large corporations. The amount of land controlled by the individual sector is
unlikely to shrink in the future. Yet market forces will probably continue to
produce significant internal restructuring in the individual sector, encouraging
consolidation through transfer of land resources from very small units to more
efficient mid-sized farms with commercial orientation and greater earning
potential. The large corporate farms are also there to stay, yet market forces and
efficiency considerations will probably sustain the downsizing trend that has been
generally observed so far. Consolidation of mid-sized family farms and
downsizing of very large corporations will ensure that the CEE farm structure
continues to move toward the market distribution pattern.
Finally, agriculture does not seem to act as an engine of growth in the CEE
countries. The available evidence suggests a reverse causality: it is the general
macroeconomic recovery stimulated by a progressive policy environment that
encourages agricultural growth. Yet agriculture remains important for the rural
population: empirical evidence clearly suggests that the welfare of rural families
increases with the increase in their land endowment. However, the future of the
rural population must be considered in a broader context of rural development,
including creation of alternative jobs in rural areas that will facilitate the exit of
surplus agricultural labor without involving the undesirable option of rural-tourban migration. The countries should take advantage of the adjustments required
for EU accession to broaden the scope of reform and to include rural development
54
4. Transformation of Cooperative Farms in Central and Eastern Europe
issues in their agenda in addition to the traditional agricultural topics of land
privatization and farm restructuring.
A Note on Sources of Data
The most recent and up-to-date country-level information (as of 1999) was
obtained by direct correspondence with national research institutes and statistical
organs in the ten countries covered by this study. In addition to these direct
contacts, we have used the data from a series of country studies commissioned by
FAO for this workshop and by OECD for the Forum on Agricultural Policies in
Non-Member Countries held in Paris in April 1999.
Important data were obtained from the Directorate-General for Agriculture
(DG VI), European Commission, Brussels. Specifically, we have made extensive
use of the series of country and summary working documents published in 1998
under the general title of Agricultural Situation and Prospects in the Central and
Eastern European Countries.
Pre-1990 data for former Comecon member-countries were obtained from
Statistical Yearbook of Member-States of the Council for Economic Mutual
Assistance, regularly published in Russian in Moscow up to 1990. The pre-1990
data for the Baltic states were collected from Soviet statistical yearbooks.
Comparative data for market economies were obtained from Eurostat
yearbooks (for EU countries) and from the 1997 USDA Census of Agriculture
(for USA).
55
5. Agricultural Cooperative Enterprise in
the Transition from Socialist Collective
Farming
Zvi Lerman and Bruce Gardner (1995-2006)
The collapse of the command economy of the Soviet Union and countries
within its sphere of influence in 1989-91 provided the opportunity for many
economic adventures. One of these was the opportunity for new roles for
cooperatives. The collapse created an institutional vacuum surrounding large
“farm enterprises” – the dominant organizational form in former socialist
agriculture – in which basic economic functions were not being performed. While
the idea of rural cooperation has had a mixed history in the world’s market
economies, conditions in the former Soviet Union and other formerly
collectivized farm sectors in Central and Eastern Europe appear in important
respects promising for the cooperative form of business. So far, however,
cooperative enterprise has not taken off as a means of economic organization.
This paper considers the record and the reasons for it.
Economic Environment of the Early 1990s
In general, the agricultural sectors of the formerly centrally planned economies
were in a state of disarray and economic crisis in the period after the socialist
governments fell. The former command system disappeared almost overnight
while new market structures had not yet emerged, and state support provided to
the large farm enterprises was largely withdrawn. An immediate outcome of this
transition shock was a sharp decline in both agricultural output and the sector’s
GDP (value added) in the early 1990s. However, the countries of Central and
Eastern Europe (CEE) recovered from this initial decline much faster than the
56
5. Agricultural Cooperative Enterprise in the Transition from Collective Farming
former Soviet republics in the Commonwealth of Independent States (CIS).
Gross agricultural product in the CEE countries stabilized after 1994, while the
decline in CIS agriculture continued for four more years, until 1998 (Table 5.1,
Figure 5.1). The principal reason for the difference appears to be the more
resolute adherence of CEE governments to reform policies throughout their
economies. Agricultural labor in CEE countries as a group declined all through
the 1990s, as growing economies provided alternative employment opportunities
to some in the relatively large rural population (Table 5.1, Figure 5.2). In CIS,
on the other hand, the shrinking economy triggered a substantial increase in
agricultural labor during that period, in a sharp contrast to the pre-1990 pattern,
when Soviet labor was shifting from agriculture to other sectors of the economy.
The differences in the behavior of agricultural output and labor between CEE and
CIS produced sharp differences in productivity of agricultural labor: it generally
increased in the CEE countries, while declining through 1998 in CIS (Table 5.1,
Figure 5.3).
Table 5.1. Agricultural output, agricultural labor, and agricultural labor productivity for CEE
and CIS, 1990-2002 (percent of 1990)
Ag output
Ag labor
Year
CIS
CEE
CIS
CEE
1990
100
100
100
100
1991
89
95
107
94
1992
85
82
113
90
1993
83
79
112
85
1994
73
110
84
76
1995
70
114
80
81
1996
67
116
80
81
1997
67
116
77
81
1998
117
75
65
80
1999
121
74
68
78
2000
122
71
68
75
2001
125
66
75
79
2002
124
63
75
79
Bold numbers mark the recovery period after the turnaround.
Source: Lerman et al. (2004) based on official country statistics.
Ag labor productivity
CIS
100
84
76
76
67
63
60
60
57
59
59
64
69
CEE
100
101
94
99
98
113
113
118
121
123
124
143
147
Although total factor productivity or technical efficiency changes are more
difficult to estimate because of severe data limitations, some attempts have been
made and the findings are similar to those for labor productivity. Kim, Lee, and
An (2005) undertook technical efficiency growth comparisons for 22 CEE and
CIS countries over the 1992-2001 period. They found higher rates of increase in
the CEE countries, and moreover variations in efficiency gains across countries
in the CEE group were positively associated with measures of economic reform.
57
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
.
120
1990=100
100
80
60
40
20
0
1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002
CIS
140
Figure 5.1. Gross Agricultural
Output 1990-2002 (GAO 1990 =
100).
CEE
1990=100
120
100
80
60
40
20
0
1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002
CIS
160
Figure 5.2. Agricultural labor
1990-2002 (1990 = 100).
CEE
1990=100
140
120
100
80
60
40
20
0
1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002
CIS
CEE
58
Figure 5.3. Agricultural labor
productivity 1990-2002 (1990 =
100).
5. Agricultural Cooperative Enterprise in the Transition from Collective Farming
Analysts in the CEE and CIS countries as well as outside observers have
undertaken efforts to understand the sources of problems in the agriculture
sectors, and to recommend policies to improve economic performance. These
have ranged from simple ideas such as raising commodity prices to fundamental
reforms of the legal and institutional arrangements governing property and
contracting. In this context it is natural to consider new roles for cooperatives
among the options.
Potential for Cooperatives
The ideals of cooperative enterprise in agriculture have had a long history of
acceptance and even enthusiastic advocacy in CEE and CIS countries. This legacy
was tarnished by experience of State control of cooperatives. The International
Labour Office recently summarized the situation as follows (Couture et al.,
2002:2):
The State-controlled period was characterized by government
interference in cooperative affairs at all levels. Most of the time,
member registration was compulsory, and the directors and staff
were not appointed by the members, but directly appointed by the
State. In many countries, cooperatives were not particularly
concerned about profitability since they were subsidized by the
government and received preferential treatment. In the same way,
they were subject to rigid State planning, which did not provide them
with the possibility to develop their own entrepreneurial strategies.
Their business affairs were often restricted to a small range of
products and services, and State control extended to instructions and
directives concerning, for example, the number of employees and
their wages.
The large collective farms that had these characteristics were administered
under the label of cooperatives in the formerly socialist countries, even when they
had not evolved out of voluntary associations but were imposed from above in a
forced collectivization process. Consequently, among many of the rural
population the concept of cooperation in agricultural production appears to have
lost, if it ever had, the positive and idealistic connotations it has had in the
traditional cooperative movement throughout Europe and North America. In its
place, we find a strong psychological resistance to cooperation, bred from years
of abuse of the whole concept by socialist regimes. As noted by the Plunkett
Foundation (1995),
59
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
The use of the word “co-operative” in Central and Eastern Europe
will not only create the wrong impression, it will also create barriers
to progress. The old style of co-operative or collective has no
relevance in the new free-market approach.
The predominance of “old-style” production cooperatives in socialist
agriculture as of 1970 is shown in Table 5.2 (the numbers do not include state
farms).
Table 5.2. Share of Production Cooperatives in Socialist Agriculture (%, 1970 data)
USSR
Agricultural land
37.5
Number of
64.2
employed
Productive assets
42.4
Gross product
40.0
State purchases:
grain
51.9
meat
33.3
milk
36.5
Source: GSE 1973, vol. 13:102.
Bulgaria
68.0
58.7
Czechoslovakia
55.7
60.5
Hungary
67.6
75.5
Poland
Romania
1.2
0.9
53.9
82.0
East Germany
72.0
72.2
56.7
62.6
47.9
53.2
-45.8
1.4
1.1
23.6
42.3
---
81.0
44.7
59.7
64.5
50.0
53.4
79.8
-43.3
1.3
1.3
0.6
71.0
20.6
28.7
79.3
---
The Soviet model of agriculture that emerged in the process of collectivization
during the 1930s was automatically imposed by the USSR upon the CEE
countries after World War II. Collectivization of agriculture in these countries
was part of an extensive process of land reform, which included distribution of
large estates to smallholders. Contrary to the Soviet Union, which eliminated all
private land ownership immediately in October 1917, land in these countries was
never completely nationalized, and production cooperatives were created on
private land contributed by joining members. The original landownership records
of cooperative members survived the Communist era in these countries. In all
other respects, the production cooperatives in CEE were basically similar to
Soviet collective farms: they were large-scale horizontally integrated
multifunctional entities operating in a centrally controlled environment, which
had a responsibility for both economic and social aspects of rural communities
and whose members were largely treated as hired hands. The collectivized
agriculture in CEE developed the same duality as Soviet agriculture, with largescale production cooperatives coexisting symbiotically with small household
plots of their members.
Table 5.2 illustrates the very large share of Soviet-model collective farms in
the agricultural sector of most countries in the region. The difference to 100% is
60
5. Agricultural Cooperative Enterprise in the Transition from Collective Farming
largely made up by state farms, not the quasi-private household plot sector. A
notable exception in CEE was Poland, where collectivization had not been forced
and agriculture remained largely based on individual peasant farms (a similar
system prevailed in Yugoslavia). Without large-scale multifunctional collectives,
Poland retained a relatively receptive environment for agricultural service and
credit cooperatives. In 1970, the Polish marketing cooperatives purchased over
75% of farm products from peasant farms (GSE 1973, vol. 13:106). In general,
throughout the rest of the region, various service and consumer cooperatives have
not been eradicated as completely as in the USSR. In Hungary, 70% of consumer
services were provided by cooperatives; in Czechoslovakia, Romania, Hungary,
Poland, and East Germany, consumer cooperatives handled over 30% of all retail
trade (1971 data) (GSE 1973, ibid).
While the end of State support created severe economic problems for
agriculture in the transition economies, the end of State supervision created
opportunities. Given the institutional inheritance of large collective farming
operations, with management and on-site infrastructure for large-scale enterprise
remaining largely intact, the idea was that autonomous cooperatives might solve
some of these problems, especially in input provision and output marketing. The
main competing idea, development of individually owned and operated farm
enterprises along the predominant Western model, was hindered by the lack of
property ownership in land, lack of competitive market sources of inputs, and lack
of access to credit.
Proponents of cooperatives as a means of progress in the agricultural sectors
of transition economies, at a conference of the International Cooperative Alliance
in 1995, formulated the following principles of “genuine” cooperation (Couture
et al., 2002:2):
N democratic member control (generally ‘one-member, one vote’)
N voluntary and open membership
N member economic participation (on the basis of equity provided by
members, with limitations on individually held equity)
N distribution of surpluses or profits as patronage refunds
N social consciousness (providing training and information, and community
services).
These principles are essentially congruent with U.S. statements of what
distinguishes cooperatives from other forms of business, namely: “First, persons
who own and finance the cooperative are those that use it. Second, control of the
cooperative is by those who use it. Third, benefits of the cooperative are
distributed to its users on the basis of their use.” (Barton, 1989:1).
61
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
Could the prospects for such cooperatives overcome the historically validated
negative impressions of the past in the minds of agricultural producers or potential
new farmers? If so, the new cooperatives would then have to overcome the
classical economic problems that have been blamed for the failure of cooperatives
in agricultural production in the West – problems of incentives of managers and
workers (in allocation of on-farm effort, mobilization of members’ savings,
distribution of the cooperative’s net returns, and means of treating off-farm
income earned by members), of raising capital for investment , or of reaching
collective decisions needed for example to adopt new technology or change the
product mix to meet market trends. It seems likely that exposure to the negative
side of Western debates on cooperatives would resonate with some whose
experience with State-directed collective farming was disheartening, even if for
different reasons.
Experiences with New Cooperatives
Different countries in the region have pursued different farm restructuring
strategies. Albania, Romania, Armenia, and to a certain extent also Georgia
rapidly disbanded the collective farms and divided their land into very small
private farms during 1991-92. In other countries, dismantling is a rare
phenomenon and the traditional collective and state farms are generally required
to reorganize into new corporate forms with market-sounding names, such as
joint-stock company, limited liability partnership, etc. “Agricultural cooperative”
is one of the corporate forms explicitly recognized by company laws in transition
countries for the successors of former collectives. Agricultural cooperatives are
observed quite frequently, as is evident from the data for Russia, Ukraine, and
Moldova in Table 5.3. Yet agricultural cooperatives in transition countries are
not really cooperatives in the Western sense of the word and they are virtually
indistinguishable from other corporate farms. In a recent interview with the
manager of a large agricultural cooperative in Hungary, it turned out that the farm
was actually owned by the manager’s extended family and it was simply
registered as a cooperative for legal and administrative considerations. The term
“cooperative” thus appears to be a misnomer for farms in transition countries.
This may explain why comparative productivity studies consistently fail to detect
any performance differences between agricultural production cooperatives and
other corporate farms in CIS and CEE (see, e.g., Curtiss et al., 2004; Schulze et
al., 2001).
In most CIS countries land was generally privatized starting in 1991-92
through a mechanism involving distribution of “land shares” – paper certificates
62
5. Agricultural Cooperative Enterprise in the Transition from Collective Farming
of entitlement. These certificates could be converted on request into specific
physical plots for individual farming, but most landowners simply turned around
and entrusted their land shares to the managers of the former collectives for joint
cultivation. Survey results consistently indicate that the new landowners
overwhelmingly preferred the security of the cooperative umbrella to the risks
and uncertainties of individual initiative (Lerman et al., 2004). These preferences
are particularly strongly underscored by the landowner attitudes in Moldova and
Ukraine, where land shares have been recently converted by law into fully titled
and demarcated physical plots, so that special request is no longer required in
order to obtain land. In Moldova, only one-third of individual landowners
cultivate their land independently, while fully two-thirds entrust their land
through various leasing arrangements to managers of newly created corporate
farms, many of them registered as “agricultural cooperatives” (2000 World Bank
survey). In Ukraine (2005 FAO survey), only 20% of rural landowners cultivate
their own land, while two-thirds (as in Moldova) leave their land in joint
cultivation in the local large enterprise (the remaining 13% lease their land to
individual farmers).
Table 5.3. Number of agricultural production cooperatives in selected CIS countries in the early
2000s
All corporate farms
Russia (2001)
Agricultural
production
cooperatives
15,314
24,995
Agricultural cooperatives in
percent of all corporate
farms
61%
Ukraine (2000)
3,325
13,487
25%
Moldova (2003)
166
1,527
11%
Source: Official country statistics.
This attitude is also prevalent in the CEE countries, which unlike CIS have
followed the strategy of restitution to former owners. Thus, half the restitution
beneficiaries in Bulgaria and a significant proportion in Hungary have also chosen
to remain in agricultural production cooperatives, while in Romania, where
collectives were forcibly dismantled, fully 48% of land originally distributed to
private farms is now in various informal farmers’ associations (Lerman et al.,
2004). Members of former collective farms are thus voting “with their feet” for
perpetuation of the cooperative framework, at least in the immediate future,
probably because of the sense of security it affords to individuals in a highly
uncertain and rapidly changing environment.
Two conferences, one at which Western and Eastern European proponents of
cooperation assessed the record as of 2001 and the other a more scholarly
63
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
conference sponsored by the European Association of Agricultural Economists in
2005, provided several informative case studies. Bulgaria is notable in that after
the legislated liquidation of Soviet-style cooperatives and distribution of land
holdings to individuals, at least on paper, in 1991, the way was clear, and
encouraging, for the formation of new cooperatives. Most of the landowners
chose “to unite their land and other resources in agricultural production
cooperatives.” (Doitchinova et al., 2004:2). By 1998 the number of such “new”
cooperatives reached 3,268, which with an average of 742 hectares and 234
members accounted for 42 percent of Bulgaria’s land in cultivation. However, the
expansion occurred despite growing problems in maintaining viability in a
difficult economic environment, caused partly by State credit that, in retrospect,
was too easily granted. After a new Law for Cooperatives in 1999, which
attempted to stem the budgetary costs of aid to cooperatives, the cooperatives
accelerated moves already under way to devolve their assets to members, e.g., by
renting land to non-members and their own members (“A strange thing is
happening – the cooperators are renting land from themselves” (Ganev,
2001:36)). Many cooperatives were liquidated – essentially a declaration of
bankruptcy – and the number remaining in operation dropped from about 3,300
in 1999 to 1,750 in 2003 (Doitchinova et al., 2004).
Although it is still believed by some that “the fate of Bulgarian agriculture
rests with the fate of agricultural cooperatives” (Ganev, 2001:35), the trend
appears firmly in the direction of individual farms and larger agricultural
holdings, essentially registered profit-seeking corporations, which grew to
number 4,300 in 2003, averaging 214 hectares in size and accounting for 30
percent of Bulgaria’s cultivated land (Doitchinova et al., 2004:6). Doitchinova et
al. (2004) conclude with an assessment of what might be done to cure the
problems of production cooperatives. The problems are seen as stemming from
difficulties in resolving differences in interests of members, the distribution of
income, mobilizing capital for investment, and ensuring labor participation of
members, Several ideas for contractual arrangements among members are
discussed, but the most promising alternative is seen as follows: “Most of the
contradictions between the different groups of cooperative members can be
solved by transforming the cooperative [to become] a limited liability company”
(Doitchinova et al., 2004:8). This is not of course the end-state envisaged in the
cooperative movement.
The Czech Republic on the eve of transition in 1989 had an almost entirely
collectivized agriculture, with 99 percent of both land and production attributed
to large-scale collective and state farms. There were over 3,000 small,
individually owned farms, but they accounted for less than 1 percent of the
64
5. Agricultural Cooperative Enterprise in the Transition from Collective Farming
country’s land and production (Curtis et al., 2004:4). The cooperative movement
had had a strong presence in Czech agriculture for over 150 years (Moznar, 2001).
The intellectual foundation was there for cooperatives to play a major role in
picking up the pieces in the transition period of the 1990s. Indeed, the mandatory
breakup of former collective farms resulted as of 2000 in a roughly even split of
agricultural land between cooperatives of several kinds, business companies of
several kinds, and owner-operated small farms (Moznar, 2001:44). The last
category was expected by some to become predominant, and had expanded to an
estimated 23 percent of Czech agricultural land by 1995; but from that point
various larger-scale enterprises held their own (Curtiss et al., 2004:5).
Hungary had some experience with cooperatives before 1948, but the Sovietstyle collective farm, where the residual profits were extracted by the State and
the members were not independent owners, “was alien to the Hungarians, who
had an entirely different tradition” (Sebestyen, 1993:301). The result was that the
collective farm concept was transformed in the Hungarian context. Farmland was
not nationalized and remained the property of the members (even if they could
not farm all the land as individuals). As of 1990 there were 1,360 cooperative
farms in operation, which accounted for 80 percent of all farmland. Of their one
million members, half were active and half were pensioners (Filipsz and Szabo,
2001), and within these cooperatives there were about 40,000 relatively
independent farming units, about 30 of them on average per cooperative. These
were, for example, machinery-services units that rented equipment from the
cooperative (Sebestyen, 1993).
Hungary’s history of flexibility of organization within a broadly Soviet-style
collective farm system provided a useful starting point for the more drastic
changes that had to be undertaken with the end of State support and direction after
1990. Laws governing compensation of former owners and reorganization of
cooperatives were in place by 1992. The laws provided for the division of
cooperatives’ assets among existing members (as well as former members and
their heirs), permitted members to withdraw from the cooperative along with their
share of assets, and specified that cooperatives may transform themselves into a
limited liability or joint stock corporation. Enterprises that remained cooperatives
were not entitled to special tax or credit treatment (Sebestyen, 1993).
In these circumstances, the number of agricultural cooperatives in Hungary
has declined substantially, to about 800 in 2000, which cultivated about a third of
the country’s farmland and employed about 135,000 (compared to the 500,000
active members mentioned above for 1990). The cooperatives that disappeared
often did so essentially through bankruptcy liquidation, with assets going either
to former members or to corporate enterprises. As in the previously discussed
65
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
countries, the cooperative as a means of organization of agricultural production is
proving unviable as compared to the alternatives.
Rizov and Mathijs (2003) attempt to explain the survival and growth of farms
in Hungary using characteristics of the farms as explanatory variables, but they
do not consider organizational form as a causal factor. Ferto and Fogarasi (2004)
undertake an explanation of organizational form in Hungarian agriculture through
application of ideas of transaction-cost economics as developed in Allen and
Lueck (1998). The general hypothesis is that certain organizational forms, with a
focus in these studies on family farms as compared to corporate farms, are best
suited to particular economic environments. The particular hypotheses that
receive most attention are that high transaction costs, for example in mobilizing
capital or dealing in labor or product markets, favor large corporate farming in
which more decisions are handled through internal management instructions
rather than priced transactions (following Coase’s classic article, 1937); and that
when price-based transactions are necessary, they are done at a scale sufficient to
minimize high costs per transaction. Ferto and Fogarasi (2004) do not find
empirical evidence that transaction-cost factors are important in explaining the
prevalence or success of family farming as compared to larger-scale corporate
farming, and they do not attempt to investigate whether the decline of cooperative
farming might be linked to transaction-cost factors. Their work provokes the
thought, however, that transaction costs should be considered in the analysis of
fate of agricultural cooperatives, especially their devolution to much smaller
individual farms. These small farms unquestionably face high transaction costs
in both input acquisition and product marketing, and that could be a reason for
cooperative enterprise to play a role in the farming economy even if not as the
internal management mechanism for large farms.
The study of Romanian organizational structure by Rizov (2002) suggests
similar reasons for farmers becoming individual owner-operators, part-time
farmers, or “association farmers” (essentially smaller-scale cooperative ventures
for purposes of pooling capital). It is noteworthy that remaining a large-scale
cooperative is not even considered a possibility in the Romanian context, given
the “spontaneous privatization” with which many cooperatives were broken up
by members upon their first opportunity to do so in 1991 (Rizov, 2002:172).
Marketing and Input-Supply Cooperatives
In considering cooperatives in agricultural production we have been looking
where their prospects are in general weakest. In the United States, for example,
all manner of experiments have been undertaken in cooperative and communal
66
5. Agricultural Cooperative Enterprise in the Transition from Collective Farming
farming over the past 150 years, and they have almost without exception been
commercial failures and have not survived; yet cooperatives in the broader
agricultural economy have thrived. In 1915 marketing cooperatives sold $624
million of farm products, amounting to 8 percent of U.S. farm output. In 2002
they sold $70 billion of products (including processed products), about 15 percent
of the aggregate U.S. wholesale value of the products. Farm input and service
cooperatives have grown to a volume of business of about $26 billion in 2002
(USDA, 2004). Farm production cooperatives are too negligible to have any
statistics reported on them.
Many observers have noted that conditions in the transition economies that
make farming economically most difficult involve marketing and even more so
input supply. Often this is attributed to monopolies on either the buying or selling
side, but it may equally well be a problem of high transaction costs in an
environment of generally not well developed marketing infrastructure, including
information, transportation, and storage services. Could cooperative enterprises
owned by farmers remedy these problems? Certainly the hopes for this remain
and are being implemented. In the case of Hungary, while farming cooperatives
are not passing the survivor test, a substantial number of new cooperatives have
been established in marketing and input supply. Legislation of 1999 provided
financial support for the formation of such cooperatives and attempted to ensure
access to working capital. As of 2000 there were estimated to be 500 new local
cooperatives, including specialized ones for the marketing of fruits and
vegetables, pigs, poultry, sheep, and for crop warehousing (Filipsz and Szabo,
2001).
Legislation in transition countries is finally beginning to differentiate between
production cooperatives and service cooperatives. This is a notable departure
from earlier cooperative laws in the CIS, which distinguished between “consumer
cooperatives” and “producer cooperatives”, indiscriminately lumping both
production and service cooperatives in the latter category. Thus, the Ukrainian
Law on Agricultural Cooperation adopted in July 1997, after a general definition
of a cooperative as a voluntary association of members established for the pursuit
of a common agricultural activity, specifies that production cooperatives (those
created for joint farming activities) must be based on members’ labor and are
therefore organized as associations of individual farmers, whereas service
cooperatives (those created to provide farm support services to their members)
may employ hired labor and their membership may therefore include both
individual and corporate farms. The cooperative laws in Russia and Moldova, on
the other hand, still restrict cooperative membership to individual farmers.
67
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
No official statistics are available on service cooperatives in CEE and CIS, and
we have to rely on farm-level surveys to provide some information on cooperation
among farmers in transition countries. Despite the resistance to cooperatives
stemming from the long-term abuse of this concept under the Soviet regime, we
are witnessing the emergence of new forms of cooperation among individual
farmers in transition countries (Table 5.4). This is voluntary cooperation, often
informal and sporadic, that stands in stark contrast to the all-pervasive mandatory
cooperation of the socialist era. Cooperation is quite strong in many areas, with
the notable exception of processing and credit. Consistently with theoretical
considerations, the level of cooperation is lower in Poland, where the market
environment is substantially more developed than in the other countries. In
another series of surveys conducted in CEE back in 1993 (Euroconsult 1995),
45% of Romanian private farmers, 30% of Bulgarian farmers, and 15% of
Hungarian farmers indicated that they participated in cooperative farm-support
activities.
Table 5.4. Cooperation in farm services among private farmers (percent of respondents)
Russia
Ukraine
Belarus
Armenia
Moldova
Poland
Some form of cooperation
74
82
60
44
30
20
Consulting
58
64
33
9
10
8
Marketing
33
24
13
10
11
8
Input supply
30
20
7
1
7
5
Machinery
43
45
37
19
19
7
Production services
27
34
17
10
11
6
Processing
8
6
0
1
7
2
16
10
0
2
2
Credit
37
Source: World Bank surveys 1994-2000.
Cooperation in machinery – a high-cost lumpy asset – is understandably one
of the major areas of cooperation among individual farmers in transition
countries. Through cooperation, the actual access of individual farmers to
machinery and machinery services is much higher than that suggested by
machinery ownership rates. Thus, in Armenia only 14% of farmers own farm
machinery (either individually or jointly with their relatives and neighbors).
Machinery pools and service cooperatives, however, ensure that fully 80% of
individual farmers in this country have access to machinery or mechanical field
services (Lerman and Mirzakhanian, 2001). In Moldova, fewer than 30% of
peasant farmers participating in the 2000 World Bank survey have their own
machinery; another 40% have access to machinery through joint ownership (a
kind of low-level cooperation) or rental; finally, over 30% buy mechanical field
services. It is not clear how much of the machinery rentals and custom machinery
68
5. Agricultural Cooperative Enterprise in the Transition from Collective Farming
services originate from cooperatives and how much from private rental
companies, but we have seen in Table 5.4 that about 20% of farmers have
cooperation in machinery.
New forms of cooperation compensate in part for the absence of crucial
markets in products and services. As markets become more developed, the ways
in which farmers cooperate are likely to evolve as well.
Summary
Developments since the demise of socialist agriculture in the economies of
Central and Eastern Europe and the former Soviet Union provide a set of
experiments in economic organization whose outcome will be crucial for the
future of agriculture in those countries. For the agenda of this Journal, it is
notable that a large element of these experiments involves the role and functioning
of cooperatives.
Two distinct roles of cooperatives are prominent in both on-the-ground means
of replacing the former collective farm system and in legislation that attempts to
facilitate the successor system. The first role is the cooperative as a means of
business organization, one which follows the principles of farmer-members
owning, controlling, and capturing the fruits of a relatively large-scale farming
enterprise as a self-governing entity. The second role is the cooperative as a
means of obtaining market power for farmers in relation to buyers of their
products and providers of goods and services to the farm enterprise.
While both of these roles have been alive and well in proposals and new laws
in the transition economies, experience so far parallels the longstanding outcome
in Western market economies: cooperatives have been overwhelmingly failures
in the first role, but have been moderately successful in the second. The second
role is important in farmers’ estimation when they see themselves as being
exploited by monopoly or monopsony power among businesses that sell products
to them or buy from them, and it is important in fact when perceptions of
exploitation are accurate. It seems highly likely that such market failures exist in
the economic environment of the transition economies, where former State
monopolies have been transferred to private hands, and in this respect farmerowned cooperatives can be useful in fostering competition, or in some cases
hastening the creation of selling and buying channels which have not yet arisen
in the transition.
Cooperatives as a means of organizing multi-farmer agricultural production
enterprises, despite some initial and continuing enthusiasm, have run afoul of the
same weaknesses that underlie their general failure in the West: the seeming
69
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
impossibility of implementing the basic principles. The central issues involve
management decision-making and coordination. These tasks according to
cooperative principles are essentially ones of self-government by equally
empowered farmer-members, i.e., they are issues of politics. These arrangements
can work successfully for homeowner associations, labor unions, and clubs of
many kinds, so why not for farms? The difficulties pointed to in the Central and
Eastern European cases are ones of getting agreement on many managerial
decisions and on mobilization of capital for investment in the cooperative, but
most of all on the division of revenues or profits among members whose
contributions to the business vary. The difficulties lead to a tendency toward
devolution of responsibilities, assets, and revenues toward individual members
(leading to a loose association of independent farmers), or alternatively to
managerial decision-making by a hired executive or outside entity (converting the
enterprise to a corporation or subsidiary of a non-agricultural enterprise).
Even for cooperative enterprises in marketing and processing, or in supply of
farm inputs and services, it is not clear how far the cooperative principles of
management will prove viable. The Western story is moving toward cooperatives
becoming managerially more and more like corporations, with ownership and
management by persons other than the farmer-members. Indeed it is arguable that
cooperatives still flourish more because of favorable tax and regulatory treatment
than the advantages of cooperative principles as mechanisms of economic
organization for the business. Can the story be different in the transition
economies?
The evidence on the fate of agricultural cooperatives in the CIS and CEE
countries remains sketchy. The most useful findings at this time involve not
conclusions, but questions for further investigation. One line of research that
should prove fruitful is to analyze in more detail the experiences of individual
farms. In a recent detailed study of Russian farm enterprises, we found a
tremendous variation in the efficiency of production from farm to farm, not just
by small margins but with large groups of farms getting 3 to 4 times the output
from given resources as other farms (Grazhdaninova and Lerman, 2005). This
occurs not only between farms of different organizational forms, but even within
the set of former collective farms within a given region. It is likely that different
farms chose different ways of solving the managerial problems that arose
following the demise of the collective-farm system. Among other differences, the
extent to which cooperative principles were followed, and how they were
implemented, are likely to vary among these farms. It could be illuminating to
see the extent to which differences in the economic performance of these farms
line up with differences in managerial strategies and procedures.
70
5. Agricultural Cooperative Enterprise in the Transition from Collective Farming
References
Allen, D. W., and Lueck, D. (1998). “The Nature of the Farm,” Journal of Law
and Economics, 41:343-386.
Barton, D. (1989). “What is a Cooperative?” in Cobia, D. (ed.), Cooperatives
in Agriculture, Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall, pp. 1-19.
Coase, R. (1937). “The Nature of the Firm,” Economica, 3:386-405.
Couture, M.-F., Faber, D., Levin, M., and Nippierd, A.-B. (2002). Transition
to Cooperative Entrepreneurship: Case Studies from Armenia, China,
Ethiopia, Ghana, Poland, Russia, Uganda, and Vietnam, Geneva:
International Labour Office.
Curtiss, J., Medonos, T., and Ratinger, T. (2004). “Ownership Form Effect on
Large-Scale Farms’ Performance: Case of Czech Agriculture,” in From
Households to Firms with Independent Legal Status, 94th EAAE Seminar,
Ashford, UK, April.
Doitchinova, J., Kanchev, I., and Miteva, A. (2004). “Development of
Agrarian Structures in Bulgaria: From Production Cooperatives to Sole
Traders and Partnerships,” in From Households to Firms with Independent
Legal Status, 94th EAAE Seminar, Ashford, UK, April.
Euroconsult (1995). Farm Restructuring and Land Tenure in Reforming
Socialist Economies: A Comparative Analysis of Eastern and Central
Europe, World Bank Discussion Paper 268, Washington, DC: World Bank.
Ferto, I., and Fogarasi, J. (2004). “The Choice of Farm Organization: The
Hungarian Case,” in From Households to Firms with Independent Legal
Status, 94th EAAE Seminar, Ashford, UK, April.
Filipsz, L., and Szabo, Z. (2001). “Hungary,” in Proceedings of Workshop
Promotion of Rural Development through Agricultural Cooperatives,
ICAO-ICA Europe, Budapest, June.
Ganev, A. (2001). “Bulgaria,” in Proceedings of Workshop Promotion of
Rural Development through Agricultural Cooperatives, ICAO-ICA
Europe, Budapest, June.
Grazhdaninova, M. and Lerman, Z. (2005). “Allocative and technical
efficiency of corporate farms in Russia,” Comparative Economic Studies,
47(1):200-213, March.
GSE (1973). Bol’shaya Sovetskaya Entsiklopediya (Great Soviet
Encyclopedia), 3rd edition, Moscow [in Russian].
71
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
Kim, H., Lee, S., and An, D. (2005). “The Dynamics of Productivity Changes
in Agricultural Sector of Transition Countries,” presented at American
Agricultural Economics Association meetings, Providence, Rhode Island,
July.
Lerman, Z. and Mirzakhanian, A. (2001). Private Agriculture in Armenia,
Lanham, MD: Lexington Books.
Lerman, Z., Csaki, C., and Feder, G. (2004). Agriculture in Transition: Land
Policies and Evolving Farm Structures in Post-Soviet Countries, Lanham,
MD: Lexington Books.
Moznar, M. (2001). “Czech Republic,” in Proceedings of Workshop
Promotion of Rural Development through Agricultural Cooperatives,
ICAO-ICA Europe, Budapest, June.
Plunkett Foundation (1995). Review of 1994 Activities, Plunkett Foundation,
Oxford.
Rizov, M. (2002). “Endogenous Production Organization During Market
Liberalization: Farm Level Evidence form Romania,” Economic Systems,
27:171-187.
Rizov, M. and Mathijs, E. (2003). “Farm Survival and Growth in Transition
Economies: Theory and Evidence from Hungary,” Post-Communist
Economies, 15:227-242.
Schulze, E., Tillack, P., and Frohberg, K. (2001). “Factors determining
profitability of large scale farms in the Volgograd region,” Quarterly
Journal of International Agriculture, 40(1):67-96.
Sebestyen, K. (1993). “Transformation of Cooperatives in Hungarian
Agriculture,” in Csaki, C. and Kislev, Y. (eds.) Agricultural Cooperatives
in Transition, Boulder, CO: Westview Press, pp. 301-309.
USDA (2004). Farmer Marketing, Supply and Service Cooperatives
Historical Statistics, Cooperative Information Report 1, Section 26,
Washington, DC: U.S. Department of Agriculture, August.
72
6. Agricultural Cooperatives in Eurasia
Zvi Lerman and David Sedik (2014)
Across Eurasia there is an immense divide in the development of agricultural
cooperatives between the countries of the European Union and those of the
Commonwealth of Independent States and Georgia (CIS-G). This gap can be seen
in the differences in the spread of cooperatives within agriculture, in government
policy and in the enabling legislative environment. The divide is supported by a
basic conceptual and experiential distinction that existed during the socialist
period and which continues to exist in modified form between the two parts of
Eurasia today.
This paper will analyze the divergence in the development of agricultural
cooperatives in Eurasia. It begins with the question of why cooperatives are
needed, of what problems they solve. It then describes the divide within Eurasia
on agricultural cooperatives, starting with concepts, and illustrating differences in
the spread of cooperatives across the region, government policies and enabling
legislation. A conclusion summarizes policy recommendations to bring the useful
experience of the international cooperative movement to bear on agricultural
cooperatives in the countries of the Commonwealth of Independent States and
Georgia.
Why Agricultural Cooperatives?
Cooperatives in agriculture are usually created by grassroots farms to
overcome market failures, which are manifested in unwillingness of private
business entrepreneurs to provide services in areas that they judge unprofitable
or, alternatively, in situations where private businesses unfairly exploit farmers
through monopolistic practices. Best-practice world experience suggests that
service cooperatives provide a very effective way of improving the access of small
farmers to market services in both situations (Schrader, 1989). The focus on
73
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
service cooperatives is fundamental; in market economies agricultural
cooperatives are invariably of this type with very few exceptions (see Box 6.1).
Box 6.1. Agricultural production and service cooperatives
Agricultural cooperatives can be classified into two types. In production cooperatives members jointly
engage in the production process. In agriculture members jointly cultivate pooled or cooperatively held
agricultural resources, such as land or farm machinery. Collective farms in the former Soviet Union and
kibbutzim in Israel are examples of agricultural production cooperatives. Production cooperatives sell
their output to outsiders; yet their main function is to improve the wellbeing of their members by creating
conditions for more efficient farming than what would otherwise be feasible in individual farms.
It is often argued that by allowing members to pool their fragmented smallholdings into large farms
production cooperatives exploit economies of scale and achieve higher efficiency. Yet empirical studies
in market economies show that economies of scale do not generally exist in primary agriculture and
many researchers have in fact shown that agricultural production cooperatives are substantially less
efficient than individual and family farms. As a result, production cooperatives in the world are a tiny
minority among producers. According to International Cooperative Alliance (ICA) data, production
cooperatives account for less than 5% of all cooperatives in the world.
Service cooperatives, on the other hand, are the largest and most typical category of cooperatives in
developed and developing countries: these are cooperatives that provide services to their membersproducers, who continue to carry out all production activities independently on their own land. Service
cooperatives in many countries account for a large share of transactions, particularly in agriculture. For
instance, agricultural marketing, processing, and supply cooperatives are major players in markets for
farm products and farm inputs in North America, Western Europe, Japan, and South-East Asia. In the
U.S., agricultural cooperatives handle about 30% of farmers’ total farm marketing volume and 28% of
farmers’ total supply purchases. In the European Union, the share of agricultural cooperatives is even
larger: in countries such as the Netherlands, Denmark, Ireland, and Sweden 70%-80% of farm products
are marketed through cooperatives and cooperatives account for 50%-70% of all farm input purchases.
Service cooperatives are usually subdivided into marketing cooperatives, processing cooperatives, input
supply cooperatives, and farm machinery cooperatives.
Small farms commonly use agricultural service cooperatives to overcome
difficulties of unequal bargaining power with large-scale input suppliers (for
machinery, fertilizer, advisory and credit services), processors and middlemen.
These difficulties combine to create what is sometimes referred to as “the curse
of smallness”, a trap that prevents smallholders from fully exploiting their
inherent productivity advantages due to barriers in access to markets (Abele and
Frohberg, 2003). In dealing with a service cooperative, the market effectively
deals with a relatively large entity that combines many smallholders into a single
negotiating position. Access difficulties imposed by smallness are thus
automatically lifted.
In the post-socialist countries of Eurasia agrarian reform produced tens of
millions of small family farms in place of tens of thousands of large-scale
collectives and production cooperatives. Table 6.1 illustrates how small the
74
6. Agricultural Cooperatives in Eurasia
average farm is in the CIS-G. The situation is no different in Central and Eastern
Europe: of the total of nearly 8 million farms in the ten New EU Member States,
4.5 million (58%) are holdings of less than 2 hectares and only 80,000 (just 1%)
have 50 hectares and more (Csaki and Jambor 2009). In some countries land
reforms produced fragmented land holdings, based on the need for equitable
distribution of different land qualities and perennial crops.
Table 6.1. Average size of family farms in some CIS countries and Georgia
Average farm size, hectares
Armenia
Georgia
Azerbaijan
Kyrgyzstan
Tajikistan
Turkmenistan
Ukraine
Moldova
Source: Farm-level surveys 2000-2012.
1.38
0.96
1.86
3.80
3-5
4-5
4.6
---
Mean number of parcels
(excluding household plot,
survey data)
1.3
1.4
1.2
1.3
1.7
3
Thus, agricultural service cooperatives should be an excellent means for farms
in the formerly socialist countries of Eastern and Central Europe, as well as the
CIS-G, to improve their bargaining power vis-à-vis input providers and
processors, thus improving the welfare of the cooperative membership. Though
forming and sustaining an agricultural service cooperative is never easy, it is a
proven method to improve the sustainability of small farms in agriculture today,
just as it has been in Western Europe and North America for many decades.
The Great Divide Within Eurasia on Agricultural Cooperatives
The International Cooperative Alliance (ICA) describes a cooperative as “an
autonomous association of persons united voluntarily to meet their common
economic, social, and cultural needs and aspirations through a jointly-owned and
democratically-controlled enterprise”. The modern cooperative was developed in
Western Europe, and spread to other industrializing countries in the late
nineteenth century. Cooperatives were a self-help means to combat market
failures and poverty. As bottom-up, self-help institutions, they adhered to certain
principles that have been codified by ICA (2014), namely, voluntary and open
membership, democratic member control (one member, one vote), member
economic participation, autonomy and independence, education, training and
information, cooperation among cooperatives and concern for community.
75
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
Agricultural cooperatives evolved and continue to evolve out of this liberal,
democratic, self-help tradition.
The countries of Eastern Europe and the Russian Empire participated in this
liberal self-help tradition in the nineteenth and early twentieth centuries.
However, a paradigm shift dates to the 1920s, when Lenin proclaimed his socialist
vision of the development of cooperatives: gradual and voluntary movement from
lower to higher forms of cooperation, from marketing, service, and credit
cooperatives to production cooperatives. This vision, presenting production
cooperatives as the highest form of cooperation, was subsequently implemented
in Stalin’s collectivization drive (from 1928-1929), which eventually transformed
agriculture in all republics of the Soviet Union and much of Eastern Europe to
agriculture of collective farms, i.e., production cooperatives. 1 Thus, contrary to
the situation in developed market economies, tens of thousands of production
cooperatives existed in the USSR and continued to exist in the CIS-G in the form
of collective farms (kolkhozes) well into the post-1992 transition and many
continue to exist as production cooperatives after the reforms that eliminated
collective farms. 2
The socialist legacy of agricultural production cooperatives created a parting
of the ways within Eurasia that persists to this day in two forms. First, farmers’
support for the cooperative idea is low in the CIS-G countries based on past
experience with the Soviet cooperative model, and due to the lack of information
on and experience with alternatives. 3 Second, there is a profound conceptual
1
In The Immediate Tasks of the Soviet Government (1918) Lenin advocated for the total cooperation of
the people through their involvement, first, in consumers’ and other simple types of cooperatives, and
later, in producers’ cooperatives, which entail a higher form of cooperation. In On cooperation (1923)
Lenin stated that cooperation must be promoted by convincing the peasants of the expediency of
merging small farms and the advantages of collective production. He believed that the party and the
working class should play a leading role in raising the cultural level and consciousness of the peasants.
Lenin called this a “cultural revolution”.
2
Just as with collective farms, the degree to which these production cooperatives adhere to ICA
cooperative principles is subject to doubt.
3
Academic researchers have investigated the issue of distrust in cooperation in post-socialist economies
more formally. Gijselinckx and Bussels (2012) investigated two potential reasons for the lack of
cooperation in the ex-socialist countries of Europe, finding high correlations between indicators of
“social capital” and member intensity of agricultural cooperatives (percentage of farmers of a country
that are cooperative members), but no discernible correlations between indicators of “general deeprooted cultural values” and member intensity. “Social capital” is defined as “the trinity of ‘networks,
norms of reciprocity and trust’” (Gijselinckx and Bussels, 2012). Indicators of “general deep-rooted
cultural values” were based on research by Hofstede, Hofstede and Minkov (2010). Lissowska (2013)
came to similar conclusions in her analysis of social attitudes towards cooperation in European countries
(based on the European Social Survey), where she found that the preference for cooperation in transition
countries (Central and Eastern Europe, Russia and Ukraine) is close to that of the other (Western)
European countries. However, transition countries differ in that people have less faith in the cooperative
model based on their past experience with the socialist version of cooperation, which usurped and
76
6. Agricultural Cooperatives in Eurasia
confusion as to the nature of agricultural cooperatives within a market economy.
In the CIS-G countries the term “cooperative” is automatically understood to
mean “production cooperative”, while in established market economies, where
practically no production cooperatives exist, “agricultural cooperatives” are
automatically understood as “agricultural service cooperatives”.
Table 6.2. Development of agricultural service cooperatives in selected countries
Country
Year
Number of
Number of
Number of
Ratio:
Ratio:
agricultural
cooperative
farms
Farms per Farms per
service
members
member
cooperative
cooperatives
Ukraine
2010
801
21,521
5,300,000
246
6,617
Kazakhstan 2010
300
N.A. 1,850,000*
N.A.
6,167
US
2010
2,310
2,200,000
2,200,000
1
952
France
2010
2,900
500,000
516,100
1
178
Hungary
2007
58
20,177
626,300
31
10,798
Italy
2008
5,800
900,000
1,679,400
2
290
Netherlands 2010
60
100,000+
70,000
1
1,167
Spain
2010
3,989
1,160,300
967,290
1
242
Sources: US: USDA, 2012, USDA-NAS, 2013; Ukraine: Korinets, 2013: 36, 38, State Statistics Service
of Ukraine, 2011: 10, State Statistics Service of Ukraine, 2012: 51; France: Eurostat, 2013, Filippi,
2012: 14; Hungary: Szabo, 2012: 23; Italy: Bono, 2012: 19; Kazakhstan: number of service cooperatives
from Conception (2012), number of farms see next note. Netherlands: Bijman, van der Sangen, Poppe
and Doorneweert (2012): 16; Spain: Giagnocavo and Vargas-Vasserot (2012) and Eurostat (2013).
*The sum of peasant farms (170,000) plus an estimate of the number of household plots (1,680,000,
assuming that each rural household has a household plot). Data for peasant farms from Statistical
Agency of Kazakhstan (2012); data for rural households from Statistical Agency of Kazakhstan (2012),
v. 1: 4. Similar numbers emerge from the 2006-2007 Agricultural Census (Statistical Agency of
Kazakhstan (2007-08)).
The socialist legacy has also created a sizeable disparity in the development of
agricultural service cooperatives in the CIS-G compared to countries in
particularly Western Europe, but also Eastern Europe. Table 6.2 illustrates that
the countries of the CIS-G are many decades behind EU countries in the
development of service cooperatives. Only one farm in 246 in Ukraine and one in
31 in Hungary are members of a service cooperative, while in the US, France,
Netherlands and Spain each farmer is a member of a service cooperative and in
Italy every other farmer is a member. There are also far more farms per
cooperative in Kazakhstan, Ukraine and Hungary, than in the countries of
Western Europe and the US. Whereas there is only one cooperative for every
6,000 farms in Ukraine and Kazakhstan, and for every 10,000 farms in Hungary,
in France there exists one service cooperative for every 178 farms. This statistic
distorted the liberal democratic model of cooperation that pervaded Europe (including Russia and
Ukraine) before socialism.
77
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
also indicates that the development of service cooperatives in Eastern Europe and
the CIS-G is far behind that in the US and Western Europe.
Policy and Legislative Support for Cooperatives
Policies and legislation comprise the enabling environment for the
development of cooperatives. The purpose of this section is to point to the key
areas where the tools of public policy can assist in the development of agricultural
service cooperatives, and then illustrate the differences in approach between CISG policies and international best practice.
We should preface our remarks with the following general observations. First,
it is not fruitful to directly compare all policies for agricultural cooperatives in the
EU countries with those in the CIS-G countries. Cooperative law and policies
have considerably evolved in the EU countries over their more than 100-year
history, as a result of changes that have gone on in the cooperative movement.
Today, there are many cooperatively owned and operated companies that are
equally as large and complex as multinational public corporations. As the size and
complexity of companies change, so do laws governing them. It is counterproductive to transplant regulations from EU member states with a more
developed cooperative sector with a legal body that serves this sector to countries
where the cooperative movement is in its infancy and in which the main subject
is startup cooperatives (van der Sangen, 2012). Second, it is difficult to point to
types of policies that support or inhibit cooperative development based on a pancountry comparison of present policies and indicators or cooperative market
presence primarily because the “success indicator” of cooperatives (market share)
depends not only on current policies but on past policies and development as well.
In a cross-country comparison Brusselaers, Doorneweert and Poppe (2012) found
no correlation between current market share of agricultural cooperatives and
policies.
Agricultural Service Cooperatives in CIS-G Countries
It is therefore preferable to look to the reality of cooperatives in the CIS-G
countries and take only what is relevant from international, cooperative bestpractice enabling policies and legislation. A picture of the development of the
cooperative movement in countries of the CIS-G is presented in Chapters 7-11,
and also in Millns (2013), Korinets (2013), Tomich (2013), FAO (2014), and
Akimbekova (2010). The following picture emerges from these studies:
The socialist legacy of agricultural production cooperatives has caused low
farmers’ support for the cooperative idea. There is also a profound conceptual
78
6. Agricultural Cooperatives in Eurasia
confusion as to the nature of agricultural cooperatives within a market economy.
The term cooperative is automatically understood to mean “production
cooperative” both by farmers and by politicians. Politicians, while expressing
support for the cooperative idea, often promote cooperation as a means to
consolidate land holdings of smallholders into larger production cooperatives.
This, of course, increases the unattractiveness of the cooperative idea to farmers.
There are very few working agricultural service cooperatives throughout the
CIS-G. Statistics on cooperatives are often difficult to interpret because of the
large number of “sleeping cooperatives” and the conceptual confusion between
service and production cooperatives (see Box 6.2). The popularity of “sleeping
cooperatives” is a direct result of poor policies whereby governments have
occasionally advanced subsidies, machinery leases or credits at preferential rates
to agricultural cooperatives (Korinets, 2013).
Practically all CIS-G countries have cooperative-specific laws in their statutes
(see Chapter 7). The prominent role of production cooperatives in CIS-G
countries (as successors of Soviet-era collective farms) is reflected in the
prevailing service/production dichotomy, which is often “canonized” in separate
laws for the two types of cooperatives. Six of the twelve CIS-G countries have
separate laws for production and service cooperatives on their statutes. This is not
the recommended practice in market-oriented economies.
The ILO guidelines for cooperative legislation recommend “one law for all
types of cooperatives, possibly with specific parts/chapters for specific types of
cooperatives” (Henry, 2012: 59), and CIS-G countries indeed seem to be moving
in this direction in their recent legislative attempts (Kyrgyzstan, Tajikistan,
Azerbaijan, and perhaps most notably Ukraine). According to the ILO guidelines,
the one-law approach, among other benefits, diminishes bureaucracy and prevents
fragmentation of the cooperative system that inevitably weakens its selfmonitoring and lobbying power (see Chapter 7).
Tax policies in CIS-G countries are often profoundly unfriendly to service
cooperatives, often entailing double taxation for farmers who may venture to join
them. This is not because of any built-in bias against cooperatives: it is simply
because tax laws generally treat cooperatives as any other legal person
(corporation), without due regard to cooperatives’ specific features.
79
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
Box 6.2. Agricultural cooperatives in Kyrgyzstan
Statistics on cooperatives in Kyrgyzstan are available from two sources: a special unit dealing with
cooperative development in the Ministry of Agriculture and the National Statistics Committee (NSC).
The Ministry reports the number of registered cooperatives, which showed impressive growth over time,
rising from about 300 in 2004 to 1,300 in 2009 (Figure 6.1). 4 NSC based its reporting on the number
of active (operating) cooperatives. The gap between the two sources is dramatic (Figure 6.1). In 2011,
the Ministry reported more than 1,400 registered cooperatives, while according to NSC there were just
400 active cooperatives in the country (National Statistics Committee of Kyrgyzstan, 2012). It thus
became apparent that more than 70% of registered cooperatives in Kyrgyzstan were inactive and existed
only on paper, presumably with the intent of taking advantage of future credit or taxation benefits that
might materialize through government policies. Such entities are known as “sleeping cooperatives”. The
dominant majority of registered cooperatives in Ministry of Agriculture statistics are production
cooperatives, not service cooperatives. In 2009, 88% of the registered cooperatives were classified as
production cooperatives and only 12% were service and processing cooperatives.
Figure 6.1. Development of
agricultural cooperatives in
Kyrgyzstan 2004-2011.
Key: Grey bars: registered
cooperatives from Ministry
of Agriculture; black bar:
active cooperatives from
National Statistics
Committee of Kyrgyzstan.
FAO initiated a survey of cooperatives in 2012. The sample frame for the survey consisted of the 400
active cooperatives in the NSC database. The original objective was to survey a sample of 100
cooperatives from the NSC list, collecting information mainly on service cooperatives, with control
information on some production cooperatives. This objective could not be achieved, however, because
virtually no pure service cooperatives were found in the NSC database. Among 400 active cooperatives
in the NSC list, only 17 were identified as mixed service/production cooperatives and 3 as trade/service
cooperatives.
Source: Adapted from Chapter 7.
Cooperative law may outline conceptual principles of the taxation of
cooperatives and suggest taxation guidelines, but ultimately any tax ruling is
based on the Tax Code. Thus, Kyrgyzstan Law of Cooperatives (2005) contains
4
These numbers do not include credit unions, created mainly by the Raiffeisen Foundation in
Kyrgyzstan (some 300 in 2009).
80
6. Agricultural Cooperatives in Eurasia
a blanket statement deferring all tax-related decisions for cooperatives to the Tax
Code (Article 32).
Taxation of cooperatives involves two distinct issues: (a) value added tax
(VAT) and (b) tax on profits at the level of the cooperative. In both instances, the
Western approach to cooperative taxation is guided by the view that cooperatives
act on behalf of their members as their agents. Because of the close involvement
of the members in the decision-making processes in the cooperative and because
of the special nature of the transaction between the members and their
cooperative, cooperatives can be seen as the executing agents of the members.
This view suggests that transactions between cooperatives and their members
should be exempt from both VAT and profit tax. The burden of taxation should
shift from the cooperative (“the agent”) to the members as the principal (see also
Chapter 11).
Not all legislation in the CIS-G countries adheres to these principles. Even
Ukraine, which has generally good legislation on agricultural service
cooperatives, has not completely adapted its tax system to provide a good tax
environment for private plot holders who wish to form a service cooperative (see
Chapter 10).
Registration requirements for cooperatives are often unnecessarily difficult.
Cooperatives are legal bodies and as such require registration, either as part of
general registration of legal bodies according to Civil Code or as a special
registration procedure specified in the country’s law of cooperatives. The ILO
guidelines for cooperative legislation state that, “the establishment of a speedy
and impartial registration procedure is a first step by the state towards facilitating
the development of a genuine cooperative system” (Henry, 2012: 69).
The registration requirements in CIS-G legislation are usually formulated in a
muted general language. The mild tone adopted in various CIS-G laws is
consistent with the ILO recommendations on registration of cooperatives (Henry,
2012):
…a cooperative must be registered once the conditions laid down
in the law are fulfilled.…If prior approval is necessary, the
discretionary power of the approving authority must be strictly and
effectively limited by law. In no case must the registration procedure
hinder people from forming entities in the way that suits them best.
Registration . . . [should] be concluded within a short time period; a
refusal to register must be justified in writing; in the case of refusal,
the founders may appeal before a court, which should give a decision
81
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
within a brief time period. The fees for the registration and
publication must in no case be prohibitive (pp. 68-70).
A different approach is found in the new Law of Agricultural Cooperatives
(2013) in Georgia. Uniquely among the CIS countries, Georgia establishes a
special state agency, the Agency for the Development of Agricultural
Cooperatives within the system of the Ministry of Agriculture. The main purpose
of this agency is to develop viable cooperation in agriculture in Georgia. In pursuit
of this overall goal, the agency is charged with the following competencies (article
8):
N Administration of government support measures, and provision of a
strategy for the development of cooperatives in Georgia.
N Provision of training, advice and information to cooperatives on issues of
importance to them.
N Monitoring and evaluation of cooperatives in Georgia.
N Organization of conferences, consultations and seminars on cooperative
issues, and cooperation with the International Cooperative Alliance.
N Granting and termination of the status of an agricultural cooperative.
Agricultural cooperatives in Georgia first register in the registry of
entrepreneurs and non-profit (non-commercial) legal entities. In order to be
granted the additional status of “agricultural cooperative” cooperatives must
register with the agency (art. 7.2). The cooperative is then evaluated according to
criteria specified by law, and must provide periodic information to the agency for
monitoring purposes. In return, the cooperative is eligible for government support
measures. According to the Law on Agricultural Cooperatives (art. 15.2), the rules
for granting and termination of the status of an agricultural cooperative were to
be specified within 2 months after the Law came into force in July 2013. However,
to date (March 2014) no regulation on this crucial issue has been made public.
The two-step registration process without clear criteria for the granting and
termination of the status of an agricultural cooperative would appear to be
inconsistent with the strong recommendations for simplicity and transparency
voiced by the ILO (see above). In the absence of clear regulations on the rules for
granting and termination of the status of agricultural cooperative, it is not possible
to clearly understand the mandate of the Agency for the Development of
Agricultural Cooperatives in Georgia. However, sources within Georgia state that
the two registrations are of a totally different nature. Registration as a legal entity
is the normal record-keeping listing required in Georgia as well as in other
countries for legal bodies, including for all cooperatives. Registration with the
82
6. Agricultural Cooperatives in Eurasia
agency is an optional step to be undertaken if the cooperative would like to
participate in government support programs. The authority to grant and terminate
the status of “agricultural cooperative” in Georgia represents an effort at quality
control, in order to weed out “false cooperatives” which abuse the cooperative
name in order to qualify for state aid. 5 This is an important function, as the
“sleeping cooperative” phenomenon mentioned above is fairly widespread in the
region.
News reports in the Georgian press indicate that the government expects the
new cooperative law “to stimulate the enlargement of farms”(Georgia Business,
2013). Georgia’s new law of agricultural cooperatives does not speak explicitly
of agglomeration of holdings in production cooperatives or transfer of
individually owned land to cooperatives. The views in the media are apparently
fostered by the definition of agricultural cooperative in article 6 of the new law,
where areas of cooperative activity are listed as “production, processing,
packaging, labeling, storage, transportation and marketing of agricultural
products”. Lack of clear differentiation between the activities of production and
service cooperatives is probably responsible for the traditional identification of
any cooperative with “production cooperative” (see Chapter 7).
Conclusions
Because of the legacy of the past, CIS-G countries require specialized
legislation (on cooperatives, as well as mention in the civil and tax codes) in order
to provide an enabling environment to allow agricultural cooperatives to operate
properly. Ukraine is a good model: it has benefitted from at least three advisory
projects from donors in order to improve its cooperative legislation in the past two
years, and it now has perhaps the best legislation on agricultural service
cooperatives in the CIS-G. For the revision of legislation, it may be helpful to set
up fora where government, donors and service cooperative leaders can exchange
views on enabling legislation with the aim of supporting the development of
service cooperatives.
Good legislation is important, but it is not sufficient. Politicians in the region
also need to do their part. Production cooperatives should not be advanced as a
policy tool to solve land fragmentation. Production cooperatives are known to be
inefficient, in the post-socialist context they are vestiges of the past, and their
political and financial support is indefensible 22 years after the dissolution of the
Soviet economic system. On the other hand, agricultural service cooperatives
5
Information provided by the FAO Representation Office in Tbilisi, Georgia (March 2014).
83
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
have the potential to solve real problems of small and medium size farms that
produce the majority of agricultural output in every CIS-G country.
The rural population also requires capacity building. Farmers need to be
informed on the cooperative idea and its benefits. In Ukraine this issue was
mentioned as perhaps the most important issue by the participants of the All
Ukraine Public Meeting “Ukraine on the Eve of the International Year of
Cooperatives” (15 December 2011) attended by service cooperative leaders,
regional cooperative activists, as well as researchers, government employees and
project personnel connected with development of cooperatives (Korinets,
2013:17). Cooperative Development Centers in the United States are an example
of the type of government-private sector collaboration that can accomplish this
task. Cooperative Development Centers are non-profit state-level organizations
funded by cooperatives themselves and co-funded by the US Department of
Agriculture. Their function is to explain the cooperative idea and the specific
benefits for those interested, to train in cooperative management skills, and
support the public with the business, legal and tax information needed for
cooperative startups and management. They also offer individual technical
assistance by qualified experts, the costs of which may be covered by the US
Department of Agriculture grants for the development of cooperatives.
While the type of public-private partnership represented by the US
Cooperative Development Centers is an excellent example of an institution to
support the development of cooperatives, there is no substitute for a grass-roots
cooperative movement driven by enthusiasm for the cooperative model. It is the
movement in countries around the world that was responsible for building
agricultural service cooperatives far before they became a part of state policy. The
cooperative movement in all CIS-G countries is at an early stage, perhaps
understandable for countries that only twenty years ago knew only the Soviet
model of cooperation.
Agricultural service cooperatives also require capacity building and
investment support as part of a targeted policy to improve the sustainability of
small family farming. Unfortunately, governments in the region do not yet have
the capacity to do this. At this time only donors in association with governments
and cooperatives in the region can accomplish this with any degree of expertise.
But the typical donor project of 2 years is not sufficient to develop a farm service
cooperative to self-sufficiency. The best example of donor support in the region
is Danone-Ukraine’s support of milk cooperatives through Dobrobut gromad
(Heifer International) in Ukraine where Danone has supported cooperatives for
an average of 5 years (Danone-Ukraine, 2014). The Danone-Dobrobut gromadmilk cooperatives cooperation is not, however, a typical donor intervention. If the
84
6. Agricultural Cooperatives in Eurasia
raw product offered by supported cooperatives meets Danone’s quality standards6
the company enters into a long-term contract with the suppliers to secure its raw
material base. Thus, this is a two-way beneficial arrangement, not standard
dependence on donor generosity. Other private dairy firms interested in creating
a high-quality raw material base may wish to consider such an approach.
References
Abele, S. and Frohberg, K., eds. 2003. Subsistence Agriculture in Central and
Eastern Europe: How to Break the Vicious Circle, Studies on the Agricultural
and Food Sector in Central and Eastern Europe, Vol. 22, IAMO, Halle.
Akimbekova, G. U. 2010. “Agricultural Cooperation in Kazakhstan: problems
and possible solutions,” Ekonomika APK (Kiev), No. 9: 161-166.
Bijman, J., G. van der Sangen, K.J. Poppe and B. Doorneweert (2012). “Support
for Farmers’ Cooperatives; Country Report The Netherlands”. Wageningen:
Wageningen UR.
Georgia Business (2013). Business Gruziya, 9 August 2013.
http://bizzone.info/agriculture/2013/1376075873.php.
Bono, P. (2012). “Support for Farmers’ Cooperatives; Country Report Italy”.
Wageningen: Wageningen UR.
Brusselaers, J., Doorneweert, B. and K. Poppe. 2012. “Support for Farmers’
Cooperatives: EU synthesis and comparative analysis report: policy
measures”. Wagingen: Wagingen UR.
Cobia, D., ed. 1989. Cooperatives in Agriculture (Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice
Hall).
Conception. 2012. Conception of the Development of Agricultural Cooperation
in Kazakhstan, Kazakh Research Institute of Agricultural Economics and AO
“Kazagroinnovatsiya”, Almaty.
Csaki, C. and Jambor, A. 2009. “The Diversity of Effects of EU Membership on
Agriculture in New Member States,” FAO Regional Office for Europe and
Central Asia Policy Studies on Rural Transition, No. 2008-1 (Budapest).
http://www.fao.org/fileadmin/user_upload/Europe/documents/Publications/P
olicy_Stdies/EUeffects_en.pdf
Danone-Ukraine. 2014. “Cooperatives and Family Farms.”
http://danone.ua/en/social-responsibility/id/kooperativi-ta-simejni-fermi-004/
6
If a supported cooperative does not meet Danone’s standards, investment support is eventually
dropped.
85
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
Eurostat. 2013. “Agricultural holdings, 2000-2010.”
http://epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/statistics_explained/index.php?title=File:Agr
icultural_holdings,_2000-2010.png&filetimestamp=20121105110459
Filippi, M. 2012. “Support for Farmers’ Cooperatives; Country Report France”.
Wageningen: Wageningen UR.
Food and Agriculture Organization of the UN (FAO). 2012. Report of the Twentyeighth FAO Regional Conference for Europe, 19 and 20 April 2012.
http://www.fao.org/docrep/meeting/025/md942e.pdf
Food and Agriculture Organization of the UN (FAO). 2014. International
Roundtable on Cooperation, Report (in Russian).
http://www.fao.org/fileadmin/user_upload/Europe/documents/docs/ASI/roun
dtable/Report_ru.pdf
FAO Regional Office for Europe and Central Asia (FAO-REU). 2014. Regional
Initiative for Europe and Central Asia.
http://www.fao.org/europe/agrarian-structures-initiative/en/
Georgia Business (2013). Business Gruziya, 9 August 2013.
http://bizzone.info/agriculture/2013/1376075873.php.
Giagnocavo, C., Vargas-Vasserot, C. 2012. “Support for Farmers’ Cooperatives;
Country Report Spain”. Wageningen: Wageningen UR.
Gijselinckx, C., Bussels, M. 2012. “Support for Farmers’ Cooperatives; EU
synthesis and comparative analysis report; Social and Historical Aspects”.
Wageningen: Wageningen UR.
Henrÿ, Hagen. 2012. Guidelines for Cooperative Legislation, 3rd ed. revised
(Geneva: International Labor Office).
Hofstede, G., Hofstede, G.J. and Minkov, M. (2010). Cultures and Organizations:
Software of the Mind, third edition (New York: McGraw-Hill).
Hoyt, A. 1989. “Cooperatives in other Countries,” in Cobia, D. (1989), pp. 81-97.
ICA. 2014. “Co-operative identity, values & principles,” International
Cooperative Alliance. http://ica.coop/en/what-co-op/co-operative-identityvalues-principles
Korinets, R. 2013. “Sel’skokhoziastvenny obsluzhivaiushchie kooperativy v
Ukraine” [Agricultural Service Cooperatives in Ukraine], FAO Regional
Office for Europe and Central Asia Policy Studies on Rural Transition No.
2013-6. http://www.fao.org/docrep/018/ar593r/ar593r.pdf
Kyrgyzstan in Numbers. 2012. Kyrgyzstan v Tsifrakh 2007-2001 [Russian],
Statistical yearbook, National Statistics Committee of Kyrgyzstan, Bishkek.
86
6. Agricultural Cooperatives in Eurasia
Kyrgyzstan Law of Cooperatives. 2005. Law of the Republic of Kyrgyzstan on
Cooperatives No. 70 (11 June 2004) as amended by Law No. 37 (25 February
2005).
http://www.cac-civillaw.org/gesetz/kirgisistan/GenossenschaftsG.KIR.ru.rtf.
Lissowska, M. 2013. “The Deficit of Cooperative Attitudes and Trust in PostTransition Economies,” EAEPE Papers in Evolutionary Political Economy,
no. 10 (2013).
Millns, J. 2013. “Agriculture and Rural Cooperation: Examples from Armenia,
Georgia and Moldova,” FAO Regional Office for Europe and Central Asia
Policy Studies on Rural Transition, No. 2013-2.
http://www.fao.org/docrep/018/ar424e/ar424e.pdf
State Statistics Service of Ukraine. 2012. Agriculture of Ukraine, 2011: Statistical
Yearbook (Kiev).
State Statistics Service of Ukraine. 2011. Main Agricultural Characteristics of
Rural Households in Rural Areas (Kiev).
Statistical Agency of Kazakhstan. 2007-08. Results of the First National
Agricultural Census, 2006-2007, vols. 1-9 (Astana) [www.stat.gov.kz].
Statistical Agency of Kazakhstan. 2011. 2009 Population Census of Kazakhstan:
Households (Astana) [www.stat.gov.kz].
Statistical Agency of Kazakhstan. 2012. Agriculture in Kazakhstan 2007-2011,
Statistical yearbook, (Astana) [www.stat.gov.kz].
Schrader, L. 1989. “Economic Justification” in D. Cobia, ed., Cooperatives in
Agriculture (Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall), pp. 121-136.
Szabó, G. G. 2012. “Support for Farmers’ Cooperatives; Country Report
Hungary”. Wageningen: Wageningen UR.
Tomich, I. F. 2013. “Initsiativa ‘Rodnoe selo’—posledniaia nadezhda selian”,
Gazeta.ua, 22.03.2013 [http://gazeta.ua/ru/articles/488810] .
USDA. 2012. Cooperative Statistics 2011, U.S. Department of Agriculture (Sarah
Ali, Jacqueline E. Penn and E. Eldon Eversull), Service Report 72, October.
USDA-NAS. 2013. Farms, Land in Farms, and Livestock Operations 2012
Summary, U.S. Department of Agriculture, National Agricultural Statistics
Service, February.
Van der Sangen, G. 2012. Support for Farmers Cooperatives: EU synthesis and
Comparative Analysis Report—Legal Aspects. Wageningen, UR.
87
7. Cooperative Development in Central
Asia
Zvi Lerman (2013)
The five countries of former Soviet Central Asian – Kazakhstan, Kyrgyzstan,
Tajikistan, Turkmenistan, and Uzbekistan – have made huge strides in their
efforts to reform tenure rights in agricultural land and change the traditional
Soviet-style farming structure to a model closer to market principles (Lerman and
Sedik, 2009). Two of the five countries – Kazakhstan and Kyrgyzstan – now
recognize private ownership of agricultural land and allow land market
transactions; Tajikistan retains state ownership of land but nevertheless allows
land market transactions in the guise of transferable land use rights; only
Uzbekistan and Turkmenistan retain the Soviet model of state-controlled rigidly
nontransferable land, but even in these two countries land use and agricultural
production have massively shifted from large collective farms to small
leaseholders. The individualization of Central Asian agriculture has largely driven
the impressive recovery in agricultural production that we are witnessing since
about 1998 across the region. While much remains to be done in the area of land
reform and farm restructuring until Central Asia closes the gap between the
administrative-command tradition and market agriculture (EBRD, 2012, Table
A.1.1.2), the focus of attention has begun to shift to post-restructuring measures
intended to ensure viability and profitability of the smallholder farms by
counteracting the negative effects of smallness.
In developed economies, the access of small farmers to markets is usually
facilitated by agricultural service cooperatives. They act as integrators of farm
product sales and farm input supplies for whole groups of smallholders; they
provide pooled machinery services in cases when an individual small farmer
cannot purchase his own machines; they negotiate loans and credit terms with
commercial banks from positions of strength (Cobia, 1989). There are hundreds
of thousands of such service cooperatives in the world with hundreds of millions
88
7. Cooperative Development in Central Asia
of member farmers. Central Asian agriculture, with its multitude of small family
farms and underdeveloped market channels, seems to be ripe for the emergence
of service cooperatives, and yet their development has been slow and halting.
Instead of Western-style service cooperatives, the very concept of cooperative in
Central Asia is automatically interpreted as a production cooperative, i.e., a model
of the Soviet-style collective farm (Plunkett Foundation, 1995).
The purpose of this paper is to introduce Central Asian policy makers to the
Western paradigm of service cooperative and to explore the constraints – both
physical and ideological – to faster development and acceptance of cooperatives.
We also discuss the need for a complete reorientation of the government’s
approach to cooperative development. The main message is that the government
should focus on provision of public goods, such as information, education, and
training in the cooperative arena, and desist from interfering in allocation of
credits and financial support, which in the past led to inefficiency and rampant
corruption.
Conceptual Issues of Agricultural Cooperative Legislation in
Central Asia
Smallholder Agriculture and the Rationale for Service Cooperatives
Individualization of agriculture manifested in a sweeping shift from largescale collective farms to small family farms is the most striking change that the
transition has produced in all CIS countries. Agriculture in Central Asia is now
based primarily on smallholders – peasant farms and household plots (Lerman
and Sedik, 2009). These small producers control the major part of agricultural
land and livestock, and they produce most of Gross Agricultural Output (GAO)
across the region. Small farms everywhere in the world face essential difficulties
and constraints in their access to market services, and Central Asia is not an
exception in this regard. The main difficulties faced by smallholders include:
difficulties with access to sales channels for market products,
difficulties with access to supply channels for farm inputs,
difficulties with purchase of farm machinery and transportation equipment,
difficulties with access to information and advisory services, which are
essential for raising productivity and efficiency,
N limited access to credit resources, which are required to finance short-term
working capital and long-term investment needs.
N
N
N
N
89
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
These difficulties combine to create what is sometimes referred to as “the curse
of smallness”, a trap that prevents smallholders from fully exploiting their
inherent productivity advantages due to barriers in access to markets (Abele and
Frohberg, 2003).
In developed market economies, farmers typically achieve access to markets
through private intermediaries. Such private intermediaries are beginning to
emerge in Central Asia in a variety of forms, which include integrators for
collection and sale of farm products, private processors buying wholesale from
farmers, providers of rental machinery services, or distributors of farm inputs to
remote villages. These private service providers fulfill a crucial function for rural
development: they free the farmers from the need to travel to the marketplace and
enable them to concentrate on agricultural production. So far, however, private
rural intermediaries are relatively rare in Central Asia and do not satisfy the needs
of the huge number of peasant farms and household plots in the region. In such
cases in market economies farmers organize self-help bodies – so-called service
cooperatives, whose function is to correct market failure by allowing alternative
access to markets without relying on private service intermediaries.
Best-practice world experience suggests that farmers’ service cooperatives
provide the most effective way of improving the access of small farmers to market
services in areas where no private intermediaries operate or where private
intermediaries unfairly exploit farmers through monopolistic practices (Cobia,
1989). Such cooperatives can cover the whole field-to-market value chain,
including joint purchase of farm inputs, attention to water distribution and
irrigation (through Water User Associations), organization of machinery pools for
field work, establishment of sorting and packing facilities, transport of farm
products to markets, processing, etc. They can also provide agricultural extension
and market information services, as well as veterinary and artificial insemination
services, all of which are essential for productivity improvement in both crop and
livestock production.
Typical functions of an agricultural service cooperative can be described as
follows:
N the cooperative purchases farm inputs in bulk for all its members and is
thus able to negotiate lower prices and better terms through volume
discounts;
N the cooperative delivers and sells products from all its members jointly,
thus breaking through minimum-quantity barriers imposed by some large
buyers and chains (in addition to freeing the farmers from the need to travel
in person to the marketplace);
90
7. Cooperative Development in Central Asia
N the cooperative establishes processing facilities to create value added for
its members, while guaranteeing fair prices and terms for raw materials
delivered by its members;
N the cooperative maintains a pool of farm machinery and transport vehicles
to serve all its members, thus freeing small farmers from the need to
purchase expensive equipment on their own;
N the cooperative negotiates with the banks relatively large amounts of
credits for the entire contingent of its member-farmers, thus achieving
better terms and lower interest rates than each small farm would have
achieved for itself.
In dealing with a service cooperative, the market effectively deals with a
relatively large entity that combines many smallholders into a single negotiating
position. Access difficulties imposed by smallness are thus automatically lifted.
Service cooperatives overcome the “curse of smallness” by conducting market
transactions for a large number of small farmers simultaneously.
Service cooperatives do not rule out private initiative: private trade
intermediaries, integrators, and service providers may co-exist with service
cooperatives and continue their currently developing operations. In parallel with
encouraging the development of service cooperatives for the benefit of small
farmers, government policies should also encourage and facilitate the operation
of rural private intermediaries – by simplifying licensing arrangements,
implementing more flexible inspection procedures, cultivating a generally
friendly and helpful attitude among the local officials, and perhaps granting tax
credits on transactions with agricultural producers. The government should also
consider establishing special credit facilities for expansion of business activities
of such rural intermediaries.
Service cooperatives as an example of self-organization in the rural sector are
created “bottom-up” and farmers obviously need guidance on how to create such
institutions. Providing such guidance is the function of special information and
training systems that the government or donors should establish for the
development of cooperatives. Furthermore, new cooperatives may require
support through grants or subsidized credit, but the self-organizing nature of the
system of cooperatives ensures relatively easy rollout to remote rural locations.
An important component for successful development of service cooperatives (as
well as private support services) is a change in government attitude: instead of
persisting in the negative attitude of total neglect and disdain of household plots
and small family farms, government officials and decision makers have to
acknowledge their importance, abandon the traditional preference for large farms,
91
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
and focus on policies that ensure a supportive market environment for successful
operation of the small-farm sector – including policies to encourage creation of
service cooperatives. This change of attitude will require a comprehensive “reeducation” effort in all ministries and should probably be guided from the level
of the central government.
Western Classification of Cooperatives
International Cooperative Alliance (ICA) defines a cooperative as an
autonomous association of persons united voluntarily to meet their common
economic, social, and cultural needs and aspirations through a jointly owned
and democratically-controlled enterprise (ICA, 2013). The persons who
voluntarily unite to form a cooperative are usually referred to as members or
member-owners, and one of the key attributes of membership is active
participation in the activity of the cooperative (whether economic, business, or
social). A cooperative is a legal entity and in a certain sense it is an analogue of a
shareholder corporation. There are, however, some fundamental differences
between a cooperative and a corporation, as listed in Table 7.1.
Table 7.1. Comparative attributes of a cooperative and a shareholder corporation
Attribute
Owners
Owners’ objective
Organization’s objective
Voting rights
Income distribution rules
Cooperative
Members
Use of services provided by the
cooperative
Maximize members’ benefits
from working with the
cooperative
One member–one vote,
regardless of share contribution
Income distributed to members
in proportion to their
participation in the activity of
the cooperative
Corporation
Shareholders–investors
Earning income
Maximize corporate profits
Number of votes proportional
to number of shares (i.e.,
share contribution)
Income distributed to
shareholders in proportion to
the number of shares held
Perhaps the main difference concerns the organization’s objective: while
business corporations aim to maximize their profit, cooperatives aim to maximize
the benefits that members derive from their participation in cooperative activities,
including lower prices paid for inputs and services and higher prices received for
products (Cobia, 1998).
The Western cooperative paradigm distinguishes between production
cooperatives, service cooperatives, and consumer cooperatives based on their
functional characteristics.
92
7. Cooperative Development in Central Asia
Production cooperatives are cooperatives in which members are jointly
engaged in the production process – irrespective of whether this is production of
manufactured goods, agricultural commodities, or services. These may include:
N Manufacturing cooperatives, usually called employee owned or labor
managed firms. They used to be very popular in former Yugoslavia before
1989, but they are also observed in Western countries (Mondragon
Cooperative Corporation in Spain, Ha’Argaz Metal Works in Israel, and
others).
N Agricultural production cooperatives, in which members jointly cultivate
cooperatively held agricultural resources, such as land or farm machinery,
producing a variety of farm products. Collective farms in the former Soviet
Union and kibbutzim in Israel are examples of agricultural production
cooperatives.
N Cooperatives that produce services for sale to the general public (Avis
Rent-A-Car world-wide, United Airlines in the U.S., Egged Transportation
Cooperative in Israel, and others). These are usually characterized as
employee owned or labor managed firms (like manufacturing
cooperatives): they are not called “service cooperatives”, because this term
is reserved for cooperatives that sell services to members, not third parties
(the sales clientele criterion).
Production cooperatives sell their output to outsiders; yet the main function of
production cooperatives is to improve the wellbeing of their members by
providing jobs and working conditions that are superior to what would otherwise
be available in the market.
The rationale for the creation of production cooperatives is notionally the same
as for service cooperatives. In agriculture, for instance, it is often argued that by
allowing members to pool their fragmented smallholdings into large farms
production cooperatives exploit economies of scale and achieve higher efficiency.
Yet empirical studies in market economies show that economies of scale do not
generally exist in primary agriculture and many researchers have in fact shown
that agricultural production cooperatives are substantially less efficient than
individual and family farms. As a result, production cooperatives in the world are
a tiny minority among organizations that produce manufactured goods,
agricultural products, or services. According to ICA data, production cooperatives
account for less than 5% of all cooperatives in the world
Service cooperatives, on the other hand, are the largest and most typical
category of cooperatives: these are cooperatives that provide services to their
93
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
7
members-producers, who continue to carry out all production activities
independently on their own. In contrast to the minor role of production
cooperatives in market economies, service cooperatives in many countries
account for a large share of transactions in the relevant economic sector. For
instance, agricultural marketing, processing, and supply cooperatives (see below)
are major players in markets for farm products and farm inputs in North America,
Western Europe, Japan, and South-East Asia. In the U.S., agricultural
cooperatives handle about 30% of farmers’ total farm marketing volume and 28%
of farmers’ total supply purchases (Mather et al., 2004). In the European Union,
the share of agricultural cooperatives is even larger: in countries such as the
Netherlands, Denmark, Ireland, and Sweden 70%-80% of farm products are
marketed through cooperatives and cooperatives account for 50%-70% of all farm
input purchases (Van Bekkum and Van Dijk, 1997).
Service cooperatives may actually employ some of their members as workers,
but most employees (and even most managers) are hired outsiders. Service
cooperatives use members’ share contributions to capital and borrowed funds to
finance purchase of goods and services from various market sources and then
resell these services to members at advantageous prices.
Service cooperatives exist in many different areas of economic activity.
Agricultural service cooperatives are usually subdivided into:
N Marketing cooperatives: cooperatives that collect and prepare members’
produce for sale, truck it to the market, and arrange for actual sale at prices
that are higher than what would be normally attained by the farmers
themselves;
N Processing cooperatives: cooperatives that buy members’ produce for
processing at fair prices (often vertically integrated as the last downstream
link in marketing cooperatives);
N Input supply cooperatives: cooperatives that exploit the benefits of size
to purchase inputs (fertilizers, chemicals, fuel, seeds, animal feed, etc.) or
specialized services (veterinary medicine, artificial insemination) at prices
and terms beneficial to members-producers;
N Machinery cooperatives (or machinery pools): pools (fleets) of farm
machinery jointly owned by groups of members in situations when it is too
7
For this reason, service cooperatives are sometimes called in English “producer’s cooperatives” (as
distinct from “production cooperatives”), or “farmer’s cooperatives” in agriculture. In Russian this term
would be translated as dhhi_jZlb\u ijhba\h^bl_e_c (kooperativy proizvoditelei), to distinguish it
from ijhba\h^kl\_ggu_ dhhi_jZlb\u (proizvodstvennye kooperativy), which is the accepted Russian
term for “production cooperatives”.
94
7. Cooperative Development in Central Asia
expensive or too inefficient for each farmer to purchase machinery
independently;
N Agricultural extension and information management cooperatives:
services to upgrade the human capital of cooperative membership through
training, education, knowledge exchange, and management information
technologies provided by hired experts.
There are many examples of service cooperatives outside agriculture:
N
N
N
N
N
N
N
N
N
N
rural electric power cooperatives,
renewable energy cooperatives,
rural telephone cooperatives,
healthcare cooperatives (the cooperative hires healthcare professionals
for the benefit of its members),
housing cooperatives
cooperative schools, nurseries, child-care facilities,
cooperative art galleries (a “marketing cooperative” for art “produced”
by member artists)
credit unions and cooperative banks
cooperative (mutual) insurance companies
auditing and accounting cooperatives (usually serving other
cooperatives, not individuals)
All these are examples of situations where private entrepreneurs find it
unprofitable to enter and provide the basic service, or alternatively the private
entrepreneurs enjoy a monopolistic position that leads to exploitation of the
consumers. In agriculture and other areas, service cooperatives thus fulfill the
important function of correcting for market failure, by stepping in to provide
missing services and counteracting monopolistic exploitation by private initiative.
Consumer cooperatives in Western nomenclature are trading firms that sell
consumer goods primarily to their members at advantageous prices. They are
basically a variety of supply cooperatives (outside agriculture), but they are
treated as a separate class because of their numerical importance in the world. The
largest segment of consumer cooperatives is cooperative food stores and
supermarkets (“grocery stores”), but cooperative stores that sell clothes,
housewares, appliances, and even cars to their members – at advantageous prices
– also fall in the category of consumer cooperatives. In the West, consumer
cooperatives, unlike other service cooperatives, are most likely to deal with nonmembers (“third parties”) on a regular basis: this is their strategy of achieving
95
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
growth comparable with other firms in the highly competitive consumer services
sector.
Figure 7.1. Schema of a service or consumer
cooperative.
Figure 7.2. Schema of a production cooperative.
Figures 7.1 and 7.2 schematically illustrate the organizational differences
between service (or consumer) cooperative and production cooperative. The
service cooperative is created by members-producers who retain their legal and
operational independence, operating outside the cooperative (Figure 7.1). Twoway relations exist between the members and the cooperative: members may
deliver their output to the cooperative for selling to outside customers, and
members may acquire from the cooperative inputs and services that the
cooperative purchases from outside suppliers. Money flows from the cooperative
to members as payment for their deliveries and from members to the cooperative
as payment for their purchases. Member participation in the activity of the
cooperative (either selling or buying) is typically a precondition of membership,
although there is no obligation for the members to sell all their output or purchase
all their inputs exclusively through the cooperative.
In a production cooperative, members typically work inside the cooperative,
and not as independent entities (Figure 7.2). They engage in joint production
using pooled resources (land or machinery); the cooperative sells the jointly
produced output in the market and purchases inputs for the joint production
process – not for individual members.
Classification of Cooperatives in Legislation in Central Asia
The legislative base in all five Central Asian countries includes a variety of
laws on cooperatives (Table 7.2), starting with cooperation laws inherited directly
from the Soviet system (1991-1992) and ending with latest efforts to adapt the
96
7. Cooperative Development in Central Asia
cooperative legislation to Western principles (the 2005 Kyrgyzstan Law of
Cooperatives and the 2013 Tajikistan Law of Cooperatives).
Nevertheless, there is deep-rooted lack of understanding of the exact nature of
cooperative in Central Asia and throughout the CIS. Ever since the Soviet time,
legislation on cooperation and cooperatives included the standard ICA principles
of voluntary membership and democratic control (see above). Although in
practice these principles were blatantly abused by the state, there is by now
general familiarity with the standard formula of voluntary membership and the
goal of maximizing members’ benefits from participation in the cooperative.
However, there is lack of clarity as to what types of cooperatives exist, how they
correspond to the Western typology of cooperatives, and how the newly promoted
service cooperatives are different from the Soviet-style production cooperatives
(collective farms).
Cooperative legislation in Central Asia (which necessarily draws on the
corresponding definitions from the Civil Code and has its roots in the 1988 USSR
Law on Cooperation) distinguishes between production cooperatives
(proizvodstvennye kooperativy) and consumer cooperatives (potrebitel’skie
kooperativy). Unfortunately, the meaning that the existing legislation imparts to
these two familiar-sounding terms is different from the accepted meaning in
Western usage.
Furthermore, the term “service cooperative” (servisnyi kooperativ,
obsluzhivayushchii kooperativ) is generally not mentioned in Central Asian
legislation: it occurs only once in two versions of the Kyrgyzstan Law of
Cooperatives – 1999 and 2005, and the standard range of service functions is
apparently entrusted to “consumer cooperatives”. 8
8
The issue of proper classification becomes even more difficult when we notice that in addition to “laws
of cooperatives” the Central Asian countries also have so-called “laws of cooperation” or “laws of
consumer cooperation”, which were passed in 1991-1992 based on Soviet concepts of cooperation.
These “laws of consumer cooperation” deal with so-called “rural consumer societies” – part of a
centrally imposed state-run system (formerly known as Tsentrosoyuz in the Soviet Union) whose
function was to supply consumer goods to the rural population and sell the output produced on
household plots. The administrators of the “consumer cooperation system” remain a powerful lobby to
this day and the system, although hardly functioning, is so entrenched in former Soviet countries that
Tajikistan, for instance, had to retain the 1992 Law of Consumer Cooperation in its statutes in parallel
with the new 2013 Law of Cooperatives.
97
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
Table 7.2. Cooperative legislation in Central Asia 1991-2013
Kazakhstan
1991
Kyrgyzstan
Law of
Cooperation
1992
1994
1995
Civil Code:
Production Coop
(articles 96-101)
Law of Production
Cooperatives
Civil Code (amnd):
Consumer Coop
(article 108)
1999
Law of Rural
Consumer
Cooperation
2000
Law of
Agricultural
Partnerships and
Their Associations
Law of Consumer
Cooperatives
(excluding rural
consumer
cooperation)
2005
2013
Uzbekistan
Law of
Cooperation
(revised 1993-98)
Law of
Peasant
Associations
Law of
Agricultural
[Production]
Coops (Shirkats)
Law of
Cooperation
2002
2003
Turkmenistan
Law of
Consumer
Cooperation
Law of Consumer
Cooperation
1998
2001
Tajikistan
Civil Code:
Production Coops
(articles 118-123);
Consumer Coops
(article 128)
Law of Production
Cooperatives
Law of Rural
Consumer
Cooperatives of
Water Users
(“Water User
Association”)
Law of
Cooperatives
``
Law of
Cooperatives
The so-called “consumer” cooperatives appear to be functionally closest to the
Western notion of service cooperative. Their functions, according to the 2001
Kazakhstan Law of Consumer Cooperatives, include marketing, input supply,
processing, and other service activities. The Kyrgyzstan Law of Cooperatives (in
its 1999 and 2005 version) contains a rare mention of the term “service
cooperative” with an explicit list of its functions: marketing, storage, and packing
of farm products, veterinary services, fertilizer application, plant protection,
construction, transport, extension services, and more. On the other hand, the 2013
98
7. Cooperative Development in Central Asia
Tajikistan Law of Cooperatives does not elaborate the specific functions of either
consumer or service cooperatives, simply stating in very general terms that
cooperatives may engage in all legal activities involving production and provision
of various services (including consumer services). This non-specific attitude
toward consumer cooperatives in Tajikistan legislation may be regarded as a
carryover from the 1999 Tajikistan Civil Code, which devotes a long article to
consumer cooperatives but only says that their function is “to satisfy the material
needs of members”.
“Production” cooperatives receive very vague definition in Central Asian
legislation. They are typically characterized as engaging in “joint production and
other activities”. The 2005 Kyrgyzstan Law of Cooperatives includes a very terse
and simple definition of a production cooperative as engaging in joint production,
without mentioning anything about services. The 2013 Tajikistan Law of
Cooperatives does not devote special place to production cooperatives (despite
their prominence in the Civil Code), merely stating that cooperatives may engage
in production alongside a range of other activities. The 1999 Tajikistan Civil Code
elaborates the “other activities” by listing processing, marketing, contract work,
trade, and consumer services, so that a production cooperative emerges as a mix
of the Western notions of production cooperative and service cooperative.
Continuing the established Soviet tradition, production cooperatives in Central
Asia and all of CIS use the pooled land and assets of the members for joint
production (like a collective farm) and provide marketing and supply services to
the joint production process, not to its members: the production cooperatives sell
the jointly produced output to third parties (a marketing service) and provide
supply services (e.g., purchase of farm inputs, provision of farm machinery) to
the joint production process, not to individual members. In this respect,
production cooperatives in Central Asia are similar to production cooperatives in
the West (to the extent that such exist), but in addition to supporting joint
production, production cooperatives in CIS also supply services to members that
are intended for the members’ subsistence-oriented household plots and are a
byproduct of the cooperative’s collective production activity. This appears to be
a unique feature of production cooperatives in the CIS, as Western production
cooperatives carefully disassociate their primary business activities (joint
production) from the individual farming activities of their members. The two
levels of service provision in production cooperatives in Central Asia – services
for joint production and services to members’ household plots – strengthen the
impression these are essentially a mix of production and service cooperative.
It seems that the legal distinction between production and consumer
cooperatives in Central Asian legislation is not based on functional attributes (i.e.,
99
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
what the cooperatives do). Instead, cooperatives are classified based on formal
business-related attributes (Table 7.3), such as profit-making behavior
(“commercial”, i.e., “for profit” organizations and “non-commercial”, i.e., “not
for profit” organizations), clientele orientation (sales to members or nonmembers), and composition of the labor force (members work or do not work in
the cooperative). Unfortunately, these formal attributes are ambiguous and fuzzy
for cooperatives, and thus do not allow cooperatives to be classified into two
disjoint groups.
Table 7.3. Classification of cooperatives in Central Asian legislation
Production cooperative
Legal body
Commercial (“for profit”) organization
Sales to third parties only
Members part of the labor force
Consumer cooperative
Legal body
Non-commercial (“not-for-profit”) organization
Sales mostly to members
Members not necessarily part of the labor force
First, the notion of profit in a cooperative is vague and unclear. Some
international authorities argue that all cooperatives are essentially not-for-profit,
because their goal is to maximize the members’ benefits by lowering the prices
that they charge and raising the prices that they pay. Profits are reduced to zero
(or almost zero) by this pricing policy. 9 Furthermore, there is no reason to assume
a difference in profit orientation between the two groups of production and
consumer cooperatives: under the current Law on Consumer Cooperation in
Tajikistan (1991) consumer cooperatives include retail and wholesale traders,
providers of food and other services, traders in consumer goods, etc., which in
principle are not less profit-making than other cooperatives. The attributes of “forprofit” (commercial) and “not-for-profit” (non-commercial) are too ambiguous to
be used as classification attributes for cooperatives and should be removed from
future legislation.
Second, there are also difficulties with the sales clientele attribute (“production
cooperatives” selling mainly to third parties versus “consumer cooperatives”
selling mainly to members). Production cooperatives in the sense of cooperatives
in which members produce goods or services indeed sell their output to outsiders,
i.e., third parties. But this is the Western definition of production cooperative,
whereas in Tajikistan legislation (Civil Code, Article 118) production
cooperatives also engage in processing and sale of agricultural products, contract
work (e.g., plowing or harvesting), trade, provision of services, and other
9
The Civil Code of Switzerland (OR Art. 828) specifically defines all cooperatives as not-for-profit.
This was noted by H.-H. Muenkner in materials prepared for the discussion of the draft Law of
Cooperatives in Tajikistan (September-November 2011)
100
7. Cooperative Development in Central Asia
activities that do not involve production – activities that mainly target members –
not third parties – as the sales clientele. In Western nomenclature these
cooperatives are called service cooperatives, not production cooperatives (Table
7.4), and they are definitely member-oriented in their sales, whereas the Civil
Code of Tajikistan puts them in the category of production cooperatives that are
supposed to sell to third parties only. Finally, consumer cooperatives in the sense
of food and other retail traders (as defined in the West) indeed sell to members,
but the proportion of non-member sales in these cooperatives is steadily growing
and according to Tajikistan legislation eventually they will have to be transformed
into production cooperatives – although they do not engage in any production.
These terminological inconsistencies suggest that the feature of selling to third
parties vs. selling to members should also be dropped as a classification attribute
for cooperatives.
Table 7.4. Functions of “production cooperative” as defined in the 1999 Civil Code of Tajikistan
(Art. 118) and their classification according to Western views of production, service, and
consumer cooperatives
Functions of “production cooperative”
according to Civil Code of Tajikistan
Production
Processing
Sale of products
Contract jobs, custom work
Trade
For and with producers
For and with consumers
Consumer goods and services
Other services
Services to producers
Services to consumers, general population
Western classification of respective
functions
Production cooperative
Service cooperative
Service cooperative
Service cooperative
Depends on specifics
Service cooperative
Consumer cooperative
Consumer cooperative
Depends on specifics
Service cooperative
Consumer cooperative
Need for Consistent Definitions
The terms “production cooperative” and “consumer cooperative” as used in
Central Asian legislation are inconsistent with the accepted Western terminology.
A consistent set of definitions of service, consumer, and production cooperatives
should be introduced into legislation, based on functional features (including
appropriate amendments in the Civil Code).
Clear unambiguous definition of different types of cooperatives – production,
service, and consumer – is essential to ensure acceptance of the concept of
cooperatives by the rural population. In market economies, the term “cooperative”
is automatically interpreted as a service cooperative. In Central Asia, as in all CIS
countries, the term “cooperative” is still automatically understood as a production
101
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
cooperative – the model of a former kolkhoz or collective farm. Having been
exposed for decades to the negative experience with such “production
cooperatives”, rural people may persist in their negative view of the whole
concept of cooperatives and reject any proposals to form cooperatives, even when
the intention is to create service cooperatives, not old-style production
cooperatives (Plunkett Foundation, 1995). The new legislative framework must
acknowledge this psychological barrier to cooperatives by introducing
unambiguous definitions that will prevent any possibility of misunderstanding or
misinterpreting the strategic intentions.
A special public awareness campaign should be organized to explain what
cooperatives are in market economies, how they function, and what benefits
farmers derive from membership. The educational effort should make it
abundantly clear that service cooperatives are intended to improve smallholders’
access to services, thus overcoming many of the difficulties associated with small
farm sizes while allowing each member to maintain their independence as a
producer. Service cooperatives are not intended to overcome the problem of land
fragmentation by merging small farms into larger production units: this is the role
of production cooperatives, which are very rare in market economies, largely due
to their lower efficiency compared with individual and family farms. The public
awareness campaign should be carried out by a special cooperative information
service to be established by the government with donor support. This should be a
permanent system that will continue providing information to farmers and
cooperatives over the long term, and not only during the creation and setup phase.
The system can be modeled on existing cooperative information services in the
U.S., the Netherland, and other developed countries.
Taxation of Cooperatives
Service cooperatives have the potential to increase the benefits to members by
exercising their market power and negotiating better prices and improved terms
both for sale of member products and for delivery of services. Yet tax distortions
may negate these positive effects and make membership in a cooperative an
ineffective proposition for farmers. Tax issues must be carefully addressed and
resolved if cooperatives are to have any chance of developing in Central Asia.
Farmers join cooperatives with the objective of getting higher prices for their
products and paying lower prices for the inputs and services they buy. The
cooperative model achieves these objectives in two ways. First, a cooperative
represents many farmers in the market and thus enjoys greater market power than
each small farmer individually. The cooperative can negotiate lower prices for
wholesale bulk purchases of inputs and pressure traders into paying higher prices
102
7. Cooperative Development in Central Asia
for guaranteed deliveries of high-quality products. Second, the cooperative does
not aim to maximize its profits: in fact it distributes all its profits to members in
proportion to their participation in cooperative activities, thus increasing
members’ revenues and reducing their costs compared to what they could achieve
by dealing with private profit-maximizing intermediaries. These two mechanisms
usually guarantee that cooperative members fare better than smallholder farmers
selling and buying independently. In principle this provides an incentive for
joining a cooperative, but there is a danger that taxation of cooperatives may
negate the membership benefits and discourage farmers from becoming members.
A cooperative is a legal body and three types of taxes may negatively affect
the benefits that members receive from their cooperative:
N VAT on transactions between the cooperative and its members
N Retail sales tax on transactions between the cooperative and its members
N Tax on accounting profits reported by the cooperative
The social tax is often mentioned as a serious problem for rural people, but
this tax is paid by everybody – farmers and cooperatives alike – and is not activitybased. It is therefore not relevant for the present discussion.
The Law of Cooperatives and, more importantly, the Tax Code, should address
the three types of taxes in the following way.
Exemption from Value Added Tax
Peasant farmers pay VAT on their purchases from suppliers. The cooperative
also pays VAT to suppliers, but then the cooperative has to charge VAT on its
sales to members. As a result, members may end up paying to the cooperative
more than what they would have paid independently to a supplier. To avoid
negative effects of VAT on the relations between cooperatives and their members,
all transactions with members – supply, provision of services, contract work –
should be exempt from VAT. In addition to a provision in the national cooperative
law, an appropriate amendment has to be added to the national tax codes. This is
the only way to ensure that the provision is respected in practice by tax inspectors.
The recommended approach to VAT exemption of cooperative transactions
with members is an excellent example of the principle of “fiscal transparency”
applied to cooperatives in the Netherlands. In this country, with its outstanding
tradition of cooperation in agriculture and other sectors, transactions between
members and their cooperative are exempt from all taxes, not only VAT. This
gives recognition to the “not-for-profit” status of cooperatives and makes the
103
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
entire surplus available for distribution to members, without subjecting it to taxes
on profit.
Exemption from Retail Sales Tax
Retail sales tax is common in Central Asian countries and the rest of CIS.
Household plots are exempt from this tax by definition, whereas peasant farms,
although legally liable, usually manage to avoid retail sales tax on their direct
sales to consumers in the market. Avoidance becomes impossible when peasant
farms (or even household plots) sell to legal bodies, such as processors or, in the
future, marketing cooperatives: in such cases, the legal body pays the retail sales
tax and passes this tax as an additional charge to members. However, sales to a
processor or a marketing cooperative are in principle not retail sales: these are
wholesale transactions and should be exempt from the retail sales tax. Yet, in
reality, tax authorities enforce collection of retail sales tax also on wholesale
transactions with processors. This issue must be resolved, as payment of retail
sales tax on transactions with marketing cooperatives will place cooperative
members (whether peasant farms or household plots) at a distinct disadvantage
compared to non-members.
It will also be necessary to exempt cooperatives from any retail sales tax on
inputs delivered to members: this will have to be resolved in the spirit of “fiscal
transparency” as in the VAT exemption amendment. Transactions between
members and the cooperative – whether sale of products by members to the
cooperative or sale of inputs by the cooperative to members – should not be
subject to retail sales tax. This principle should be officially recognized and
included in formal instructions to tax inspectors at all levels.
Exemption of Distributions to Members from Profit Tax
Although in principle cooperatives are non-profit organizations, their financial
reports may show an accounting profit at the level of revenues and expenses
(called “surplus” in cooperative accounting). This accounting profit is created
because the cooperative may have initially underpaid its members for products
delivered (expenses too low) or overcharged them for inputs supplied (revenues
too high). In effect the accounting profit is the result of internal pricing decisions
within the cooperative, and not profit in the usual economic sense of the term.
As an example, let us consider the relations between member-farmers and their
marketing service cooperative. Members produce independently on their plots
and deliver their products (milk, vegetables, honey) to the cooperative. The
members do not deal with retail sales to consumers: this function is entrusted to
104
7. Cooperative Development in Central Asia
the marketing cooperative. Receiving the products from its members, the
cooperative makes the first payment to members calculated on the basis of
estimated market or near-market prices. This first-wave payment to members is
an advance on account of products received: the final accounting is made at the
end of a quarter or a year, when the cooperative prepares its financial report. If
the financial report shows an accounting profit (“surplus” in Western cooperative
terminology) after deducting the first-wave payments to the members and other
operating expenses incurred by the cooperative during the period, this essentially
indicates that the cooperative underpaid the members for the products delivered
during the reporting period. The surplus in principle should be distributed as a
second payment to the members in proportion to their deliveries to the
cooperative. In the end, the members may receive from the cooperative a price
higher than the market price that they would have received by selling
independently to the consumers. If the financial report shows an accounting loss
(i.e., “deficit” or negative “surplus”), this indicates that the cooperative overpaid
the members for the products delivered during the reporting period. The deficit is
also distributed to the members in proportion to their deliveries and is recorded
as a debit entry in the accounts of each member, to be covered from next year
sales or special funds maintained by the cooperative.
The same considerations exactly apply to the relations between members and
a supply cooperative, which purchases inputs (fertilizers, seeds, feed, etc.) from
suppliers at wholesale prices and re-sells them to members. Members initially pay
an advance to the cooperative to cover the estimated cost of the inputs (first-wave
payments). If the financial report at the end of the period shows positive “surplus”
(accounting profit), this means that the cooperative initially overcharged the
members for the inputs and the “surplus” is distributed to the members in
proportion to their purchases through the cooperative. This effectively lowers the
end price that members pay to the cooperative for inputs. If the financial report
shows a “deficit” (accounting loss), this means that the cooperative initially
undercharged the members for their purchases and the “deficit” is also allocated
to members in proportion to their purchases. A similar scheme is applied in other
service cooperatives, including cooperatives that provide machinery services to
members using a jointly owned pool of farm machines.
Cooperatives do not know in advance, at the time of the actual transaction,
how much to pay to members for product deliveries and how much to charge for
input supplies and other services. Financial settlements with members are handled
in two waves: the first-wave payments and charges are in the nature of an initial
advance, and the final settlement is made at the end of the period, when the
financial statements have been prepared. As a result, a service cooperative usually
105
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
presents a financial statement that shows a positive surplus (accounting profit) or
a deficit (accounting loss) according to the scheme in Table 7.5.
Table 7.5. Schematic “profit and loss” statement of a cooperative
Marketing cooperative
Revenues from sale of members’ products to
third parties
Costs:
First-wave payments to members
Operating costs of the cooperative
Gross income (surplus/deficit)
Supply cooperative
Revenues: first-wave payments from members
Costs:
Paid to suppliers
Operating costs of the cooperative
Gross income (surplus/deficit)
Gross income (^hoh^ in Russian) represents the surplus or deficit that is
further allocated by three channels:
1) Allocation to the cooperative reserve fund or other capital funds
(“retention of earnings” in standard accounting terminology).
2) Distribution to members in proportion to their share contribution to the
cooperative capital (“dividends” in standard Western terminology; iZ_\u_
\uieZlu in Russian).
3) Patronage refunds (dhhi_jZlb\gu_ \uieZlu) in proportion to the
members’ use of cooperative services (i.e., basically in proportion to firstwave payments to the members).
The sum of the three amounts distributed to members is equal to gross income.
Patronage refunds are determined as the difference between gross income and the
first two allocations (Table 7.6).
Table 7.6. Allocation of profit in a service cooperative
Gross income:
Less allocation to reserve fund and other funds
Less distribution in proportion to share contribution (iZ_\u_ \uieZlu, “dividends”)
Difference available for distribution as patronage refunds (dhhi_jZlb\gu_ \uieZlu)
Conventional interpretation of the tax code will require the cooperative to pay
tax on the full gross income at applicable rates. Recognition of the special nature
of patronage refunds in cooperatives (as second-wave adjustment of initial overor under-payment to members) and the Dutch principle of “fiscal transparency”
suggest that this component of gross income should not be taxable. Furthermore,
the U.S. tax code recognizes “dividends” paid to members in agricultural
cooperatives (but not other cooperatives) as non-taxable at the cooperative level,
i.e., exempt from withholding taxes (Autry and Hall, 2009). If the Dutch and the
U.S. tax principles are adopted, the cooperative will be required to pay tax only
106
7. Cooperative Development in Central Asia
on the share of gross income retained in reserve fund and other capital funds. The
amount retained in the reserve fund and other capital funds will be shown net after
deduction of the appropriate taxes.
Recognizing the need to exempt patronage refunds (dhhi_jZlb\gu_
\uieZlu) from taxation, the 2013 Law of Cooperatives in Tajikistan introduced
an important provision in Art. 36(3):
Payments to cooperative members in accordance
with their participation in cooperative activities
and payment of bonuses/honoraria to
cooperative managers are treated as expenses.
<uieZluqe_gZfdhhi_jZlb\Z\khhl\_lkl\bb
kbomqZklb_f\ohayckl\_gghc^_yl_evghklb
dhhi_jZlb\Zb\uieZlu\hagZ]jZ`^_gbc
^he`ghklgufebpZfdhhi_jZlb\Zhlghkylky
djZkoh^Zfdhhi_jZlb\Z
The explicit wording in the Law of Cooperatives is particularly important for
achieving the desired effect as the 2005 Law of Cooperatives in Kyrgyzstan, for
instance, contains a blanket statement deferring all tax-related decisions in
cooperatives to the Tax Code (Article 32). The 2009 Tax Code of Kyrgyzstan
indeed exempts agricultural service cooperatives from VAT on transactions with
members (Article 239) and from retail sales tax (Article 259). It also exempts
from taxation the profit of agricultural service cooperatives (Article 212), thus
guaranteeing a special status for patronage refunds. Yet expert opinions in
Kyrgyzstan indicate that these provisions are not observed in their entirety by tax
inspectors, perhaps because they are relatively new and unfamiliar (the relevant
version of the Tax Code was adopted in July 2009).
The provision concerning exemption of patronage refunds from profit tax in
Tajikistan, in addition to the proposed VAT and retail sales tax amendments, is a
very important step toward establishing “fiscal transparency” for cooperatives. To
be effective, this provision must be incorporated as an amendment in the Tax
Code (following the example of Kyrgyzstan): expert opinions suggest that tax
authorities in Tajikistan (and probably also in other countries in Central Asia)
refuse to follow provisions in specific laws unless they are also reflected in the
Tax Code and the courts are reluctant to rule against the tax authorities in such
instances. We furthermore recommend following the U.S. practice and exempt
share payments (iZ_\u_ \uieZlu) from taxation in agricultural service
cooperatives.
107
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
Observations from the Field: Cooperatives in Tajikistan and
Kyrgyzstan
Agricultural development strategies in both Tajikistan and Kyrgyzstan
emphasize the development of service cooperatives as one of the priorities
(Tajikistan Strategy, 2011; Kyrgyzstan Strategy, 2012). This obviously
strengthens the need for precise and consistent definitions of different types of
cooperatives in national legislation and emphasizes the urgency of resolving the
taxation issues. This section describes the cooperative scene in Tajikistan and
Kyrgyzstan as it emerges from recent field visits and interviews.
Fledgling Service Cooperatives in Tajikistan10
Several donor organizations work actively on the establishment of agricultural
service cooperatives in Tajikistan. These include Acted, OSCE, GIZ/TAFF, and
the Aga Khan Foundation. Unfortunately donor experiences and monitoring
efforts have not been documented (with the possible exception of the GIZ/TAFF
TAG groups) and it is very difficult to analyze the actual achievements of these
efforts so far. It is even impossible to map the existing donor-established
cooperatives across Tajikistan to get a sense of spread and coverage.
Visits to northern Tajikistan (Khatlon, Sughd, and Rasht provinces) have
revealed the existence of authentic service cooperatives created bottom-up by
groups of local farmers.
N One example is an apricot-drying cooperative (registered as a consumer
cooperative) with a membership of 20 independent apricot growers, which
operates jointly owned apricot-drying and almond-extracting equipment. It
bags and sells dried apricots and almonds extracted from apricot pits,
actively looking for trade outlets and export opportunities. In addition to
marketing activities, it also supplies fertilizer to its members. It is officially
registered as a consumer cooperative.
N Another example is a machinery pool with several pieces of farm
machinery that provides mechanized field services to its members and also
to non-members (charging 30% higher prices). The machinery coop also
sells fertilizer and fuel to members, charging a mere 2% markup. In an
attempt to ensure sustainability, the cooperative has applied for land to
develop an apricot orchard: its strategy thus includes diversifying into
10
This section is based on impressions from field visits in northern Tajikistan organized by FAO-TJ in
March 2012.
108
7. Cooperative Development in Central Asia
production activities as a mixed service/production cooperative, which
highlights the prevailing confusion between different types of cooperatives.
N A vivid illustration of the bottom-up approach is provided by the “interest
group” of some 20 small peasant farmers in Rasht Province, each with 1-2
hectares of land, who organized (with assistance from the Aga Khan
Foundation) to overcome the bottleneck with access to quality seed
potatoes and to renovate an existing potato storage facility. The “interest
group” initially did not register as a coop, because members decided to
accumulate some experience before applying to the Ministry of Justice for
formal registration.
The cooperatives interviewed in northern Tajikistan are typically managed by
former collective-farm specialists (agronomists or livestock professionals)
identified by the donor organizations. These specialists capitalize on their
professional experience by providing agricultural extension and advisory services
to local farmers (both members and non-members) through donor-sponsored
networks or associations.
A different example of village-level cooperative activities in Tajikistan is
provided by livestock herding as practiced everywhere across the country:
animals are collected from the village households and taken to pasture every
morning by a herder (chaban), who is typically one of the village residents with
cattle. The responsibility for the day’s herding rotates among the families in the
village. This cooperative organization relieves the individual farmers from routine
responsibility for herding their animals, just as produce collection by a marketing
cooperative relieves them from the responsibility of traveling to the town market.
Yet the cooperative grazing scheme in itself does not prevent unsustainable use
of the common pastures where the animals graze. This second objective was
achieved in an inventive way through the establishment of livestock committees
(“associations”) in Muminabad (a district in the east-central part of Khatlon
Province). The local livestock committee is responsible for dividing the common
pasture into ten fenced segments and establishing a grazing rota, so that on any
given day animals graze on one segment, while the other segments are allowed to
rest and recover (the rotation cycle is 5-7 days on each segment). The livestock
“cooperative” does not own any cattle – the animals remain in the ownership of
the village households. Yet the cooperative’s pasture planning activities provide
an important service to the members by promoting sustainable pasture
109
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
management and preserving pasture quality in the long run.11 In addition to
rotational grazing, the association used cooperative funds to establish watering
points and shelter for the animals, as well as initiate alfalfa seeding to improve
the nitrogen content of the pasture soil.
The cooperatives in Tajikistan are fledgling efforts which are badly in need of
training and guidance. The general feeling is that cooperatives, once launched
fairly effectively with donor assistance, are left pretty much on their own, without
follow-up assistance, monitoring, and guidance. Cooperative managers naturally
complain of difficulties with purchasing machinery or raising credit, but beyond
that it is clear that they are untrained and without experiencing in managing a
service cooperative. All cooperatives have formal business plans, but managers
need training and guidance on how to implement the plans and how to work
toward achieving their strategic objectives. Training and learning programs are
needed for existing and potential cooperative managers (and also members).
The field impressions in Tajikistan can be summarized as follows:
N the new cooperatives in Tajikistan are voluntary grass-roots initiatives,
created with initial donor guidance and financial support;
N they mainly engage in delivery of services, not joint production;
N they are often informal and created in a sporadic manner;
N they are characterized by small scale and limited scope of operations.
All these features place the new cooperatives in Tajikistan in stark contrast to
all-pervasive mandatory cooperation of the socialist era.
Dominance of Production Cooperatives in Kyrgyzstan 12
Some statistics on cooperatives in Kyrgyzstan have been available from two
sources: a special unit dealing with cooperative development in the Ministry of
Agricultural (largely without proper budgets or strategic guidance since 2008) and
National Statistics Committee (NSC). MinAg reports the number of registered
cooperatives, which showed impressive growth over time, rising from about 300
in 2004 to 1,300 in 2009 (Figure 7.3). 13 NSC, on the other hand, based its
11
The livestock associations were initiated by a project of Caritas Switzerland, which has since ended.
There is no evidence that, despite its promise, the original rotational grazing scheme has been adopted
in other parts of Tajikistan. For more information, see WOCAT (2010a, 2010b).
12
This section draws on official data from the Ministry of Agriculture of Kyrgyzstan and the National
Statistics Committee, as well as field data from a survey of cooperatives and peasant farms conducted
by FAO/REU in the spring of 2012 across the country.
13
These numbers do not include credit unions, created mainly by the Raiffeisen Foundation in
Kyrgyzstan (some 300 in 2009).
110
7. Cooperative Development in Central Asia
reporting on the number of active (operating) cooperatives. The gap between the
two sources is dramatic (Figure 7.3): in 2011, MinAg reported more than 1,400
registered cooperatives, while according to NSC there were just 400 active
cooperatives in the country (Kyrgyzstan in Numbers, 2012). It thus became
apparent that more than 70% of registered cooperatives in Kyrgyzstan were
inactive and existed only on paper, presumably with the intent of taking advantage
of future credit or taxation benefits that might materialize through government
policies.
Figure 7.3. Development of
cooperatives in Kyrgyzstan 20042011. Blue bars: registered
cooperatives from MinAg; red bar:
active cooperatives from National
Statistics Committee (Kyrgyzstan in
Numbers, 2012).
The dominant majority of registered cooperatives in MinAg statistics are
production cooperatives, not service cooperatives. In 2009, 88% of the registered
cooperatives were classified as production cooperatives and only 12% were
service and processing cooperatives. Unfortunately, the existing statistics are
limited to the number of cooperatives: there are no data on land endowments,
sales volumes, or the size of membership. Special surveys have to be conducted
to elicit any functional information.
FAO initiated such a survey of cooperatives in (FAO/REU survey, 2012). The
survey focused on 400 active cooperatives in the NSC database. The original
objective was to survey a sample of 100 cooperatives, collecting information
mainly on service cooperatives, with control information on some production
cooperatives. This objective could not be achieved, however, because virtually no
pure service cooperatives were found in the NSC database. Among 400 active
cooperatives only 17 were identified as mixed service/production cooperatives
and 3 as trade/service cooperatives (these were apparently closest to pure service
cooperatives). All these 20 service-oriented cooperatives were included in the
111
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
sample, which additionally included 37 production cooperatives for a total of 57
respondents. In addition to cooperatives, the survey also covered 1,000 peasant
farmers randomly selected across the country. These respondents provided
insights on the relations between users and cooperatives.
Judging by their asset base and activity profile, 52 of the 57 cooperatives in
the sample were in fact production cooperatives. They all reported that they
cultivated some agricultural land – a clear distinguishing characteristic of a
production cooperative. The land in cooperatives was typically contributed by the
members, who were the source for 57% of total agricultural land in the sample;
another 27% of land in cooperatives was leased from the municipality or the state.
The land endowment was very large, averaging 7,000 hectares in the sample.
Virtually all cooperatives (51 out of 57) reported that they engaged in agricultural
production – predominantly crops, with mixed crop-livestock farming in 11 of the
51 cooperatives. In other words, practically all the cooperatives painstaking
selected from official registers are actually production cooperatives, with not
more than 6 out of 57 cooperatives in the sample possibly qualifying as service
cooperatives (these are the six without primary production activities).
In addition to primary production, all cooperatives reported providing services
to both members and non-members. As explained in the discussion of cooperative
organization, provision of services to members and non-members is a typical
feature of production cooperatives and does not necessarily identify the
cooperative as a service cooperative. A production cooperative, in addition to
providing services to the joint production process where members work, also
supplies inputs to individual production in members’ subsidiary household plots
and sells some of its surplus inputs to non-members (for a higher price). Table
7.7 shows the percent of cooperatives in the sample that provide various services
to their members and non-members. The frequency of services to members is
substantially higher than the frequency of services to non-members (46%
compared with 17% averaged over 14 service categories). The main services
provided by more than 50% of cooperatives to members include marketing of
farm products (sales, storage, packing, and processing), fertilizer application,
mechanical field services, and transportation. Mechanical field services and
transportation are also the most common services provided to non-members,
presumably because the local production cooperative is the main source of farm
machinery and vehicles in rural areas. This, combined with the relatively high
percentage of cooperatives providing access to storage facilities for nonmembers, is a clear illustration of the positive role that cooperatives play in overall
rural development.
112
7. Cooperative Development in Central Asia
Table 7.7. Services provided by cooperatives in the sample (n=57)
Category of service
Sales of farm products
Storage
Packing
Processing
Fertilizer application
Machinery services
Transportation
Soil melioration
Information
Veterinary
Marketing services
Purchased inputs
Advisory
Construction
Average
Source: FAO/REU survey (2012).
For members
70
74
52
56
67
65
58
42
35
30
26
26
21
19
46
For non-members
19
23
21
18
12
28
33
21
19
9
12
5
11
5
17
Figure 7.4. Local service sufficiency
increases with the percent of
cooperatives that deliver the service.
Source: FAO/REU survey (2012).
A direct indication of the positive role that cooperatives play in rural life is
provided by the results shown in Figure 7.4. Here each dot represents one of 15
different services, such as storage of farm products, machinery services, input
purchases, product sales, and so on. For each of these services the cooperative
managers were asked if their cooperative supplied the particular service and to
what extent the local demand for the service was satisfied in their opinion (fully
satisfied, partially satisfied, not satisfied). The vertical axis in Figure 7.4 plots
the percentage of cases when the demand for each service was fully satisfied; the
horizontal axis is the percentage of cases when the service was delivered by the
coop. There is a clear positive correlation between the frequency of cases when
the local demand for the service was fully satisfied and the frequency of cases
113
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
when the particular service was delivered by the coop. Service sufficiency thus
clearly improves when cooperatives step in as service providers.
Taxation and financial performance
Two-thirds of cooperatives surveyed pay taxes, with land tax figuring as the
main tax (67% of respondents). The next in importance is the obligatory social
tax, which is reported by 40% of the cooperatives. Profit tax and VAT are reported
by very few cooperatives (17% and 2%, respectively), which indicates that the
tax code provisions explicitly exempting cooperatives from these taxes (see
above) are generally observed.
Taxes do not appear to be a major burden for cooperatives, as less than 10%
listed reduction of taxes among the demands for support from the government.
The main areas in which tax reductions were desired include purchase and leasing
of farm machinery (18% of respondents), construction services (17%), and sales
of farm products (16%).
Fully 80% of cooperatives surveyed do not receive any support from the
government and more than 40% state that they do not require any support.
Between 10% and 15% of the cooperatives expect to receive government support
in the form of subsidized prices, subsidized credit, and – importantly – training.
All this can be interpreted as signs of satisfactory financial performance.
Indeed, the majority of cooperatives (58%) report their financial situation as
stable or profitable and only the remaining 42% are loss-making.
Farmers’ attitudes toward cooperation
Informal cooperation is quite widespread among farmers in Kyrgyzstan. Fully
22% of farmers surveyed participate informally in some joint activity with other
nearby farmers (Figure 7.5). Joint use of farm machinery and transport facilities
is the most common, reported by 17% and 14% of respondents respectively. Joint
sales of farm products, joint purchase of inputs, and joint processing are also
reported, although with lower frequency of between 5% and 10% of respondents.
It is somewhat surprising to find that 10% of peasant farmers surveyed report
informal cooperation in agricultural production outside a production cooperative.
On the other hand, formal, organized cooperation is very limited among
peasant farmers in Kyrgyzstan. Only 8% of the 1,000 farmers surveyed (78
respondents) are members of an agricultural cooperative and fully 50% do not
belong to any association. It is noteworthy that 46% are members in Water User
Associations, which presumably have established themselves as an effective
114
7. Cooperative Development in Central Asia
institution for water management – not without large-scale promotion campaigns
by the government and the World Bank.
Figure 7.5. Informal cooperation in
various activities among family farms.
Source: FAO/REU survey (2012).
Among the small number of farmers who are members of a formal cooperative
(78 respondents), over 50% enjoy four main services: farm machinery, sales of
farm products, supply of fertilizers, and quality seeds (Table 7.8). Furthermore,
56% of these farmers produce independently, i.e., they receive services from their
cooperative without engaging in joint agricultural production. The survey thus
distinguishes between two groups of cooperative members among peasant
farmers: 44% are in effect members of a production cooperative and receive
services as such; 56% are in effect members of a service cooperative, or rather a
service component of a production cooperative: they receive services from the
cooperative while continuing to produce independently.
Table 7.8. Participation of cooperative members in various services and activities (percent of
respondents)
Area of cooperation
All coop Members who
members participate in
joint production
(n=78)
(n=34)
Joint production
44
Machinery for field work
59
Product sales
54
Seed supply
55
Fertilizer/chemicals supply 54
Ag processing
33
Animal feed
37
Average satisfaction rating
Source: FAO/REU survey (2012).
100
85
79
88
88
56
65
Members who
do not
participate in
joint production
(n=44)
0
39
34
30
27
16
16
Satisfaction
rating among
those using
the activity
59
61
64
67
62
58
55
61
Members in service cooperatives (i.e., those who do not participate in joint
production) receive basically the same services as members in production
115
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
cooperatives. However, the frequency of these services for farmers who are only
members of the service cooperative (i.e., do not participate in joint production) is
lower than the frequency for those who participate in joint production, although
the relative ranking is the same. In other words, farm machinery, sales of farm
products, supply of fertilizers, and quality seeds are the most frequently enjoyed
services for both groups of cooperative members.
Cooperative members are generally satisfied with the services they receive
from the cooperative: on average, over 60% of members who actually use the
various services report that they are satisfied.
Figure 7.6. Reasons for not
becoming a cooperative
member (n-922). Source:
FAO/REU survey (2012).
The large gap between the frequency of formal and informal cooperation (8%
and 22% of farmers, respectively) clearly suggests that there is a large potential
for development and adoption of service cooperatives in Kyrgyzstan. Why are
farmers reluctant to join a cooperative? The main reason cited by the respondents
is that there is no cooperative in the vicinity that they can join (55%; see Figure
7.6). The second most frequently cited reason is that the respondents wish to
preserve their independence (42%), which probably reflects the ingrained
influence of Soviet-style production cooperatives. Loss of independence does not
apply to service cooperatives, and this reason is clearly a facet of the lack of clear
understanding of the differences between service and production cooperatives.
About 15% of respondents attribute their not joining a cooperative by
insufficiency of information about cooperatives, which strengthens our
contention that cooperative development requires a large-scale information
campaign to familiarize the rural population with the workings of cooperatives.
The universal issue of lack of trust in managers and other members is cited by
more than 10% of respondents. Finally, the danger of increased taxation for
cooperative members does not seem to be a problem: only 6% of respondents
116
7. Cooperative Development in Central Asia
raise this issue. This finding for potential members is consistent with the generally
relaxed attitude of cooperative members toward taxation (see above).
Cooperative Development Policy for Central Asia
World Practice and Central Asia
In developed countries, the basic cooperative principle of voluntary
membership has a broader meaning than simply the right of voluntary entry into
an existing cooperative. This principle essentially signifies also voluntary creation
of new cooperatives by groups of individuals with common interests and
objectives. Cooperatives are created “bottom-up”, driven by the voluntary
initiative of the users, and not “top-down”, according to formal cooperative
development programs advocated by state organs. The Western approach to
cooperative development is radically different from the approach observed in
Kyrgyzstan, Tajikistan, and other Central Asian countries, where the government
has a significant role in the “development of the cooperative movement” through
central dictates and formal strategy documents. Furthermore, cooperative
development strategies in Central Asia consistently advocate the creation of
production cooperative as a cure to the fragmentation of land holdings; they put
much less emphasis on the creation of service cooperatives as a means for
improving market access for small farmers. The world experience clearly shows
that cooperatives created “top-down” according to government programs seldom
survive, and only cooperatives created “bottom-up” based on user initiative in
rural areas have a chance of proving to be viable.
The Western “bottom-up” approach to the creation of cooperative effectively
limits the role of the government in this process. The government’s role is
essentially restricted to organizing a broad information campaign in rural areas
with the objective of acquainting the rural population with the advantages and
benefits of membership in a service cooperative. Such an information campaign
is necessary to neutralize the negative experience of the rural population with
Soviet-period cooperatives and to clearly delineate the differences of Western,
market-style service cooperatives from the production cooperatives in centrally
planned economies. The information campaign should be reinforced by the
development of information packages and materials intended for cooperative
members and managers, including personnel training and education programs. A
useful example of an information package for potential cooperators is a basic
start-up guide on agricultural cooperatives developed by Agriculture Canada
(processed).
117
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
The main responsibility for the organization of the information campaign,
personnel training, and preparation of information materials rests with the
government and appropriate public institutions (such as the national union of
agricultural cooperatives in each country). International donors should support the
government in this endeavor through their technical assistance and rural
development programs. The USDA cooperative service in the U.S. (USDA,
2013), the Canadian Co-operative Association, and similar undertakings in the
Netherlands (e.g., National Cooperative Council for Agriculture and Horticulture)
and other developed countries provide a good model for Central Asia.
Local government organs in rural areas should play a leading role in the
proposed information campaign and in dissemination of cooperative principles
among the population. These local organs should act at the village level as a
conduit for disseminating the basic information received from the center and for
motivating and encouraging the rural people through appropriate teaching and
training to create service cooperatives by their own local forces. They should also
stimulate exchange of information and experience between functioning
cooperatives in the region. Together with district and provincial authorities, they
can also contribute to the development of close relationships between local
cooperatives and processors, exploiting the natural symbiosis between these
organizations: cooperatives are suppliers of raw materials for processors, and the
sale of farm products by processors is in turn a guarantee of viability for
cooperatives. The envisaged role for local government organs requires allocation
of adequate budgets and preparation of local cadres qualified to deal with the
relevant tasks.
Cooperative development efforts envisage the following role for government
and international donors:
N Providing general policy guidance and policy advice regarding the
advantages and disadvantages of cooperatives, especially aiming to steer
the policy makers from the idea of re-establishing large collective farms in
the guise of production cooperatives
N Providing instruction materials and specific technical advice on
organization and functioning of cooperatives
N Re-drafting the law of cooperatives and the civil code based on a
combination of economic and legal considerations, with advice provided
by experts from both fields.
In addition to information and training, cooperative development may require
certain financial support, including startup funds for the purchase of machinery
118
7. Cooperative Development in Central Asia
and equipment, and also access to credit. The government and international
donors should develop appropriate programs, including partial participation in
machinery purchase through distribution of grants, leasing systems, and access to
discretionary credits for investments and working capital. All these programs
should be conditional on the ability of the cooperatives to generate own funds for
partial financing of their requirements. Government and donor programs must not
support deeply unprofitable or inactive cooperatives: grants and subsidies should
be made available to healthy, fundamentally viable cooperatives, which
ultimately will have sufficient own funds to finance their business activity, but
which require temporary assistance to achieve sustainability.
Strict targeting and monitoring of government financial support is essential.
Previous efforts to provide startup funds and discretionary credits for the
development of cooperatives in Kyrgyzstan during President Bakiev’s tenure
(2008) have failed: their only effect was to create an artificial increase in the
number of registered cooperatives willing to accept government money, without
any noticeable impact on agricultural production or rural wellbeing (Beyshenaly
and Namazova, 2012). They furthermore gave rise to corruption, as enterprising
farmers tried to secure government funds by less than legitimate means.
Government support funds are used in the West to help new cooperatives:
USDA (2013) gives a long list of support instruments available to qualifying
cooperatives. It is certainly possible to institute similar financial support
instruments in Central Asia, but this requires a radical change in the attitude of
government officials: distribution of support must be totally impartial and
objective. Support should go to cooperatives that have proved their ability to
function, cooperatives that are capable of providing matching funds of their own,
and cooperatives that can present credible business plans for development.
Government funds should not be granted from considerations of political or
personal favoritism. As long as conditions in government circles are not ripe for
such impartial and objective distribution of financial support, it is better to have
governments concentrate entirely on information, teaching, and training of
potential cooperators.
Promoting Cooperatives: Information Campaign and Legal Framework
for Cooperatives
Efforts to promote the development of service cooperatives naturally require
a proper legal framework. The national cooperative laws, as well as the civil
codes, should clearly and unambiguously define the three main types of
cooperatives that exist in market economies:
119
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
N Service cooperatives
N Consumer cooperatives (a variant of service cooperatives)
N Production cooperatives
The classification should be based primarily on functional characteristics
(what the different cooperatives do) and should disassociate itself from the
inherited Soviet-era classification (as reflected in the legacy of the so-called
consumer cooperation system). Legal experts working on cooperative legislation
issues in Central Asia should study the example of Kyrgyzstan’s Civil Code,
where the 1999 amendments reduced the discussion of cooperatives to the bare
legal minimum (a cooperative is a legal body that may be either a commercial or
a non-commercial organization) and left all the functional and organizational
details to the law of cooperatives.
In Central Asia, as in all CIS countries, the notion of cooperative automatically
raises the connotation of a “production cooperative” or the collective farm that
enjoyed such an unfavorable reputation during the Soviet era. The agricultural
reform strategies aim at establishing a different type of cooperatives – service
cooperatives, whose function is to provide farm services without in any way
depriving farmers of independence in all production activities. The
implementation of the strategy to encourage the development of service
cooperatives should therefore start with a broad information campaign in rural
areas, intended to explain the new notion of cooperative and to elaborate on the
advantages of becoming a member. This information campaign is basically the
responsibility of the government, but donors should naturally be invited to utilize
their experience with the establishment of cooperatives and help with funding.
Beyond initial training and learning, it is necessary to establish permanent
information services for members and managers. These information services
should focus on the following areas:
N
N
N
N
Market information
Relations with banks
Taxation
Legal issues
The USDA Cooperative Service in the U.S. (USDA, 2013) and similar
cooperative services in Canada, the Netherlands and other EU countries are good
models for the establishment of permanent cooperative services in Central Asia.
As part of information and training services, it is necessary to establish
mechanisms for systematic experience sharing among existing cooperatives. A
successful cooperative is an excellent example that should be followed by other
120
7. Cooperative Development in Central Asia
existing or potential cooperatives – but this example should be advertised through
experience sharing among others. The feeling from field visits in Tajikistan is that
today the existing cooperatives operate largely on their own, without joining their
forces with neighboring cooperatives (as is inherent in all cooperative systems in
the world). One example is a dried-apricot marketing cooperative in northern
Tajikistan (Sughd), which had to refuse a large export order because it did not
have enough capacity to deliver the required volume. Curiously, the cooperative
manager did not think it feasible to connect with one or two neighboring
cooperatives to make up the missing volume. Experience-sharing efforts should
also emphasize the advantages of joining forces among cooperatives.
In addition to information support and human-capital development, fledgling
cooperatives may require assistance with physical capital, including machinery,
equipment, and access to credit. Programs should be put in place to provide seed
money for the establishment of new cooperatives. In this context the Acted model
in Tajikistan appears particularly promising: cooperatives paid from their own
funds about one-third of the value of equipment provided by Acted, and the
remaining two-third were a grant from the donor. Credit facilities should be
established to help cooperatives finance their investment and working capital
needs at reasonable rates. Access to these facilities should be linked to the
cooperative’s ability to generate its own matching funds (as with the requirement
of contributing a share of machinery costs). All these efforts may require
cooperation between the government and the donors.
Development of a Multi-level Cooperative System for Denser Coverage
Although service cooperatives and private service providers are definitely
spreading in Central Asia, the coverage so far is very sparse. The example of
Tajikistan shows that a machinery cooperative or a private machinery service
provider may exist in one or two villages – with absolutely nothing in any of the
other villages in the administrative district. Central Asian countries need a much
denser network of service providers – cooperative or private – for its farmers and
rural population. A distinct advantage of cooperatives is that they are naturally
adapted to scaling up to a multi-level hierarchy: small, easily established, lowinvestment village-level cooperatives can form larger, more capital-intensive
second-level cooperatives that will scale up the first-level services to a cluster of
villages or the whole district. Take the example of a dairy cooperative system:
first-level cooperatives in villages simply need a refrigerated tank for milk
collection from households and farms; the second-level cooperative will have to
invest a refrigerated tanker for collecting milk from the village-level cooperatives
and transporting it to the central processing facility. In this way, the investment
121
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
costs are spread over the two-level system, without unduly overburdening any of
the cooperatives.
The cooperative system in market economies is usually made up of a
hierarchical structure consisting of several levels. The bottom level consists of the
“local” or primary cooperatives, i.e., cooperatives created by producers “bottomup” in villages. The next level are the “regional” cooperatives, which are created
by local cooperatives from considerations of economies of scale. Thus, processing
enterprises (a dairy, a flour mill, a fruit-and-vegetable canning factory) are not
needed in every village: one enterprise can serve processors from many villages
in the same region, accepting deliveries from lower-level local cooperatives.
Regional (or secondary) cooperatives in turn may associate in tertiary (nationallevel) cooperatives, whose role is to represent the interests of local and regional
cooperatives to the government (i.e., lobbying) and deal with general issues of
economic and organizational development (e.g., export promotion). These
national cooperatives are notionally similar to the cooperative “unions”
introduced in the CIS legislation on consumer cooperation, with one significant
difference: the entire multi-level cooperative system in market economies evolves
“bottom-up”, starting with local primary cooperatives created by producers in
villages, whereas “consumer unions” in CIS legislation are guided by Soviet
ideology and created “top-down” by state dictates.
References
Abele, S. and Frohberg, K., eds. (2003). Subsistence Agriculture in Central and
Eastern Europe: How to Break the Vicious Circle, Studies on the Agricultural
and Food Sector in Central and Eastern Europe, Vol. 22, IAMO, Halle.
Agriculture Canada (processed). Agricultural Co-operatives: A Startup Guide
www.agf.gov.bc.ca/busmgmt/bus_arrange/bus_arrang_pdf/coop1.pdf
Autrey C. and Hall, R. (2009). The Law of Cooperatives, American Bar
Association: Business Law Section, Chicago, IL.
Beyshenaly, N. and Namazova, B. (2012). Development of Agricultural
Cooperatives in the Kyrgyz Republic [in Russian], IAIR – Institute for
Analysis and Development Initiatives, Bishkek.
Cobia, D., ed. (1989). Cooperatives in Agriculture, Prentice Hall, Englewood
Cliffs, NJ.
EBRD (2012). Transition Report 2012: Integration Across Borders, European
Bank for Reconstruction and Development, London.
FAO/REU survey (2012). Survey of registered cooperatives and peasant farms
across Kyrgyzstan, implemented by El-Pikir, Bishkek.
122
7. Cooperative Development in Central Asia
ICA (2013). “Co-operative identity, values & principles,” International
Cooperative Alliance. http://ica.coop/en/what-co-op/co-operative-identityvalues-principles
Kyrgyzstan in Numbers (2012). Kyrgyzstan v Tsifrakh 2007-2001 [Russian],
Statistical yearbook, National Statistics Committee of Kyrgyzstan, Bishkek.
Kyrgyzstan Strategy (2012). Agro-Business Development Strategy for Kyrgyzstan
2013-2020 [in Russian], Ministry of Agriculture and Melioration of the
Republic of Kyrgyzstan, prepared with FAO Technical Assistance, Bishkek.
Lerman, Z. and Sedik, D. (2009). Agricultural Recovery and Individual Land
Tenure: Lessons from Central Asia, FAO/REU Policy Studies in Rural
Transition No. 2009-3, FAO Regional Office for Europe and Central Asia,
Rome-Budapest.
http://www.fao.org/fileadmin/user_upload/Europe/documents/Publications/P
olicy_Stdies/AgDevelopmentCA_en.pdf
Mather, J.W., K.C. DeVille, A.L. Gessner, and C.C. Adams (2004). Farm
Marketing, Supply and Service Cooperative Historical Statistics, USDA,
Cooperative Information Report 1, Washington, DC.
Plunkett Foundation, 1995. Review of 1994 Activities, Plunkett Foundation,
Oxford.
Tajikistan Strategy (2011). “Resolution of the International Conference on
Agrarian Reform in the Republic of Tajikistan, Dushanbe, 15 April 2011”,
prepared with technical assistance from FAO and the Donor Coordination
Council, Dushanbe.
USDA (2013). USDA Rural Development: Cooperatives, USDA Rural
Development web site.
http://www.rurdev.usda.gov/LP_CoopPrograms.html
Van Bekkum, O. and Van Dijk, G. (1997). Agricultural Co-operatives in the
European Union, Van Gorcum, Assen.
WOCAT (2010a). “Rotational grazing supported by additional water points”
http://qt.wocat.net/qt_summary.php?lang=english&qt_id=148
WOCAT (2010b). “Livestock committee at village level.”
http://qa.wocat.net/SummaryApproach.php?selected_id=269
123
8. Cooperative Development in Tajikistan
Zvi Lerman (2012)
The Role of Cooperatives as Service Providers
In developed market economies, farmers do not typically meet face to face
with the consumer in the market place and access to markets is achieved through
private intermediaries. Such private intermediaries are beginning to emerge in
Tajikistan in several forms. First and foremost, they include “integrators”, i.e.,
traders who visit the farms with their trucks and purchase farm products wholesale
for subsequent resale to retail customers. In a similar category, there are private
processors (e.g., dairies, meat packers, canning factories) that make arrangements
with farms to buy their products wholesale. On the supply side there are
organizations that rent machinery services to small farmers as needed and
“distributors” who purchase inputs wholesales and resell them to farmers in the
villages. Some distributors actually deliver supplies to the remote villages; others
establish small distribution “centers” for sale of feed or fertilizers in nearby
villages and thus minimize the travel time for farmers. Another important
category of private service providers are extension experts: former kolkhoz
specialists (agronomists, livestock scientists) now act as private consultants
providing paid advisory services to farmers.
All these private service providers fulfill a crucial function for rural
development: they free the farmers from the need to travel to the marketplace and
enable them to concentrate efficiently on their core business – agricultural
production. Government policies should be directed to encourage and facilitate
the operation of such intermediaries – by simplifying licensing arrangements,
implementing more flexible inspection procedures, cultivating a generally
friendly and helpful attitude among the local officials, and perhaps granting tax
credits on transactions with agricultural producers. The government should also
124
8. Cooperative Development in Tajikistan
consider establishing special credit facilities for expansion of business activities
of such rural intermediaries.
So far, however, such private rural intermediaries are relatively rare and do not
satisfy the needs of the huge number of smallholders – dehkan farms and
household plots in Tajikistan. Donors try to supplement the private service
providers by establishing networks of advisory centers and supporting the
creation of machinery services with grants and credits. These efforts, however,
have a very limited regional scope and are more in the nature of pilot efforts
without a clear strategy for national rollout (the GIZ/TAFF vigorously expanding
TAG network appears to be an exception to this rule). The most impressive
achievements have been recorded by donors in the area of establishment of legal
consulting centers (USAID, Helvetas): this is obviously a very important advisory
function, but unfortunately it has no direct impact on farmers’ access to market
services.
Even in market economies private service providers do not always reach every
remote rural location. In such cases, local farmers take the initiative and organize
self-help bodies – so-called service cooperatives – whose function is to allow
alternative access to markets without relying on private service intermediaries.
Decades of experience in all developed and developing market economies show
that farmers’ service cooperatives are the best mechanism to access market
services in areas where no private intermediaries operate or where private
intermediaries unfairly exploit farmers through monopolistic practices. While
farmers obviously need guidance on how to create cooperatives and new
cooperatives may require support through grants or subsidized credit from donors
or the government, the self-organizing nature of the system of cooperatives
ensures relatively easy rollout to remote rural locations. The concept of
cooperatives is discussed in more detail in the next section.
Creation of Cooperatives
Best-practice world experience suggests that farmers’ service cooperatives
provide the most effective way of improving the access of small farmers to market
services. Such cooperatives can cover the whole field-to-market value chain,
including joint purchase of farm inputs, attention to water distribution and
irrigation (through Waster User Associations), organization of machinery pools
for field work, establishment of sorting and packing facilities, transport of farm
products to markets and processing. They can also provide extension and market
information services, as well as veterinary and artificial insemination services, all
of which are essential for productivity improvement in both crop and livestock
production. Service cooperatives do not rule out private initiative: private trade
125
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
intermediaries, integrators, and service providers may co-exist with service
cooperatives and continue their currently developing operations. The main issue
here is the attitude of the government. It has to undergo a radical change from
neglect and disdain of household plots and small farmers to full recognition of the
huge role that small farms play in Tajikistan’s agriculture. Government officials
and decision makers have to acknowledge the contribution and importance of
small farms, abandon the traditional preference for large farms, and focus on
policies that ensure a supportive market environment for successful operation of
the small-farm sector – including policies to encourage creation of service
cooperatives. This change of attitude will require a comprehensive “re-education”
effort in all ministries and should probably be guided from the level of the central
government.
Western Classification of Cooperatives
International Cooperative Alliance (ICA) defines a cooperative as an
autonomous association of persons united voluntarily to meet their common
economic, social, and cultural needs and aspirations through a jointly owned
and democratically-controlled enterprise. The persons who voluntarily unite to
form a cooperative are usually referred to as members or member-owners, and
one of the key attributes of membership is active participation in the activity of
the cooperative (whether economic, business, or social). A cooperative is a legal
entity and in a certain sense it is an analogue of a shareholder corporation. There
are, however, some fundamental differences between a cooperative and a
corporation, as listed in Table 8.1. Perhaps the main difference concerns the
organization’s objective: while business corporations aim to maximize their
profit, cooperatives aim to maximize the benefits that members derive from their
participation in cooperative activities, including lower prices paid for inputs and
services and higher prices received for products.
The Western cooperative paradigm distinguishes between production
cooperatives, service cooperatives, and consumer cooperatives based on their
functional characteristics.
Production cooperatives are cooperatives in which members are jointly
engaged in the production process – irrespective of whether this is production of
manufactured goods, agricultural products, or services. These may include:
126
8. Cooperative Development in Tajikistan
Table 8.1. Comparative attributes of a cooperative and a shareholder corporation
Attribute
Owners
Owners’ objective
Organization’s objective
Voting rights
Income distribution rules
Cooperative
Members
Use of services provided by the
cooperative
Maximize members’ benefits
from working with the
cooperative
One member–one vote,
regardless of share contribution
Income distributed to members
in proportion to their
participation in the activity of
the cooperative
Corporation
Shareholders–investors
Earning income
Maximize corporate profits
Number of votes proportional
to number of shares (i.e., share
contribution)
Income distributed to
shareholders in proportion to
the number of shares held
N Manufacturing cooperatives are usually called employee owned or labor
managed firms. They used to be very popular in former Yugoslavia before
1989, but they are also observed in Western countries (Mondragon
Cooperative Corporation in Spain, Ha’Argaz Metal Works in Israel, and
others).
N In agricultural production cooperatives members jointly cultivate
cooperatively held agricultural resources, such as land or farm machinery,
producing a variety of farm products. Collective farms in the former Soviet
Union and kibbutzim in Israel are some examples of agricultural production
cooperatives.
N Cooperatives that produce services for sale to the general public (Avis
Rent-A-Car world-wide, United Airlines in the U.S., Egged Transportation
Cooperative in Israel, and others) are usually characterized as employee
owned or labor managed cooperatives: they are not called “service
cooperatives”, because this term is reserved for cooperatives that sell
services to members (the sales clientele criterion).
Production cooperatives sell their output to outsiders; yet the main function of
production cooperatives is to improve the wellbeing of their members by
providing jobs and working conditions that are superior to what would otherwise
be available in the market. Production cooperatives in the world are a tiny
minority among organizations that produce manufactured goods, agricultural
products, or services.
Service cooperatives, on the other hand, are the largest and most typical
category of cooperatives: these are cooperatives that provide services to their
127
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
14
members-producers, who carry out all production activities independently on
their own. In contrast to the minor role of production cooperatives in market
economies, service cooperatives in many countries account for a large share of
transactions in the relevant economic sector: for instance, agricultural marketing,
processing, and supply cooperatives (see below) are major players in markets for
farm products and farm inputs in North America, Western Europe, Japan, and
South-East Asia. Some members may actually be employed as workers in service
cooperatives, but most employees (and even most managers) are hired outsiders.
Service cooperatives use members’ share contributions to capital and borrowed
funds to finance purchase of goods and services from various market sources and
then resell these services to members at advantageous prices. Service cooperatives
exist in many different areas of economic activity.
Agricultural service cooperatives are usually subdivided into:
N Marketing cooperatives: cooperatives that collect and prepare members’
produce for sale, truck it to the market, and arrange for actual sale at prices
that are higher than what would be normally attained by the farmers
themselves;
N Processing cooperatives: cooperatives that buy members’ produce for
processing (often vertically integrated as the last downstream link in
marketing cooperatives);
N Input Supply cooperatives: cooperatives that exploit the benefits of size
to purchase inputs (fertilizers, chemicals, fuel, seeds, animal feed, etc.) or
specialized services (veterinary medicine, artificial insemination) at prices
and terms beneficial to members-producers;
N Machinery cooperatives (or machinery pools): pools (fleets) of farm
machinery jointly owned by groups of members in situations when it is too
expensive or too inefficient for each farmer to purchase machinery
independently;
N Extension and information management cooperatives: services to
upgrade the human capital of cooperative membership through training,
education, knowledge exchange, and management information
technologies provided by hired experts.
Examples of service cooperatives outside agriculture include:
14
For this reason, service cooperatives are sometimes called in English “producer’s cooperatives” (as
distinct from “production cooperatives”), or “farmer’s cooperatives” in agriculture. In Russian this term
would be translated as dhhi_jZlb\u ijhba\h^bl_e_c (kooperativy proizvoditelei), to distinguish it
from ijhba\h^kl\_ggu_ dhhi_jZlb\u (proizvodstvennye kooperativy), which is the accepted Russian
term for “production cooperatives”.
128
8. Cooperative Development in Tajikistan
N
N
N
N
N
N
N
N
N
N
rural electric power cooperatives,
renewable energy cooperatives,
rural telephone cooperatives,
healthcare cooperatives (the cooperative hires healthcare professionals
for the benefit of its members),
housing cooperatives
cooperative schools, nurseries, child-care facilities,
cooperative art galleries (a “marketing cooperative” for art “produced”
by member artists)
credit unions and cooperative banks
cooperative (mutual) insurance companies
auditing and accounting cooperatives (usually serving other
cooperatives, not individuals)
Consumer cooperatives are trading firms that sell consumer goods primarily
to their members at advantageous prices. They are basically a variety of supply
cooperatives (outside agriculture), but they are treated as a separate class because
of their numerical importance in the world. The largest segment of consumer
cooperatives is cooperative food stores and supermarkets (“grocery stores”), but
cooperative stores that sell clothes, housewares, appliances, and even cars to their
members – at advantageous prices – also fall in the category of consumer
cooperatives. In the West, consumer cooperatives, unlike other service
cooperatives, are probably most likely to deal with non-members (“third parties”)
on a regular basis: this is their strategy of achieving growth comparable with other
firms in the consumer services sector.
Classification of Cooperatives in Republic of Tajikistan Legislation
Clear unambiguous definition of different types of cooperatives – production,
service, and consumer – is essential to ensure acceptance of the concept of
cooperatives by the rural population. In market economies, the term “cooperative”
is automatically interpreted as a service cooperative. In Tajikistan and all CIS
countries, the term “cooperative” is automatically interpreted as a production
cooperative – the model of a former kolkhoz or collective farm. Having been
exposed for decades to the negative experience with such “production
cooperatives”, rural people may persist in their negative view of the whole
concept of cooperatives and reject any proposals to form cooperatives, even when
the intention is to create service cooperatives, not old-style production
cooperatives. The new legislative framework must acknowledge this
129
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
psychological barrier to cooperatives by introducing unambiguous definitions that
will prevent any possibility of misunderstanding or misinterpreting the strategic
intentions.
The draft law of cooperatives (Art. 2(1)) adopts the general definition of
cooperative as advocated by ICA (see above). This is a good start, but it is not
new, as the standard ICA definition has been always accepted since the Soviet
times. Beyond the universally accepted general definition, the new draft law,
following the 1999 Civil Code and the Soviet-era practice (e.g., the 1988 USSR
Law on Cooperation), classifies cooperatives into two distinct categories: (a)
production cooperatives (proizvodstvennye kooperativy) and (b) consumer
cooperatives (potrebitel’skie kooperativy). Unfortunately, the meaning that the
new draft law imparts to these two familiar-sounding terms is different from the
accepted meaning in Western usage. Furthermore, the term service cooperative is
not mentioned in the new draft law.
The draft law (Article 2) does not examine the functional features of the
different cooperatives and instead employs the formal classification attributes
shown in Table 8.2. Tajikistan’s legislation thus classifies cooperatives by their
profit-making attributes (“for profit” and “not-for-profit”) and by their sales
clientele (third parties or members), assuming in both cases that the respective
attributes are mutually exclusive and allow cooperatives to be classified into two
disjoint groups. Unfortunately, the two attributes are ambiguous and fuzzy for
cooperatives.
Table 8.2. Classification of cooperatives in Tajikistan’s legislation (Civil Code and draft Law of
Cooperatives)
Production cooperatives
Legal body
Commercial (“for profit”) organization
Sales to third parties only
Consumer cooperatives
Legal body
Non-commercial (“not-for-profit”) organization
Sales to members only (must transform into a
production cooperatives if sales primarily to
third parties)
The notion of profit in a cooperative is vague and unclear. Some international
authorities argue that all cooperatives are essentially not-for-profit, because their
goal is to maximize the members’ benefits by lowering the prices that they charge
and raising the prices that they pay. Profits are reduced to zero (or almost zero)
by this pricing policy. 15 Furthermore, there is no reason to assume a difference in
profit orientation between the two groups of production and consumer
15
Professor Muenkner noted in his materials for the Working Group on Cooperatives (SeptemberNovember 2011) that the Civil Code of Switzerland (OR Art. 828) specifically defines all cooperative
as not-for-profit.
130
8. Cooperative Development in Tajikistan
cooperatives: under the current Law on Consumer Cooperation consumer
cooperatives include retail and wholesale traders, providers of food and other
services, traders in consumer goods, etc., which in principle are not less profitmaking than other cooperatives. The attributes of “for-profit” (commercial) and
“not-for-profit” (non-commercial) are too ambiguous to be used as classification
attributes for cooperatives and should be removed from future legislative drafts.
Table 8.3. Functions of “production cooperative” as defined in the 1999 Civil Code of Tajikistan
(Art. 118) and their classification according to Western views of production, service, and
consumer cooperatives
Functions of “production cooperative”
according to Civil Code of Tajikistan
Production
Processing
Sale of products
Contract jobs, custom work
Trade
For and with producers
For and with consumers
Consumer goods and services
Other services
Services to producers
Services to consumers, general population
Western classification of respective
functions
Production cooperative
Service cooperative
Service cooperative
Service cooperative
Depends on specifics
Service cooperative
Consumer cooperative
Consumer cooperative
Depends on specifics
Service cooperative
Consumer cooperative
There are also difficulties with the sales clientele attribute (“production
cooperatives” selling mainly to third parties versus “consumer cooperatives”
selling mainly to members). Production cooperatives in the sense of cooperatives
in which members produce goods or services indeed sell their output to outsiders,
i.e., third parties. But this is the Western definition of production cooperative,
whereas in RT legislation (Civil Code, Article 118) production cooperatives also
engage in processing and sale of agricultural products, contract work (e.g.,
plowing or harvesting), trade, provision of services, and other activities that do
not involve production – activities that mainly target members – not third parties
– as the sales clientele. In Western nomenclature these cooperatives are called
service cooperatives, not production cooperatives (Table 8.3), and they are
definitely member-oriented in their sales, whereas the Civil Code puts them in the
category of production cooperatives that are supposed to sell to third parties only.
Finally, consumer cooperatives in the sense of food and other retail traders (as
defined in the West) indeed sell to members, but the proportion of non-member
sales in these cooperatives is steadily growing and according to RT legislation
eventually they will have to be transformed into production cooperatives –
although they do not engage in any production. These terminological
131
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
inconsistencies suggest that the feature of selling to third parties vs. selling to
members should also be dropped as a classification attribute for cooperatives.
The terms “production cooperative” and “consumer cooperative” as used in
Tajik legislation and as imported into the draft law of cooperatives are totally
inconsistent with the accepted Western terminology. The best option is to
introduce a consistent set of definitions of service, consumer, and production
cooperatives into Tajik legislation, based on functional features (including
appropriate amendments in the Civil Code). An alternative (“second best”)
approach is to omit the terms “production cooperative” and “consumer
cooperative” from the draft law and to treat cooperatives generally as noncommercial (“not-for-profit”) legal entities (the category of exceptional
cooperatives that do business mainly with non-members may be regarded as
commercial – “for profit” – legal entities). This, however, would involve explicit
recognition of the fact that cooperatives, although “non-commercial”, may have
income (accounting profit, ^hoh^ in Russian), which is ultimately distributed to
members as refunds for their participation in the activity of the cooperative.
The definitions of “production cooperative” and “consumer cooperative”
introduced in the draft Law of Cooperatives (see Table 8.6) are different not only
from the accepted Western definitions: they are also different from the definitions
used in the Civil Code. They will necessarily require amendment of the Civil
Code, without achieving the desired consistency with Western terminology and
market classification of cooperatives. Since the Civil Code will have to be
amended anyhow, it is strongly recommended to go the extra mile and prepare
amendments that will ensure terminological and conceptual consistency between
Western concepts and RT legislation.
Relations and Cash Flows Between Members and the
Cooperative
As an example, let us consider the relations between member-farmers and their
marketing service cooperative. Members produce independently on their plots
and deliver their products (milk, vegetables, honey) to the cooperative. The
members do not deal with retail sales to consumers: this function is entrusted to
the marketing cooperative. Receiving the products from its members, the
cooperative makes the first payment to members calculated on the basis of
estimated market or near-market prices. This first-wave payment to members is
an advance on account of products received: the final accounting is made at the
end of a quarter or a year, when the cooperative prepares its financial report. If
the financial report shows an accounting profit (“surplus” in Western cooperative
132
8. Cooperative Development in Tajikistan
terminology) after deducting the first-wave payments to the members and other
operating expenses incurred by the cooperative during the period, this essentially
indicates that the cooperative underpaid the members for the products delivered
during the reporting period. The surplus in principle should be distributed as a
second payment to the members in proportion to their deliveries to the
cooperative. In the end, the members may receive from the cooperative a price
higher than the market price that they would have received by selling
independently to the consumers. If the financial report shows an accounting loss
(i.e., “deficit” or negative “surplus”), this indicates that the cooperative overpaid
the members for the products delivered during the reporting period. The deficit is
also distributed to the members in proportion to their deliveries and is recorded
as a debit entry in the accounts of each member, to be covered from next year
sales or special funds maintained by the cooperative.
The same considerations exactly apply to the relations between members and
a supply cooperative, which purchases inputs (fertilizers, seeds, feed, etc.) from
suppliers at wholesale prices and re-sells them to members. Members initially pay
an advance to the cooperative to cover the estimated cost of the inputs (first-wave
payments). If the financial report at the end of the period shows positive “surplus”
(accounting profit), this means that the cooperative initially overcharged the
members for the inputs and the “surplus” is distributed to the members in
proportion to their purchases through the cooperative. This effectively lowers the
end price that members pay to the cooperative for inputs. If the financial report
shows a “deficit” (accounting loss), this means that the cooperative initially
undercharged the members for their purchases and the “deficit” is also allocated
to members in proportion to their purchases. A similar scheme is applied in other
service cooperatives, including cooperatives that provide machinery services to
members using a jointly owned pool of farm machines.
Taxation of Cooperatives
Cooperatives have the potential to increase the benefits to members by
exercising their market power and negotiating better prices and improved terms
both for sale of member products and for delivery of services. Yet tax distortions
may negate these positive effects and make membership in a cooperative an
ineffective proposition for farmers. Tax issues must be carefully addressed and
resolved if cooperatives are to have any chance of developing in Tajikistan.
Farmers join cooperatives with the objective of getting higher prices for their
products and paying lower prices for the inputs and services they buy. The
cooperative model achieves these objectives in two ways. First, a cooperative
represents many farmers in the market and thus enjoys greater market power than
133
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
each small farmer individually. The cooperative can negotiate lower prices for
wholesale bulk purchases of inputs and pressure traders into paying higher prices
for guaranteed deliveries of high-quality products. Second, the cooperative does
not aim to maximize its profits: in fact, it distributes all its profits to members in
proportion to their participation in cooperative activities, thus increasing
members’ revenues and reducing their costs compared to what they could achieve
by dealing with private profit-maximizing intermediaries. These two mechanisms
usually guarantee that cooperative members fare better than smallholder farmers
selling and buying independently. In principle this provides an incentive for
joining a cooperative, but there is a danger that taxation of cooperatives may
negate the membership benefits and discourage farmers from becoming members.
Today, household plots practically do not pay any tax on the sale of their farm
products, whereas dehkan farms pay the unified tax (based on the area of land
they control) and sometimes also the local retail sales tax. Everybody has to pay
the social tax, but this is not related to the farming activity and is not relevant for
the present discussion. When household plots and dehkan farms purchase inputs
or farm services, the prices they pay include VAT, but their tax status is such that
they cannot offset these VAT payments against their sales (smallholder farmers
usually do not charge VAT on sales). A cooperative, on the other hand, is a legal
body subject to different taxation rules. Specifically, three types of taxes may
negatively affect the benefits that members receive from their cooperative:
N VAT on transactions between the cooperative and its members
N Tax on accounting profits reported by the cooperative
N Retail sales tax
Exemption from Value Added Tax
Like dehkan farms themselves, the cooperative pays VAT to suppliers, but
then the cooperative has to charge VAT on its sales to members. As a result,
members may end up paying to the cooperative more than what they would have
paid independently to a supplier. The negative effects of VAT on the relations
between cooperatives and their members have been identified and discussed in
detail by the Working Group on the Law of Cooperatives and the Working Group
on Tax Reform. It has been agreed that all transactions with members – supply,
provision of services, contract work – should be exempt from VAT. An
appropriate amendment has to be added to the Tax Code in Art. 211, para. 2,
dealing with VAT exemptions to non-commercial organizations. Further to our
previous discussion of the classification of cooperatives, we should stress that, for
the exemption to apply to all cooperatives, this approach in effect requires
134
8. Cooperative Development in Tajikistan
recognizing all cooperatives (with minor exceptions) as non-commercial
organizations.
The recommended approach to VAT exemption of cooperative transactions
with members is an excellent example of the principle of “fiscal transparency”
applied to cooperatives in the Netherlands. In this country, with its outstanding
tradition of cooperation in agriculture and other sectors, transactions between
members and their cooperative are exempt from all taxes, not only VAT. This
gives recognition to the “not-for-profit” status of cooperatives and makes the
entire surplus available for distribution to members, without subjecting it to taxes
on profit.
Exemption of Distributions to Members from Tax
Cooperatives do not know in advance how much to pay to members for
product deliveries and how much to charge for input supplies and other services.
Financial settlements with members are handled in two ways: the first-wave
payments and charges are in the nature of an initial advance, and the final
settlement is made at the end of the period, when the financial statements have
been prepared. As a result, a cooperative usually presents a financial statement
that shows a positive surplus (accounting profit) or a deficit (accounting loss)
according to the following scheme:
Marketing cooperative
Revenues from sale of members’ products
Costs:
First-wave payments to members
Operating costs
Gross income (surplus/deficit)
Supply cooperative
Revenues: first-wave payments from members
Costs:
Paid to suppliers
Operating costs
Gross income (surplus/deficit)
Gross income (^hoh^ is the Russian term used in the draft law of cooperatives)
represents the surplus or deficit that is further allocated by three channels:
1) Allocation to the cooperative reserve fund or other capital funds
(“retention of earnings” in standard accounting terminology).
2) Distribution to members in proportion to their share contribution to the
cooperative capital (“dividends” in standard Western terminology; iZ_\u_
\uieZlu in the draft law of cooperatives).
3) Patronage refunds (dhhi_jZlb\gu_ \uieZlu) in proportion to their use of
cooperative services (i.e., basically in proportion to first-wave payments to
the members).
135
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
The sum of the three amounts distributed to members is equal to gross income.
The draft law of cooperatives suggests specific formulas and ceilings for the
calculations of the first two allocations (allocation to reserve and other funds;
share-based distributions). Therefore, these allocations should be calculated first
and the amount available for distribution as patronage refunds then determined as
the difference between gross income and the first two allocations:
Gross income:
Less allocation to reserve fund and other funds
Less distribution in proportion to share contribution (iZ_\u_ \uieZlu)
Difference available for distribution as patronage refunds (dhhi_jZlb\gu_ \uieZlu)
This is the logical sequence of calculations suggested by the relevant allocation
procedures in the draft law of cooperatives, although it does not quite fit the
accepted logic of Western accounting.
Conventional interpretation of the tax code will require the cooperative to pay
tax on the full gross income at applicable rates. Recognition of the special nature
of patronage refunds in cooperatives (as second-wave adjustment of initial overor under-payment to members) and the Dutch principle of “fiscal transparency”
suggest that this component of gross income should not be taxable. Furthermore,
the U.S. tax code recognizes “dividends” paid to members in agricultural
cooperatives (but not other cooperatives) as non-taxable at the cooperative level
(i.e., exempt from withholding taxes). If the Dutch and the U.S. tax principles are
adopted, the cooperative will be required to pay tax only on the share of gross
income retained in reserve fund and other capital funds. The amount retained in
the reserve fund and other capital funds will be shown net after deduction of the
appropriate taxes.
Recognizing the need to exempt patronage refunds (dhhi_jZlb\gu_
\uieZlu) from taxation, the draft Law of Cooperatives introduced an important
provision in Art. 39(3):
Payments to cooperative members in accordance
with their participation in cooperative activities
and payment of bonuses/honoraria to
cooperative managers are treated as expenses.
<uieZluqe_gZfdhhi_jZlb\Z\khhl\_lkl\bb
kbomqZklb_f\ohayckl\_gghc^_yl_evghklb
dhhi_jZlb\Zb\uieZlu\hagZ]jZ`^_gbc
^he`ghklgufebpZfdhhi_jZlb\Zhlghkylky
djZkoh^Zfdhhi_jZlb\Z
This, in addition to the proposed VAT amendment, is a very important step
toward establishing “fiscal transparency” for cooperatives in Tajikistan. To be
effective, however, this provision must be incorporated as an amendment in the
new Tax Code currently debated: expert opinions suggest that tax authorities
136
8. Cooperative Development in Tajikistan
refuse to follow provisions incorporated in specific laws unless they are also
reflected in the Tax Code and the courts are reluctant to rule against the tax
authorities in such instances. We furthermore recommend following the U.S.
practice and exempt share payments (iZ_\u_ \uieZlu) from taxation in
agricultural service cooperatives.
Exemption from Retail Sales Tax
The last taxation issue to consider concerns the retail sales tax. Again,
household plots are exempt from this tax by definition, whereas dehkan farms,
although legally liable, usually manage to avoid retail sales tax on their direct
sales to consumers in the market. Avoidance is of course impossible when dehkan
farms (or perhaps even household plots) sell to legal bodies, such as processors
or, in the future, marketing cooperatives. In principles, sales to a processor or a
marketing cooperative are not retail sales: these are wholesale transactions and
should be exempt from the retail sales tax. We are told, however, that tax
authorities enforce collection of retail sales tax also on wholesale transactions
with processors. This issue must be resolved, as payment of retail sales tax on
transactions with marketing cooperatives will place cooperative members
(whether dehkan farms or household plots) at a distinct disadvantage compared
to non-members. It will also be necessary to exempt cooperatives from any retail
sales tax on inputs delivered to members: this will have to be resolved in the spirit
of “fiscal transparency” as in the VAT exemption amendment.
Promoting cooperatives
In Tajikistan, as in all CIS countries, the notion of cooperative automatically
raises the connotation of a “production cooperative” or the collective farm that
enjoyed such unfavorable reputation during the Soviet era. The agricultural
reform strategy aims at establishing a different type of cooperatives – service
cooperatives, whose function is to provide farm services without in any way
depriving farmers of independence in all production activities. The
implementation of the strategy to encourage the development of service
cooperatives should therefore start with a broad information campaign in rural
areas, intended to explain the new notion of a cooperative and to elaborate on the
advantages of becoming a member. This information campaign is basically the
responsibility of the government, but donors should naturally be invited to utilize
their experience with the establishment of cooperatives and help with funding.
Several donor organizations work actively on the establishment of agricultural
service cooperatives in Tajikistan. These include Acted, OSCE, GIZ/TAFF, and
137
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
the Aga Khan Foundation. Unfortunately, donor experiences and monitoring
efforts have not been documented (with the possible exception of the GIZ/TAFF
TAG groups) and it is very difficult to analyze the actual achievements of these
efforts so far. It is even impossible to map the existing donor-established
cooperatives across Tajikistan to get a sense of spread and coverage. Visits to a
number of cooperatives in Khatlon, Sughd, and Rasht have shown that these
cooperatives are mainly fledgling efforts which are badly in need of training and
guidance. The general feeling is that cooperatives, once launched with donor
assistance, are left pretty much on their own, without followup assistance,
monitoring, and guidance. Cooperative managers naturally complain of
difficulties with purchasing machinery or raising credit, but beyond that it is clear
that they are untrained and without experiencing in managing a service
cooperative. All cooperatives have formal business plans, but managers need
training and guidance on how to implement the plans and how to work toward
achieving their strategic objectives. Training and learning programs are needed
for existing and potential cooperative managers (and also members).
Beyond initial training and learning, it is necessary to establish permanent
information services for members and managers. These information services
should focus on the following areas: (1) market information; (2) relations with
banks;(3) taxation; and (4) legal issues.
The USDA Cooperative Service in the U.S. and similar cooperative services
in the Netherlands are good models for the establishment of a permanent
cooperative service in Tajikistan.
As part of information and training services, it is necessary to establish
mechanisms for systematic experience sharing among existing cooperatives. A
successful cooperative is an excellent example that should be followed by other
existing or potential cooperatives – but this example should be advertised through
experience sharing among others. The feeling from our field visits is that today
the existing cooperatives operate pretty much on their own, without joining their
forces with neighboring cooperatives (as is inherent in all cooperative systems in
the world). One example is a dried-apricot marketing cooperative, which had to
refuse a large export order because it did not have enough capacity to deliver the
required volume. Curiously, the cooperative manager did not think it feasible to
connect with one or two neighboring cooperatives to make up the missing volume.
Experience-sharing efforts should also emphasize the advantages of joining forces
among cooperatives.
In addition to information support and human-capital development, fledgling
cooperatives may require assistance with physical capital, including machinery,
equipment, and access to credit. Programs should be put in place to provide seed
138
8. Cooperative Development in Tajikistan
money for the establishment of new cooperatives. In this context the Acted model
appears particularly promising: cooperatives paid from their own funds about
one-third of the value of equipment provided by Acted, and the remaining twothird were a grant from the donor. Credit facilities should be established to help
cooperatives finance their investment and working capital needs at reasonable
rates. Access to these facilities should be linked to the cooperative’s ability to
generate its own matching funds (as with the requirement of contributing a share
of machinery costs). All these efforts may require cooperation between the
government and the donors.
In conclusion, we should stress that although service cooperatives and private
service providers are definitely spreading in Tajikistan, the coverage so far is very
sparse. Machinery cooperative or a private machinery service provider may exist
in one or two jamoats – with absolutely nothing in any of the other jamoats in the
raion. Tajikistan needs a much denser network of service providers – cooperative
or private – for its farmers and rural population. A distinct advantage of
cooperatives is that they are naturally adapted to scaling up to a multi-level
hierarchy: small, easily established, low-investment jamoat-level cooperatives
can form larger, more capital-intensive second-level cooperatives that will scale
up the first-level services to a cluster of jamoats or the whole raion. Take the
example of a dairy cooperative system: first-level cooperatives in jamoats simple
need a refrigerated tank for milk collection from households and farms; the
second-level cooperative will have to invest a refrigerated tanker for collecting
milk from the jamoat-level cooperatives and transporting it to the central
processing facility. In this way, the investment costs are spread over the two-level
system, without unduly overburdening any of the cooperatives.
139
9. Cooperatives in Kyrgyzstan: Findings
from a Survey of Cooperatives and Users
Zvi Lerman and David Sedik (2012-2014)
Individualization of agriculture manifested in a sweeping shift from largescale collective farms to small family farms is the most striking change that the
transition has produced in agricultural sector of all former Soviet republics,
Kyrgyzstan included (Lerman 2008; Lerman and Sedik 2009). Small farms
everywhere in the world face essential constraints in their access to market
services (Abele and Frohberg 2003), and Kyrgyzstan is not an exception in this
regard. The main difficulties faced by smallholders include difficulties with
access to sales channels for farm products, difficulties with access to supply
channels for farm inputs, difficulties with purchase of farm machinery and
transportation equipment, and difficulties with access to agricultural extension
and market information.
Best-practice world experience suggests that farmers’ service cooperatives
provide the most effective way of improving the access of small farmers to market
services in areas where no private intermediaries operate or where private
intermediaries unfairly exploit farmers through monopolistic practices (Cobia
1989). Such cooperatives can cover the whole field-to-market value chain,
including joint purchase of farm inputs, attention to water distribution and
irrigation (through Water User Associations), organization of machinery pools for
field work, establishment of sorting and packing facilities, transport of farm
products to markets, processing, etc. They can also provide agricultural extension
and market information services, as well as veterinary and artificial insemination
services, all of which are essential for productivity improvement in both crop and
livestock production. Recognizing these positive roles of agricultural service
cooperatives for the rural population, the agricultural development strategies for
Kyrgyzstan emphasize the development of service cooperatives as one of the
priorities (Kyrgyzstan Strategy 2012).
140
9. Cooperatives in Kyrgyzstan: A Survey of Cooperatives and Users
There is significant disparity in the level of development of service
cooperatives between the formerly socialist countries – members in the
Commonwealth of Independent States (CIS) and established market economies
(see Chapter 6). A survey of agricultural cooperatives (FAO survey 2012) was
conducted in Kyrgyzstan – one of the CIS countries – in an attempt to describe
the functioning of these emergent organizational forms and explain, as far as
possible, the reasons for the sluggish development of agricultural cooperation in
this country.
Western Classification of Cooperatives
International Cooperative Alliance (ICA) defines a cooperative as an
autonomous association of persons united voluntarily to meet their common
economic, social, and cultural needs and aspirations through a jointly owned
and democratically controlled enterprise (ICA 2013). These principles are fully
acknowledged in Kyrgyzstan’s law of cooperatives (Law 2005). A cooperative is
a business-oriented legal entity and in a certain sense it is an analogue of a
shareholder corporation. However, business corporations aim to maximize their
profit, whereas cooperatives aim to maximize the benefits that members derive
from their participation in cooperative activities, including lower prices paid for
inputs and services and higher prices received for products (for a systematic
comparison of the attributes of cooperative and shareholder corporation see
Chapter 7).
The Western cooperative paradigm distinguishes between production
cooperatives and service cooperatives.
Production cooperatives are cooperatives in which members are jointly
engaged in the production process. In agricultural production cooperatives,
members jointly cultivate cooperatively held agricultural resources, such as land
or farm machinery, producing a variety of farm products. Collective farms in the
former Soviet Union and kibbutzim in Israel are examples of agricultural
production cooperatives. Members of production cooperatives do not engage in
independent farming on their land, with the possible exception of production on
the family’s household plot. Production cooperatives sell their output to outsiders;
yet the main function of production cooperatives is to improve the wellbeing of
their members by creating conditions for more efficient farming than what would
otherwise be feasible in individual farms.
Decision makers in CIS countries often argue that, by pooling members’
fragmented smallholdings into large farms, production cooperatives exploit
economies of scale and achieve higher efficiency. Yet economies of scale
generally do not exist in primary agriculture (Binswanger et al. 1995) and
141
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
agricultural production cooperatives are less efficient than individual and family
farms due to agency costs and free-riding effects (Allen and Lueck 2002). As a
result, production cooperatives in the world are a tiny minority among producers.
According to ICA data, production cooperatives account for less than 5% of all
cooperatives in the world.
Service cooperatives, on the other hand, are the largest and most typical
category of cooperatives in developed and developing countries: these are
cooperatives that provide services to their members-producers, who continue to
carry out all production activities independently on their own land. In contrast to
the minor role of production cooperatives in market economies, service
cooperatives in many countries account for a large share of transactions in the
relevant economic sector. For instance, agricultural marketing, processing, and
supply cooperatives are major players in markets for farm products and farm
inputs in North America, Western Europe, Japan, and South-East Asia. In the
U.S., agricultural cooperatives handle about 30% of farmers’ total farm marketing
volume and 28% of farmers’ total supply purchases (Mather et al., 2004). In the
European Union, the share of agricultural cooperatives is even larger: in countries
such as the Netherlands, Denmark, Ireland, and Sweden 70%-80% of farm
products are marketed through cooperatives and cooperatives account for 50%70% of all farm input purchases (Van Bekkum and Van Dijk, 1997).
Service cooperatives may employ some of their members as workers, but most
employees (and even most managers) are hired outsiders. Service cooperatives
use members’ share contributions to capital as well as borrowed funds to finance
purchase of goods and services from various market sources and then resell these
services to members at advantageous prices. Agricultural service cooperatives are
usually subdivided into marketing cooperatives, processing cooperatives, input
supply cooperatives, and farm machinery cooperatives.
Because of the prevalence of agricultural service cooperatives in the West, the
term “cooperative” in market economies is automatically interpreted as a service
cooperative. On the other hand, in Kyrgyzstan, as in all CIS countries, the term
“cooperative” is automatically understood as a production cooperative – the
model of a former kolkhoz or collective farm (Plunkett Foundation 1995).
Although the 2005 Kyrgyzstan Law of Cooperatives attempts to characterize the
differences between production and service cooperatives (Law 2005), there is
much confusion among the rural population and even among policy makers about
the actual nature of the two types of cooperatives: the Soviet-style production
cooperative to which rural people had been exposed for decades and the Westernstyle service cooperative advocated by international experts.
142
9. Cooperatives in Kyrgyzstan: A Survey of Cooperatives and Users
Data Sources on Agricultural Cooperatives in Kyrgyzstan
Some statistics on cooperatives in Kyrgyzstan have been available from two
sources: a special unit dealing with cooperative development in the Ministry of
Agricultural (largely without proper budgets or strategic guidance since 2008) and
National Statistics Committee (NSC) in Bishkek. MinAg reports the number of
registered cooperatives, which showed impressive growth over time, rising from
about 300 in 2004 to 1,300 in 2009 (Figure 9.1). 16 NSC, on the other hand, based
its reporting on the number of active (operating) cooperatives. The gap between
the two sources is dramatic (Figure 9.1): in 2011, MinAg reported more than
1,400 registered cooperatives, while according to NSC there were just 400 active
cooperatives in the country (Kyrgyzstan in Numbers 2012). It thus became
apparent that more than 70% of registered cooperatives in Kyrgyzstan were
inactive and existed only on paper, presumably with the intent of taking advantage
of future credit or taxation benefits that might materialize through government
policies (Beyshenaly and Namazova 2012).
Figure 9.1. Development of
cooperatives in Kyrgyzstan 20042011. Blue bars: registered
cooperatives from MinAg; red
bar: active cooperatives from
National Statistics Committee
(Kyrgyzstan in Numbers 2012).
The dominant majority of registered cooperatives in MinAg statistics are
production cooperatives, not service cooperatives. In 2009, 88% of the registered
cooperatives were classified as production cooperatives and only 12% were
service and processing cooperatives. Unfortunately, the existing statistics are
limited to the number of cooperatives: there are no data on land endowments,
sales volumes, or the size of membership. Special surveys have to be conducted
to elicit any functional information.
16
These numbers do not include credit unions, created mainly by the Raiffeisen Foundation in
Kyrgyzstan (some 300 in 2009).
143
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
One such survey of cooperatives in Kyrgyzstan was conducted in 2012 by a
local NGO with FAO funding (FAO/REU survey 2012). The sample frame for
the survey consisted of the 400 active cooperatives in the NSC database. The
original objective was to survey a sample of 100 cooperatives from the NSC list,
collecting information mainly on service cooperatives, with control information
on some production cooperatives. This objective could not be achieved, however,
because virtually no pure service cooperatives were found in the NSC database.
Among 400 active cooperatives in the NSC list, only 17 were identified as mixed
service/production cooperatives and three as trade/service cooperatives (these
were apparently closest to pure service cooperatives). All these 20 serviceoriented cooperatives were included in the survey sample, which additionally
included 37 entities identified as agricultural production cooperatives for a total
sample of 57 respondents. Given the composition of the NSC list, the cooperative
sample after the fact was neither random nor proportional. In addition to
cooperatives, the survey also covered 1,000 peasant farmers randomly selected
across the country, in proportion to the total number of peasant farms in each
oblast. These respondents provided insights on the relations between users and
cooperatives.
The sample structure is presented in Table 9.1. Different survey instruments
were developed for cooperatives and for peasant farms. The questionnaire for
cooperatives was administered to cooperative managers, whereas in peasant farms
the head of farm, the spouse, or the eldest son were interviewed.
Table 9.1. Sample of cooperatives and peasant farms in the 2012 FAO/REU survey in
Kyrgyzstan
Cooperatives
N
% of sample
Chui
15
26.3
Batken
--Issyk-Kul’
15
26.3
Jalal-Abad
6
10.5
Naryn
--Osh
15
26.3
Talas
6
10.5
Total
57
100.0
Source: FAO/REU survey (2012).
Oblast
N
180
18
89
285
101
247
80
1000
Peasant farms
% of sample
18.0
1.8
8.9
28.5
10.1
24.7
8.0
100.0
Functional Typology of Cooperatives Surveyed
Judging by their asset base and activity profile, 52 of the 57 cooperatives
surveyed were in fact production cooperatives. They all reported that they
cultivated some agricultural land – a clear distinguishing characteristic of a
144
9. Cooperatives in Kyrgyzstan: A Survey of Cooperatives and Users
production cooperative. The land in cooperatives was typically contributed by the
members, who were the source for 57% of total agricultural land in the sample;
another 27% of land in cooperatives was leased from the municipality or the state.
Virtually all cooperatives (51 out of 57) reported that they engaged in agricultural
production – predominantly crops, with mixed crop-livestock farming in 11 of the
51 cooperatives. In other words, practically all the cooperatives painstakingly
selected from official registers are actually production cooperatives, with not
more than 6 out of 57 cooperatives in the sample possibly qualifying as service
cooperatives (these are the six without primary production activities).
Service Activities of the Cooperatives
In addition to primary production, all cooperatives reported providing services
to both members and non-members. A production cooperative, in addition to
providing services to the joint production process where members work, also
supplies inputs to individual production in members’ private household plots and
sells some of its surplus inputs to non-members (for a higher price). Provision of
services to members and non-members is thus a typical feature of production
cooperatives and does not necessarily identify the cooperative as a service
cooperative.
Table 9.2. Services provided by cooperatives in the sample (percent of respondents, n=57)
Category of service
Sales of farm products
Storage
Packing
Processing
Fertilizer application
Machinery services
Transportation
Soil melioration
Information
Veterinary
Marketing services
Purchased inputs
Advisory
Construction
Average
Source: FAO/REU survey (2012).
For members
70
74
52
56
67
65
58
42
35
30
26
26
21
19
46
For non-members
19
23
21
18
12
28
33
21
19
9
12
5
11
5
17
Table 9.2 shows the percent of cooperatives in the sample that provide various
services to their members and non-members. The frequency of services to
members is substantially higher than the frequency of services to non-members
(46% compared with 17% averaged over 14 service categories). The main
145
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
services provided by more than 50% of cooperatives to members include
marketing of farm products (sales, storage, packing, and processing), fertilizer
application, mechanical field services, and transportation. Mechanical field
services and transportation are also the most common services provided to nonmembers, presumably because the local production cooperative is the main source
of farm machinery and vehicles in rural areas. This, combined with the relatively
high percentage of cooperatives providing access to storage facilities for nonmembers, is a clear illustration of the positive role that cooperatives play in overall
rural development.
Figure 9.2. Local service
sufficiency increases with the
percent of cooperatives that deliver
the service. Source: FAO/REU
survey (2012).
A direct indication of the positive role of cooperatives in rural life is provided
by the results shown in Figure 9.2. Here each dot represents one of 15 different
services, such as storage of farm products, machinery services, input purchases,
product sales, and so on. For each of these services the cooperative managers were
asked if their cooperative supplied the particular service and to what extent the
local demand for the service was satisfied in their opinion (fully satisfied, partially
satisfied, not satisfied). The vertical axis in Figure 9.2 plots the percentage of
cases when the demand for each service was fully satisfied; the horizontal axis is
the percentage of cases when the service was delivered by the coop. There is a
clear positive correlation between the frequency of cases when the local demand
for the service was fully satisfied and the frequency of cases when the particular
service was delivered by the coop. Service sufficiency thus clearly improves when
cooperatives step in as service providers.
Taxation and Financial Performance of Cooperatives
Two-thirds of cooperatives surveyed pay taxes, with land tax figuring as the
main tax (67% of respondents). The next in importance is the obligatory social
tax proportional to salaries paid, which is reported by 40% of the cooperatives.
146
9. Cooperatives in Kyrgyzstan: A Survey of Cooperatives and Users
Profit tax and VAT are reported by very few cooperatives (17% and 2%,
respectively). This can be regarded as evidence that tax authorities generally
respect the tax code provisions explicitly exempting cooperatives from these
taxes.
Taxes do not appear to be a major burden for cooperatives, as less than 10%
listed reduction of taxes among the demands for support from the government.
The main areas in which tax reductions were desired include purchase and leasing
of farm machinery (18% of respondents), construction services (17%), and sales
of farm products (16%).
Fully 80% of cooperatives surveyed do not receive any support from the
government and more than 40% state that they do not require any support.
Between 10% and 15% of the cooperatives expect to receive government support
in the form of subsidized prices, subsidized credit, and – importantly – training.
All this can be interpreted as signs of satisfactory financial performance.
Indeed, the majority of cooperatives (58%) report their financial situation as
stable or profitable and only the remaining 42% are loss-making.
Farmers’ Attitudes Toward Cooperation
Cooperation is expected to alleviate the difficulties that farmers face in their
farm operations, and farmers’ perception of difficulties therefore provides an
indication of the need for cooperation. Most farmers reported that they faced
difficulties due to shortage of inputs (fuel, fertilizer, chemicals, seeds) and
inadequate access to farm machinery, including lack of machinery leasing options
(Figure 3). Other difficulties, notably difficulties with product sales, access to
financial sources, and veterinary services, were highlighted with lower frequency,
but still by more than 20% of respondents among the farmers surveyed.
Difficulties that are routinely mentioned in various reports, such as high taxes,
lack of agricultural experience, shortage of labor, and insufficient land, were
reported by 10%-15% of farmers surveyed and can be regarded as relatively
minor. The pressing difficulties – those reported by more than 20% of respondents
in Figure 3 – are precisely the problem areas that cooperatives are designed to
overcome.
Two areas of pressing difficulties in Figure 9.3 deserve special mention.
Water shortages (reported by 40% of respondents) are an endemic problem in
Kyrgyzstan. The creation of Water User Associations was expected to alleviate
these difficulties, and although almost half the respondents are members in these
associations, this form of cooperation according to the survey has so far failed to
produce a significant effect on water shortages (30%-40% complain of water
shortages among both WAU members and non-members). Lack of state support
147
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
is a general macro-economic problem not necessarily within the competence of
cooperatives, but an association of farmers clearly has more lobbying power in
this respect than each individual farmer separately. Cooperatives may be in a
better position to secure state support for their members than individuals for
themselves.
Figure 9.3. Most pressing
difficulties faced by
farmers in their operations
(n=1000). Source:
FAO/REU survey (2012).
Informal cooperation is quite widespread among farmers in Kyrgyzstan. Fully
22% of farmers surveyed participate informally in some joint activity with other
nearby farmers (Figure 9.4). Joint use of farm machinery and transport facilities
is the most common, reported by 17% and 14% of respondents respectively. There
is obviously an acute need for these services that cannot be met by individual
means, as cooperatives also report provision of mechanical services and transport
with high frequency to both members and non-members (see Table 9.2). Joint
sales of farm products, joint purchase of inputs, and joint processing are also
reported, although with lower frequency of between 5% and 10% of respondents.
Figure 9.4. Informal cooperation
in various activities among family
farms. Source: FAO/REU survey
(2012).
148
9. Cooperatives in Kyrgyzstan: A Survey of Cooperatives and Users
It is noteworthy that 10% of peasant farmers surveyed report informal
cooperation in agricultural production outside a production cooperative. On the
other hand, formal, organized cooperation is very limited among peasant farmers
in Kyrgyzstan. Only 8% of the 1,000 farmers surveyed (78 respondents) are
members of an agricultural cooperative and fully 50% do not belong to any
association. Fully 46% are members in Water User Associations, which
presumably have established themselves as an effective institution for water
management – not without large-scale promotion campaigns by the government
and the World Bank.
Table 9.3. Participation of cooperative members in various services and activities (percent of
respondents)
Area of cooperation
All coop
members
(n=78)
Joint production
44
Machinery for field work
59
Product sales
54
Seed supply
55
Fertilizer/chemicals supply 54
Agricultural processing
33
Animal feed
37
Average satisfaction rating
Source: FAO/REU survey (2012).
Members who
participate in
joint
production
(n=34)
100
85
79
88
88
56
65
Members who
do not
participate in
joint production
(n=44)
0
39
34
30
27
16
16
Satisfaction
rating among
those using
the activity
59
61
64
67
62
58
55
61
Among the small number of farmers who are members of a formal cooperative
(78 respondents), over 50% enjoy four main services: farm machinery, sales of
farm products, supply of fertilizers, and quality seeds (Table 9.3). Furthermore,
56% of these farmers produce independently, i.e., they receive services from their
cooperative without engaging in joint agricultural production. The survey thus
distinguishes between two groups of cooperative members among peasant
farmers: 44% are in effect members of a production cooperative and receive
services as such; 56% are in effect members of a service cooperative, or rather a
service component of a production cooperative: they receive services from the
cooperative while continuing to produce independently. These farmers represent
the non-member contingent of service recipients shown in Table 9.2.
Members in service cooperatives (i.e., those who do not participate in joint
production) receive basically the same services as members in production
cooperatives. However, the frequency of these services for farmers who are only
members of the service cooperative (i.e., do not participate in joint production) is
lower than the frequency for those who participate in joint production, although
149
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
the relative ranking is the same. In other words, farm machinery, sales of farm
products, supply of fertilizers, and quality seeds are the most frequently enjoyed
services for both groups of cooperative members.
Cooperative members are generally satisfied with the services they receive
from the cooperative: on average, over 60% of members who actually use the
various services report that they are satisfied.
Figure 9.5. Reasons for not
becoming a cooperative
member (n=922). Source:
FAO/REU survey (2012).
The substantial gap between the frequency of formal and informal cooperation
(8% and 22% of farmers, respectively) clearly suggests that there is a large
potential for development and adoption of service cooperatives in Kyrgyzstan.
Why are farmers reluctant to join a cooperative? The main reason cited by the
respondents is that there is no cooperative in the vicinity that they can join (55%;
see Figure 9.5). The second most frequently cited reason is that the respondents
wish to preserve their independence (42%). This probably reflects the ingrained
influence of Soviet-style production cooperatives, which generally did not
observe the basic principles of voluntary participation and democratic
governance. Loss of independence does not apply to service cooperatives, and
this reason is clearly a facet of the lack of clear understanding of the differences
between service and production cooperatives. About 15% of respondents attribute
their not joining a cooperative to insufficiency of information about cooperatives,
which strongly suggests that cooperative development requires a large-scale
information campaign to familiarize the rural population with the working of
cooperatives. The universal issue of lack of trust in managers and other members
is cited by more than 10% of respondents. Finally, the danger of increased
taxation for cooperative members does not seem to be a problem: only 6% of
respondents raise this issue, probably because farmers simply do not understand
150
9. Cooperatives in Kyrgyzstan: A Survey of Cooperatives and Users
the taxation issues involved (see Chapters 6-7). This finding for potential
members is consistent with the generally relaxed attitude of cooperative managers
toward taxation (see above, Taxation and financial performance of cooperatives).
Effect of Cooperation on Farmers’ Wellbeing
Farmers’ wellbeing was explored in the survey through two qualitative
questions. One question, probed the absolute perceived level of wellbeing by
asking “how do you rate your family’s financial situation” and another question
probed the relative perceived wellbeing by asking “how would you assess your
family’s financial situation relative to other families in the village”.
The respondents classified their absolute perceived wellbeing into five
categories:
1 – family income is hardly sufficient to buy food,
2 – family income is sufficient for basic necessities
3 – family income is sufficient to buy also clothes and footwear
4 – the family can satisfy all its daily needs, but cannot purchase durables
5 – we do not experience any financial difficulties.
For purposes of statistical analysis, the five categories were aggregated into
two levels: categories 1, 2, 3 were jointly characterized as “basic level of
wellbeing” and categories 4, 5 were grouped into “comfortable level of
wellbeing”.
Survey results indicate that cooperation – either informal or formal – has a
strong positive effect on family wellbeing. Table 9.4 summarizes the findings.
Among farmers who cooperate informally with other farmers, fully 68% perceive
their wellbeing level as comfortable, compared with just 54% among those who
do not cooperate with other farmers. Similarly, among farmers who participate in
formal cooperation as members of an agricultural cooperative, 74% perceive their
wellbeing level as comfortable, compared with just 55% for those who are not
cooperative members. In both cases, the difference is statistically significant by
the chi-square test. When formal cooperation is further broken down into
membership in a production cooperative (engaging in joint production) and
membership in a service cooperative (receiving services without participation in
joint production), members in production cooperatives appear to have a slight
edge in perceived wellbeing compared to members in service cooperatives (Table
9.4), but the difference is not statistically significant.
151
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
Table 9.4. The effect of cooperation (informal and formal) on absolute perceived wellbeing
Formal cooperation
Member in
Coop
Member in
production
member
service
coop
(n=77)
coop
(n=33)
(n=44)
Basic
46*
32*
45^
26^
18
32
Comfortable 54*
68*
55^
74^
82
68
Total
100
100
100
100
100
100
*, ^ – differences between categories statistically significant by chi-square test (p = 0.10).
Wellbeing
level
Informal cooperation
No informal Informal
cooperation cooperation
(n=195)
(n=758)
Not coop
member
(n=876)
The question that probed the relative wellbeing level by asking “how would
you assess your family’s financial situation relative to other families in the
village” received the following answers:
1 – better than the rest,
2 – worse than the rest,
3 – same as the rest
Here again cooperation has a strong positive effect on relative wellbeing, but
this is observed only for formal cooperation through membership in a cooperative,
and no such effect is observed for informal cooperation. Furthermore, the
advantage of membership in production cooperatives compared to service
cooperatives is expressed more strongly than in the previous case, and the
difference between relative wellbeing of members in production cooperatives and
service cooperatives is now statistically significant. The findings are summarized
in Table 9.5.
Table 9.5. The effect of cooperation (informal and formal) on absolute perceived wellbeing
Relative
wellbeing
Informal cooperation
No informal
Informal
cooperation
cooperation
(n=766)
(n=196)
Not
cooperative
member
(n=888)
Formal cooperation
Member in
Cooperative
member
production
(n=74)
cooperative
(n=31)
Member in
service
cooperative
(n=43)
28^
Better than
the rest
22
21
20*
36*
Same as the
rest
65
65
66*
54*
48^
52^
Worse than
13
15
14*
9*
the rest
Total
100
100
100
100
100
*, ^ – differences between categories statistically significant by chi-square test (p = 0.10).
152
72^
100
9. Cooperatives in Kyrgyzstan: A Survey of Cooperatives and Users
Conclusions
Most registered agricultural cooperatives in Kyrgyzstan appear to be
production cooperatives – successors of former collective farms. They mainly
engage in primary production on collectively held land, and provide services to
non-members merely as a byproduct of their joint production activities. The rural
population is not clear on the fundamental differences between production and
service cooperatives and the benefits that can be derived from membership in a
proper service cooperative. Government strategy documents do not distinguish
with sufficient clarity between the two types of cooperatives, which only
exacerbates the confusion. This situation suggests the need for a broad public
awareness campaign to familiarize the rural population with the working and
benefits of service cooperatives, thus encouraging bottom-up development of
service cooperatives.
Cooperatives in Kyrgyzstan are few in number and widely scattered. More
than half the respondents in the sample of peasant farmers in the FAO/REU 2012
survey report that there is no cooperative in the vicinity that they can join. Other
reasons for not joining a cooperative, e.g., fear of losing independence and lack
of information about cooperatives, manifest lack of clear understanding of the
differences between service and production cooperatives.
Formal cooperation as manifested in membership in cooperatives is very
limited among the farmers surveyed. Informal cooperation is much more
widespread, and the substantial gap between the frequency of formal and informal
cooperation (8% and 22% of farmers surveyed, respectively) clearly suggests that
there is a large potential for development and adoption of service cooperatives in
Kyrgyzstan. Furthermore, most farmers reported that they faced difficulties due
to shortage of inputs (fuel, fertilizer, chemicals, seeds) and inadequate access to
farm machinery, including lack of machinery leasing options. Other difficulties,
notably difficulties with product sales, access to financial sources, and veterinary
services, were highlighted with lower frequency, but still by more than 20% of
respondents. These pressing difficulties reported by more than 20% of
respondents are precisely the problem areas that cooperatives are designed to
overcome.
Difficulties that are routinely mentioned in various reports, such as high taxes,
lack of agricultural experience, shortage of labor, and insufficient land were
reported by 10%-15% of respondents and can be regarded as relatively minor.
Taxes are not perceived as a major issue by either cooperative managers or
farmers. Tax code provisions exempting cooperatives from profit tax and VAT
are generally respected.
153
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
Government support plays a minor role in agriculture: most cooperative
managers and farmers surveyed report that they do not receive any support. This,
however, has not led to a major outcry with demands for more government
support in the survey. This probably suggests that information and training are
more important than direct financial support for cooperative development.
The survey clearly shows that cooperatives play a positive role in rural life.
Thus, sufficiency of services in any given area improves when cooperatives step
in to provide the services and farmers’ perceived wellbeing is higher for
cooperative members than for outsiders.
References
Abele, S. and Frohberg, K., eds. (2003). Subsistence Agriculture in Central and
Eastern Europe: How to Break the Vicious Circle, Studies on the Agricultural
and Food Sector in Central and Eastern Europe, Vol. 22, IAMO, Halle.
Allen, D. and Lueck, D. (2002). The Nature of the Farm: Contracts, Risk, and
Organization in Agriculture, MIT Press, Cambridge, MA.
Beyshenaly, N. and Namazova, B. (2012). Development of Agricultural
Cooperatives in the Kyrgyz Republic [in Russian], IAIR – Institute for
Analysis and Development Initiatives, Bishkek.
Binswanger, H., Deininger, K., and Feder, G. (1995). “Power, Distortion, Revolt
and Reform in Agricultural Land Relations,” in: J. Behrman and T. N.
Srinivasan, eds., Handbook of Development Economics, vol. III, chapter 42,
2659-2772, Elsevier Science.
Cobia, D., ed. (1989). Cooperatives in Agriculture, Prentice Hall, Englewood
Cliffs, NJ.
FAO/REU survey (2012). Survey of registered cooperatives and peasant farms
across Kyrgyzstan, implemented by El-Pikir, Bishkek.
ICA (2013). “Co-operative identity, values & principles,” International
Cooperative Alliance. http://ica.coop/en/what-co-op/co-operative-identityvalues-principles
Kyrgyzstan Strategy (2012). Agro-Business Development Strategy for Kyrgyzstan
2013-2020 [in Russian], Ministry of Agriculture and Melioration of the
Republic of Kyrgyzstan, prepared with FAO Technical Assistance, Bishkek.
Kyrgyzstan in Numbers (2012). Kyrgyzstan v Tsifrakh 2007-2001 [Russian],
National Statistics Committee, Bishkek.
Kyrgyzstan Strategy (2012). Agro-Business Development Strategy for Kyrgyzstan
2013-2020 [in Russian], Ministry of Agriculture and Melioration of the
Republic of Kyrgyzstan, prepared with FAO Technical Assistance, Bishkek.
154
9. Cooperatives in Kyrgyzstan: A Survey of Cooperatives and Users
Law (2005). Law of the Kyrgyz Republic on Cooperatives, No. 37, Bishkek.
Lerman, Z. (2008). “Agricultural Recovery in the Former Soviet Union: An
Overview of 15 Years of Land Reform and Farm Restructuring,” PostCommunist Economies, Vol. 20, No. 4, pp. 391-412.
Lerman, Z. and Sedik, D. (2009). “Agricultural Recovery and Individual Land
Tenure: Lessons from Central Asia,” FAO/REU Policy Study No. 2009-3.
Mather, J.W., DeVille, K.C., Gessner, A.L., and Adams, C.C. (2004). Farm
Marketing, Supply and Service Cooperative Historical Statistics, USDA,
Cooperative Information Report 1, Washington, DC.
Plunkett Foundation (1995). Review of 1994 Activities, Plunkett Foundation,
Oxford, UK.
Van Bekkum, O. and Van Dijk, G. (1997). Agricultural Co-operatives in the
European Union, Van Gorcum, Assen.
155
10.Agricultural Cooperative Development
in Kazakhstan and Ukraine
David Sedik and Zvi Lerman (2013)
The purpose of this chapter is to review the evidence on agricultural service
cooperatives in two countries of the Commonwealth of Independent States
(CIS)—Ukraine and Kazakhstan—and to consider the reasons for their lack of
development compared to the countries of North America and Western Europe.
Only one farm in 246 in Ukraine and one in 31 in Hungary are members of a
service cooperative, while in the US and France each farmer is a member of a
service cooperative and in Italy every other farmer is a member (Table 10.1).
There are also far more farms per cooperative in Kazakhstan, Ukraine and
Hungary, than in the countries of Western Europe and the US. Whereas there is
only one cooperative for every 6,000 farms in Ukraine and Kazakhstan, and for
every 10,000 farms in Hungary, in France there exists one service cooperative for
every 178 farms. This statistic also indicates that the development of service
cooperatives in Eastern Europe and the CIS is far behind that in the US and
Western Europe.
A number of reasons are often cited for the dearth of self-help organizations
in ex-socialist countries (Akimbekova, 2010; Korinets, 2013; Tomich, 2013):
1) the agricultural policy environment may not encourage, and may even
discourage, the formation of self-help groups such as service cooperatives;
2) joining a cooperative may increase the tax burden of farmers;
3) small farmers have limited startup capital, while working service
cooperatives usually require substantial investment in order to justify
themselves financially;
4) there are a limited number of leaders capable of professionally managing
cooperatives in the countryside;
156
10. Agricultural Cooperative Development in Kazakhstan and Ukraine
5) there is a noticeable and understandable distrust in cooperation among the
rural population (which is predominantly old) because of their previous
experience with the socialist version of cooperation;
6) rural people have limited understanding of principles and direct benefits
of cooperation, which is necessary for counteracting the attitude of
distrust.
Table 10.1. The Development of Agricultural Service Cooperatives in Selected Countries
Country
Ukraine
Kazakhstan
US
France
Hungary
Italy
Year
2010
2010
2010
2010
2007
2008
Number of
agricultural
service
cooperatives
801
300
2,310
2,900
58
5,800
Number of
cooperative
members
Number of
farms
21,521 5,300,000
N.A. 1,850,000*
2,200,000 2,200,000
500,000
516,100
20,177
626,300
900,000 1,679,400
Ratio:
Ratio:
Farms per
member
Farms per
cooperative
246
N.A.
1
1
31
2
6,617
6,167
952
178
10,798
290
Sources: US: USDA, 2012, USDA-NAS, 2013; Ukraine: Korinets, 2013: 36, 38, State Statistics Service
of Ukraine, 2011: 10, State Statistics Service of Ukraine, 2012: 51; France: Eurostat, 2013, Filippi,
2012: 14; Hungary: Szabo, 2012: 23; Italy: Bono, 2012: 19; Kazakhstan: number of service cooperatives
from Conception (2012), number of farms see next note.
*The sum of peasant farms (170,000) plus an estimate of the number of household plots (1,680,000,
assuming that each rural household has a household plot). Data for peasant farms from Agriculture in
Kazakhstan 2007-2011 (Statistical Agency, Astana, 2012); data for rural households from 2009
Population Census of Kazakhstan: Households, vol. 1, p. 4 (Statistical Agency, Astana, 2011). Similar
numbers emerge from the 2006-2007 Agricultural Census (Astana, 2008).
In this chapter we show that there are potentially good economic reasons for
farmers to cooperate in Kazakhstan and Ukraine. However, the need to cooperate
is not enough. Support for the cooperative idea is low in the CIS countries based
on past experience with the Soviet cooperative model, and due to the lack of
information on and experience with alternatives.17 Overcoming the legacy of the
17
Academic researchers have investigated the issue of distrust in cooperation in post-socialist economies
more formally. Gijselinckx and Bussels (2012) investigated two potential reasons for the lack of
cooperation in the ex-socialist countries of Europe, finding high correlations between indicators of
“social capital” and member intensity of agricultural cooperatives (percentage of farmers of a country
that are cooperative members), but no discernible correlations between indicators of “general deeprooted cultural values” and member intensity. “Social capital” is defined as “the trinity of ‘networks,
norms of reciprocity and trust’” (Gijselinckx and Bussels, 2012). Indicators of “general deep-rooted
cultural values” were based on research by Hofstede, Hofstede and Minkov (2010). Lissowska (2013)
came to similar conclusions in her analysis of social attitudes towards cooperation in European countries
(based on the European Social Survey), where she found that the preference for cooperation in transition
countries (Central and Eastern Europe, Russia and Ukraine) is close to that of the other (Western)
European countries. However, transition countries differ in that people have less faith in the cooperative
model based on their past experience with the socialist version of cooperation, which usurped and
157
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
past requires a “reimagining” of the cooperative model on the part of farmers and
policymakers. Farmers need to experience the liberal-democratic model of
cooperation, while policymakers need to recognize that the role of the state in
organizing service cooperatives is minimal. Public policy should provide a
supportive enabling environment for service cooperatives while simultaneously
ensuring that both the government and farmers are aware of the change from
“cooperation” imposed from above to the Western liberal model of self-help style,
grass-roots cooperation. This has been a difficult task for CIS governments.
To understand how governments in Ukraine and Kazakhstan have dealt with
this task we consider two aspects of the enabling environment. First, we consider
policies—what do state policies illustrate about the attitude of the government
toward cooperatives in Ukraine and Kazakhstan? Second, we analyze legislation
to gauge the extent of state support for agricultural service cooperatives and how
it could be improved.
The Need for Agricultural Service Cooperatives in Kazakhstan
and Ukraine
Agriculture in the CIS countries is based primarily on smallholders – peasant
farms and household plots. The smallholder farm sector produced 70 percent of
Gross Agricultural Output (GAO) in Kazakhstan and 55 percent in Ukraine in
2011 (Statistical Agency of Kazakhstan, 2012; State Statistical Service of
Ukraine, 2012). Small farms everywhere in the world face constraints in their
access to market services, and the CIS countries are not an exception in this
regard. The main difficulties faced by smallholders include:
difficulties with access to sales channels for market products,
difficulties with access to supply channels for farm inputs,
difficulties with purchase of farm machinery and transportation equipment,
difficulties with access to information and advisory services, which are
essential for raising productivity and efficiency,
N limited access to credit resources, which are required to finance short-term
working capital and long-term investment needs.
N
N
N
N
These difficulties combine to create what is sometimes referred to as “the curse
of smallness”, a trap that prevents smallholders from fully exploiting their
distorted the liberal democratic model of cooperation that pervaded Europe (including Russia and
Ukraine) before socialism.
158
10. Agricultural Cooperative Development in Kazakhstan and Ukraine
inherent productivity advantages due to barriers in access to markets (Abele and
Frohberg, 2003).
In developed market economies private intermediaries often compete to buy
and sell agricultural commodities from farmers, or farmers themselves market
their own production. In the CIS countries such private rural intermediaries often
act as monopsonistic buyers in the region they operate. In such cases in market
economies farmers organize self-help bodies – so-called service cooperatives,
whose function is to correct market failure by allowing alternative access to
markets without relying on private service intermediaries. Such cooperatives can
cover the whole field-to-market value chain, including joint purchase of farm
inputs, attention to water distribution and irrigation (through Water User
Associations), organization of machinery pools for field work, establishment of
sorting and packing facilities, transport of farm products to markets, processing,
etc. They can also provide agricultural extension and market information services,
as well as veterinary and artificial insemination services, all of which are essential
for productivity improvement in both crop and livestock production. What service
cooperatives do not do is engage in primary agricultural production as a collective
of farmers.
In dealing with a service cooperative, the market effectively deals with a
relatively large entity that combines many smallholders into a single negotiating
position. Access difficulties imposed by smallness are thus automatically lifted.
Service cooperatives overcome the “curse of smallness” by conducting market
transactions for a large number of small farmers simultaneously.
Ukraine and Kazakhstan Policies on Agricultural Service
Cooperatives
Ukraine
The government of Ukraine has consistently declared support for agricultural
service cooperatives over the past ten years, while implementation of this support
has been far less consistent. More importantly, government programs, when they
did provide support, focused on subsidies, rather than on making information for
farmers widely available on the financial benefits of cooperatives and how to form
them. Grass-roots education programs and publications on the benefits of
cooperatives, including legal assistance for forming new cooperatives, has not
been a major part of government policy in Ukraine. The main support of the
government to agriculture has been the special agricultural VAT tax regime,
which strongly skews the beneficiaries by distributing the largest share of
159
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
subsidies to a relatively small number of large producers rather than tens of
thousands of smallholders.
The Presidential Decree On Means for Development of the Cooperative
Movement and Strengthening of its Role in the Market Reform of the Ukrainian
Economy (President of Ukraine, 2000) foresaw the organization of a credit line,
local budget resources for the development of service cooperatives and a fund for
the support of service cooperatives in procuring bank loans, including loan
guarantees. As of 2009 no funding for cooperatives was made available from the
central government (Korinets, 2013:56). The Program for the Development of
Agricultural Service Cooperatives for 2003-2004 (Ministry of Agrarian Policy,
2002) also promised support for cooperatives, though the means for this support
would come from “domestic and foreign investors, share contributions of
cooperative members and funds from local budgets. Ukrainian Law On the Main
Pillars of State Agrarian Policy to 2015 (Parliament of Ukraine, 2005) noted that
one of the main priorities of the state agrarian policy was “state support for the
development of competitive agricultural production on the basis of cooperation
and integration.” The State Special Program for the Development of the
Ukrainian Village to 2015 (Ministry of Agrarian Policy and Food, 2007) also
envisioned state support for agricultural service cooperatives with no apparent
budget resources made available (Korinets, 2013:57).
The first substantial funds made available from the central government for the
development of agricultural service cooperatives were in accordance with the
Cabinet of Ministers Decree no. 557 (3 June 2009), The State Special Economic
Program for the Support of the Development of Agricultural Service Cooperatives
to 2015 (Cabinet of Ministers of Ukraine, 2009). This decree planned for the
creation of an additional 2,500 cooperatives through support for enabling
legislation, funding infrastructure and removing obstacles for cooperative
development. In fact, the program made funds available only for purchase of
agricultural machinery for cooperatives (Korinets, 2013: 56).
In 2011 the Ukrainian government again declared its support for agricultural
cooperatives. In November 2011 President Yanukovich noted that “along with
efforts to strengthen private farmers and large scale private producers, it is also
necessary to do everything possible to develop the new cooperative movement in
the countryside. They should become an important foundation of the structural
reform of agriculture” (Korinets, 2013: 57). Support was continued into 2012 with
the new version of the law On Agricultural Cooperation (Parliament of Ukraine,
1997), signed into law by the President on 19 January 2013. According to this
legislation, 5 million UAH was to be made available for purchase of agricultural
machinery by cooperatives. Finally, in February 2013 Minister of Agrarian Policy
160
10. Agricultural Cooperative Development in Kazakhstan and Ukraine
Prisiazhniuk noted that “we are planning the development . . . of rural areas and
the formation of a rural middle class. And the main mechanism we are proposing
is agricultural cooperation, which will help increase the competitiveness of small
producers and form the basis for the renaissance of the Ukrainian village” (RBKUkraine, 2013).
Kazakhstan
The latest official policy on cooperatives in Kazakhstan is concisely
summarized in Kazakhstan-2050 (2012), the strategy for the development of
Kazakhstan to 2050 presented by the President on the eve of Independence Day
in December 2012:
It is important to raise the overall level of business culture and to
stimulate entrepreneurship… To this end we must encourage the
attempts of small and medium business to establish associations and
cooperatives and create an appropriate system of support and
incentives for the entrepreneurs.
A more detailed exposition of government policies for agricultural service
cooperatives can be found in Conception (2012). This basic document outlines
three main policy directions:
N improvement of legislative base;
N financial support (loans at subsidized interest rates, government subsidies
for inputs and investments, tax breaks);
N provision of information and training.
Attempts to improve the legislative base continue, mainly through the efforts
of the agricultural lobby (see, e.g., Draft amendment, 2010), but very little seems
to be happening with provision of information about cooperatives and training for
producers and potential managers. As in Ukraine, the main policy focus is on
financial support, including credit and subsidies. Two models of government
support are observed in Kazakhstan, both relying on state-controlled companies:
N “Agricultural Credit Corporation”, established in 2001, is an arm of the
Ministry of Agriculture that grants 5-7 year loans at 5% per annum as seed
money for the creation of rural service cooperatives (not including Water
User Associations);
N “Social-Entrepreneurial Corporations” (Natsional’naya kompaniya
“Sotsial’no-predprinimatel’skaya korporatsiya”) forming a regional
161
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
network of state–private partnerships entrusted – among other activities –
with the establishment of service–procurement centers (servisnozagotovitel’nye tsentry – SZTs) that provide agricultural services to rural
service cooperatives and agricultural producers; participation of service
cooperatives in equity capital is a necessary condition for the creation of
service–procurement centers.
Up to April 2009, the Agricultural Credit Corporation had distributed 8 billion
tenge (US$50-65 million depending on exchange rates) in subsidized agricultural
loans (Conception, 2012; Akimbekov, 2010). It is argued that the availability of
low interest-rate credits and other subsidies intended specifically for service
cooperatives encourages the creation of “false cooperatives”, i.e., cooperatives
that are established only for the purpose of gaining access to subsidized credits
and inputs, without any regard for true cooperative principles. This trend may be
responsible for the large discrepancies in cooperative statistics from different
sources and for the large gaps between the number of registered and active
cooperatives. As to service–procurement centers, in reality they duplicate the
basic functions of service cooperatives without any attempt to adhere to
cooperative principles. They appear to be a carry-over from the Soviet model of
enlargement that characterized the agro-industrial complex, and their goal is
apparently profit maximization, as is evident from the high prices that they charge
for the services to cooperatives and farmers (Conception, 2012).
Enabling Environment: Classification and Characteristics of
Cooperatives
The International Cooperative Alliance (ICA) defines a cooperative as an
autonomous association of persons united voluntarily to meet their common
economic, social, and cultural needs and aspirations through a jointly owned and
democratically-controlled enterprise (ICA, 2013). The persons who voluntarily
unite to form a cooperative are usually referred to as members or member-owners,
and one of the key attributes of membership is active participation in the activity
of the cooperative (whether economic, business, or social). A cooperative is a
legal entity and in a certain sense it is an analogue of a shareholder corporation.
There are, however, some fundamental differences between a cooperative and a
corporation, as listed in Table 10.2.
Perhaps the main difference concerns the organization’s objective: while
business corporations aim to maximize their profit, cooperatives aim to maximize
the benefits that members derive from their participation in cooperative activities,
162
10. Agricultural Cooperative Development in Kazakhstan and Ukraine
including lower prices paid for inputs and services and higher prices received for
products (Cobia, 1989).
Table 10.2. Comparative attributes of a cooperative and a shareholder corporation
Attribute
Owners
Owners’ objective
Organization’s objective
Voting rights
Income distribution rules
Cooperative
Members
Use of services provided by the
cooperative
Maximize members’ benefits
from working with the
cooperative
One member–one vote,
regardless of share contribution
Income distributed to members
in proportion to their
participation in the activity of
the cooperative
Corporation
Shareholders–investors
Earning income
Maximize corporate profits
Number of votes proportional
to number of shares (i.e., share
contribution)
Income distributed to
shareholders in proportion to
the number of shares held
The Western cooperative paradigm distinguishes between production
cooperatives, service cooperatives, and consumer cooperatives based on their
functional characteristics.
Production cooperatives are cooperatives in which members are jointly
engaged in the production process – irrespective of whether this is production of
manufactured goods, agricultural commodities, or services. Production
cooperatives are based on member labor and they sell their output to outsiders;
yet the main function of production cooperatives is to improve the wellbeing of
their members by providing jobs and working conditions that are superior to what
would otherwise be available in the market. In agriculture it is often argued that,
by allowing members to pool their fragmented smallholdings into large farms,
production cooperatives exploit economies of scale and achieve higher efficiency.
Yet many researchers have in fact shown that agricultural production cooperatives
are substantially less efficient than individual and family farms. As a result,
production cooperatives in the world are a tiny minority among organizations that
produce manufactured goods, agricultural products, or services. According to
ICA data, production cooperatives account for less than 5% of all cooperatives in
the world
Service cooperatives, on the other hand, are the largest and most typical
category of cooperatives: these are cooperatives that provide services to their
members-producers, who continue to carry out all production activities
independently on their own. In contrast to the minor role of production
cooperatives in market economies, service cooperatives in many countries
163
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
account for a large share of transactions in the relevant economic sector. For
instance, agricultural marketing, processing, and supply cooperativesare major
players in markets for farm products and farm inputs in North America, Western
Europe, Japan, and South-East Asia. In the U.S., agricultural cooperatives handle
about 30% of farmers’ total farm marketing volume and 28% of farmers’ total
supply purchases (Mather et al., 2004). In the European Union, the share of
agricultural cooperatives is even larger: in countries such as the Netherlands,
Denmark, Ireland, and Sweden 70%-80% of farm products are marketed through
cooperatives and cooperatives account for 50%-70% of all farm input purchases
(Van Bekkum and Van Dijk, 1997).
Service cooperatives may actually employ some of their members as workers,
but most employees (and even most managers) are hired outsiders. Service
cooperatives use members’ share contributions to capital and borrowed funds to
finance purchase of goods and services from various market sources and then
resell these services to members at advantageous prices.
Consumer cooperatives in Western nomenclature are trading firms that sell
consumer goods primarily to their members at advantageous prices. They are
basically a variety of supply cooperatives (outside agriculture), but they are
treated as a separate class because of their numerical importance in the world. The
largest segment of consumer cooperatives is cooperative food stores and
supermarkets (“grocery stores”), but cooperative stores that sell clothes,
housewares, appliances, and even cars to their members – at advantageous prices
– also fall in the category of consumer cooperatives. In the West, consumer
cooperatives, unlike other service cooperatives, are most likely to deal with nonmembers (“third parties”) on a regular basis: this is their strategy of achieving
growth comparable with other firms in the highly competitive consumer services
sector. Consumer cooperatives typically charge a higher price on their
transactions with non-members.
Ukraine and Kazakhstan Legislation on Agricultural Service
Cooperatives
The USSR Law on Cooperation
The first mention of cooperatives in Ukrainian and Kazakh legislation actually
predates independent Ukraine and Kazakhstan, occurring in the USSR law “On
Cooperation in the USSR” (1988). This law set the precedent for subsequent
legislation in that it considers two main types of cooperatives—consumer
(potrebitel’skie) and production (proizvodstvennye) cooperatives. However, the
164
10. Agricultural Cooperative Development in Kazakhstan and Ukraine
conceptual distinction between the two types (article 3.2) is not mutually
exclusive. Production cooperatives are defined to “produce goods, products,
works and also render paid services…. They are created and operate for
production, procurement, processing and marketing of agricultural
production….” Consumer cooperatives serve the demand of their members and
other citizens in trade and service industries, as well as their members for housing,
dachas and garden plots, garages and parking places for automobiles, socialcultural and other services. In addition to these functions, consumer cooperatives
may also develop various production activities, which are not necessarily limited
to processing and may include “subsidiary” agricultural enterprises.
The 1988 law is usually credited with being the first step toward private
enterprise and market economy in the USSR under the guise of “cooperatives”,
which were defined as new organizational forms free from strict state control –
but without adherence to Western cooperative principles. Yet this 1988 law
(articles 45-46) also perpetuates the traditional Soviet system of state-controlled
“consumer cooperation” (sistema potrebitel’skoi kooperatsii), which operated in
rural areas since the early 1920s and was primarily designed to provide farm
services (product marketing, input supply) to household plots and consumer
services (through trading outlets) to the rural population in general. Since the
Soviet “consumer cooperation system” was in effect a system of (state-run)
service facilities for small producers and rural people, a semantic link was forged
in Russian between “consumer cooperative” and “service cooperative”. The term
“consumer cooperative” is accordingly still used in the legislation of some CIS
countries (in particular, Kazakhstan) in the sense of “service cooperative”, while
other countries (e.g., Ukraine, Kyrgyzstan) have adopted the Western term
“service cooperative”.
Ukraine Cooperative Law
The basic law on agricultural cooperatives under independent Ukraine (On
Agricultural Cooperation, 1997) represented an immense improvement over the
1988 USSR law. This law seems to be drafted in accordance with the principles
of the International Cooperative Alliance. The concept of “consumer cooperative”
was replaced with the Western concept of “service cooperative”
(obsluzhivaiushchii kooperativ in Russian, obslugovuiuchii kooperativ in
Ukrainian), and the conceptual distinction between production and service
cooperatives is clear. An agricultural production cooperative is defined in article
1 of the law as “an agricultural cooperative formed by the union of physical
persons who are agricultural producers for joint production or other activities
according to the principle of obligatory labor participation with the goal of
165
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
making a profit.” An agricultural service cooperative is “an agricultural
cooperative formed through the union of physical and/or legal persons who are
agricultural producers for the organization of services aimed at reducing costs
and/or increasing incomes of the members of the cooperative in their agricultural
activities.” Agricultural service cooperatives service their members “without the
goal of making a profit and are non-profit organizations (art. 9).”
With the additional law “On cooperation” (On cooperation, 2004) the basic
legal framework in Ukraine for agricultural service cooperatives was defined. The
1997 and 2004 laws have been amended many times over the past decade and a
half with the aim of improving the enabling environment for cooperatives in
Ukraine. The last amendment to the law “On agricultural service cooperation”
was passed by the Parliament on 20 November 2012 and was endorsed by the
President of Ukraine on 19 January 2013.
Kazakhstan Cooperative Law
The basic definitions of cooperatives as a corporate form of organization
appear in the Civil Code, which was originally adopted in 1994 and then
repeatedly amended. Unlike Ukraine, however, Kazakhstan has never adopted the
term “service cooperative” in its legislation and continues to use the traditional
Soviet terms for the dichotomy of cooperatives: “production cooperative”
(proizvodstvennyi kooperativ) and “consumer cooperative” (potrebitel’skii
kooperativ). Despite the retention of the traditional Soviet term “consumer
cooperative”, this concept in Kazakhstan has been detached from the sweeping
concept of “rural consumer cooperation system” (the Soviet-model potrebsoyuz),
which is intended (on paper) to serve the entire rural population at the level of
household plots, providing collection/marketing of produce and extending
consumer goods sales through a network of stores in villages.
A detailed definition of production cooperative was included already in the
1994 version of the Civil Code (art. 96-101), where it is basically consistent with
the Western concept of production cooperative. A new definition of consumer
cooperative was added in 1998 (art. 108), and it became clear that the term
“consumer cooperative” in Kazakhstan is in effect identical with the Western term
“service cooperative”. Production cooperatives are defined as “commercial” (i.e.,
“for profit”) organizations employing members’ labor. Service (“consumer”)
cooperatives are defined as “non-commercial” (i.e., “not for profit”) organizations
that may employ hired labor. Non-commercial organizations may not distribute
their surplus (“profit”) to members: all profits must be retained as cooperative
equity (Law of Non-commercial Organizations, January 2001, art. 2; this principle
is explicitly specialized to service cooperatives in art. 14(4)).
166
10. Agricultural Cooperative Development in Kazakhstan and Ukraine
Five cooperative-related laws were passed between 1995 and 2003,
elaborating on the basic definitions in the Civil Code:
N
N
N
N
N
Law of Production Cooperative (1995)
Law of Rural Consumer Cooperation (1999)
Law of Agricultural Partnerships and Their Associations (2000)
Law of Consumer Cooperatives (2001)
Law of Rural Consumer Cooperatives of Water Users (“Water User
Associations”, 2003).
The laws clearly define the main types of cooperatives – production and
service (or “consumer”) cooperatives and there is generally no ambiguity as to
cooperative types in Kazakh legislation. The only quirk is that the Russian term
“consumer cooperative” (potrebitel’skii kooperativ) should be consistently
rendered as “service cooperative” in English. Comparative analysis of the five
laws shows that they mostly repeat the same cooperative principles and attributes.
All cooperatives are voluntary associations of users who have a common goal and
engage in common activities, the cooperative is created by a general assembly of
its founding members, the assets of a cooperative represent the sum total of
members’ contributions (“shares”) and cumulative retained profits, all
cooperatives primarily serve their members but may also engage in transactions
with non-members. The Law of Agricultural Partnerships holds a somewhat
special place, as it explicitly stipulates that an agricultural partnership sells its
services to members at cost, so that no profit is created. The services provided by
an agricultural partnership to its members include marketing, storage, processing
of farm products, supply of farm inputs, etc. An agricultural partnership is thus
essentially a classical service cooperative.
Taxation of Cooperatives
A cooperative is a legal body that deals with other legal bodies (agricultural
enterprises and peasant farms) and also with smallholders who are not registered
for tax purposes (e.g., household plots). The cooperative as a legal body is subject
to taxation, which includes both profit tax and VAT. Smallholders, on the other
hand, are typically exempt from these taxes or avoid them in various semi-legal
ways. As a result of the taxes that cooperatives pay, a smallholder dealing through
a cooperative is likely to net less from marketing transactions (or pay more for
purchasing transactions) than the amounts he would have received (or paid) by
dealing directly with buyers and suppliers. These tax distortions place cooperative
members at a disadvantage compared to those who operate independently.
167
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
Conceptual Issues of Cooperative Taxation
Profit tax and cooperatives. Although in principle cooperatives are non-profit
organizations, their financial reports may show an accounting profit at the level
of revenues and expenses (called “surplus” in Western cooperative accounting).
This accounting profit is created because the cooperative may have initially
underpaid its members for products delivered (expenses too low) or overcharged
them for inputs supplied (revenues too high). In effect the accounting profit is the
result of internal pricing decisions within the cooperative, and not profit in the
usual economic sense of the term.
Cooperatives do not know in advance, at the time of the actual transaction,
how much to pay to members for product deliveries and how much to charge for
input supplies and other services. Financial settlements with members are handled
in two waves: the first-wave payments and charges are in the nature of an initial
advance, and the final settlement is made at the end of the period, when the
cooperative financial statements have been prepared. As a result, a service
cooperative usually presents a financial statement that shows a positive surplus
(accounting profit) or a deficit (accounting loss) according to the scheme in Table
10.3.
Table 10.3. Schematic “profit and loss” statement of a cooperative
Marketing service cooperative
Supply service cooperative
Revenues from sale of members’ products to
Revenues: first-wave payments from members
third parties
Costs:
Costs:
First-wave payments to members
Paid to suppliers
Operating costs of the cooperative
Operating costs of the cooperative
Revenues – Costs =
Gross income (surplus/deficit)
Less allocation to reserve fund and other funds
Less distribution in proportion to share contribution (iZ_\u_ \uieZlu, “dividends”)
Difference available for distribution as patronage refunds (dhhi_jZlb\gu_ \uieZlu)
Gross income (dokhod in Russian) represents the surplus or deficit that is
further allocated via three channels:
1) Allocation to the cooperative reserve fund or other capital funds (“retained
earnings” in standard accounting terminology).
2) Distribution to members in proportion to their share contribution to the
cooperative capital (“dividends” in standard Western terminology; paevye
vyplaty in Russian).
168
10. Agricultural Cooperative Development in Kazakhstan and Ukraine
3) Patronage refunds (kooperativnye vyplaty in Russian) in proportion to
members’ use of cooperative services (i.e., basically in proportion to firstwave payments to the members).
The sum of the three amounts distributed to members is equal to gross income.
Patronage refunds are determined as the difference between gross income and the
first two allocations.
Conventional interpretation of the tax code will require the cooperative to pay
tax on the full gross income at applicable rates. Recognition of the special nature
of patronage refunds in cooperatives (as second-wave adjustment of initial overor under-payment to members) suggest that this component of gross income
should not be taxable. This is the essence of the principle of “fiscal transparency”
applied to cooperatives in the Netherlands, where transactions between members
and their cooperative are exempt from all taxes. Furthermore, the U.S. tax code
recognizes “dividends” paid to members in agricultural cooperatives (but not
other cooperatives) as non-taxable at the cooperative level, i.e., exempt from
withholding taxes (Autry and Hall, 2009). If the Dutch and the U.S. tax principles
are adopted, the cooperative will be required to pay tax only on the share of gross
income retained in reserve fund and other capital funds. The amount retained in
the reserve fund and other capital funds will be shown net after deduction of the
appropriate taxes.
Value added tax (VAT) and cooperatives. In buy-and-sell transactions
between legal bodies, the seller (a peasant farmer, say) charges VAT on his sale
and the buyer will deduct from his ultimate VAT liability the amount of VAT
charged by the seller. Thus, the buyer will pay the seller $100 for his tomatoes
plus $20 VAT. Reselling the tomatoes for $110, the buyer will add $22 VAT, but
his net VAT obligation will be only $2 ($22 less $20 paid to the original seller).
If, however, the seller is a physical body (a smallholder not registered for tax
purposes), he does not pay VAT and charges the buyer $100 for the tomatoes,
without adding VAT. In this way, when the buyer – a legal body – sells the
tomatoes for $110 plus $22 VAT, there is nothing to offset against this VAT and
the seller’s actual VAT obligation is $22. The buyer will naturally attempt to
charge this extra “cost” back to the original seller, paying less than $100 for the
tomatoes. The smallholder is thus at a clear disadvantage when selling his
products to a legal body (e.g., a cooperative).
A similar chain can be traced for purchase transactions. The seller of inputs (a
cooperative) charges VAT on the sale transaction. A peasant farmer (legal body
registered for tax purposes) can offset the amount of VAT against his cumulative
VAT obligations. For a smallholder, on the other hand, the actual cost is the cost
169
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
of input plus the amount of VAT, which he must absorb. A smallholder would be
better off by dealing with a small private supplier who does not charge VAT rather
than with the cooperative.
The only fair way to deal with the VAT issue is to exempt all transactions
between cooperative members and the cooperative from VAT altogether.
Cooperative laws and the Tax Code should recognize that cooperative members
do not sell their production to cooperatives, but only transfer it to the cooperative
for marketing. In this respect, the cooperative is an extension of the farm itself.
Ukraine: Taxation of Cooperatives
Beginning in 2013 the Ukrainian law on agricultural service cooperatives
explicitly recognizes the non-profit status of service cooperatives.18 However, the
Ukrainian Tax Code still does not recognize the non-profit status of these
cooperatives. Thus, agricultural service cooperatives are required to pay profit tax
on their gross income (see Table 10.3), like other legal entities, such as joint stock
companies. A partial solution to this issue (introduced into the Tax Code on 1
January 2013) was reached according to which the profit tax for service
cooperatives is assessed on its net income after subtracting all “mandatory and
dividend payments,” 19 meaning that the profit tax is assessed on the net income
available for distribution as patronage funds. This compromise still subjects
farmers who join cooperatives to double taxation, but the tax base has been
reduced considerably. A bill to amend the Tax Code to ensure that agricultural
service cooperatives are considered non-profit entities was introduced into the
Ukrainian Rada in March 2012 by the Communist parliamentary faction, but has
not been passed.
Service cooperatives, like all legal bodies, are subject to VAT in Ukraine,
including VAT on transactions with their members. Thus, in Ukraine
smallholders are at a disadvantage when buying and selling from cooperatives, as
described in the previous section.
A further disincentive to join a cooperative is that by joining a service
cooperative any agricultural producer that is a legal person risks losing the tax
benefits that accrue by virtue of its agricultural producer status. This risk is a
powerful disincentive for agricultural producers to buy and sell through
18
Ukrainian law “On changes to the Law of Ukraine On Agricultural Cooperation” -VI (20
November 2012).
19
Allocations made to reserve funds and other funds and payments made as share contributions
(dividends). See above Table 10.3 for explanation. Law of Ukraine “On changes to the Tax Code of
Ukraine for regulation of certain taxation issues,” (2 October 2012) no. 5412-VI.
170
10. Agricultural Cooperative Development in Kazakhstan and Ukraine
agricultural service cooperatives. The status of service cooperatives as legal
persons subject to both profit taxes and VAT sets them apart from agricultural
producers, which since 1998 have been subject to a special tax regime that leaves
them nearly untaxed. The two elements of the special regime for agriculture are
the fixed agricultural tax (FAT) and the agricultural VAT (AgVAT). The FAT is
a flat rate tax introduced in lieu of profit, land and a number of other taxes. Its
rate varies from 0.09 to 1% of the normative value of farmland, depending on
farmland’s type and location. In 2010, the FAT resulted in an average tax payment
of roughly 6 UAH/ha (0.75 USD/ha). This meant that farm profits in Ukraine
were virtually untaxed (Nievskiy, 2012). Under the AgVAT agricultural
producers accumulate their own VAT payments, but do not transfer them to the
government. Instead, they are required to deposit VAT payments in a special
account to use for their own input purchases, such as for farming equipment and
seeds. Thus, the AgVAT allows agricultural businesses to virtually avoid VAT
payments (Nievsky, 2012).
Kazakhstan: Taxation of Cooperatives
The current Tax Code introduces a so-called “special tax regime” for
agricultural producers (enterprises and peasant farms) and specifically also for
agricultural (or rural) service cooperatives. Legal entities opting for the special
tax regime are understood to be small agricultural producers. They are entitled to
follow a highly simplified tax-return system, with minimum accounting
requirements, and in addition they pay only 30% of the standard tax rate on all
basic taxes (primarily VAT and corporate income tax, as well as land tax, land
lease payments to the state, property tax, social tax, vehicle tax). Since the tax
code explicitly puts agricultural service cooperatives in the same category with
other agricultural producer, there are no blatant tax distortions for cooperatives.
Possible distortions may arise for operators of household plots. They only pay
personal income tax and their agricultural activities are exempt from taxes. If they
join a service cooperative, the cooperative – a legal entity – will be obligated to
calculate VAT on their transactions, albeit at the concessionary rate.
Another possible distortion stems from Article 448 (para. 3) of the Tax Code
(Conception, 2012). According to this curious article, a rural service cooperative
is not entitled to follow the special tax regime if its members are at the same time
members of another service cooperative or if it has subsidiary enterprises. This
provision was originally intended to preclude large agricultural enterprises from
enjoying the special-regime tax concessions, but it has run into vocal opposition.
In the past, Article 448 was suspended once for the 2010 tax year and it is now
again a bone of contention between agricultural tax payers and the government.
171
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
Conclusion
This short review of the status of agricultural service cooperatives in
Kazakhstan and Ukraine has shown the difficulties encountered by governments
in the region in encouraging the formation of agricultural service cooperatives.
While there appears to be widespread recognition by governments of the
usefulness of cooperatives, policies designed to support them focus on subsidies
for input purchases and subsidized loans. While these policies have been of some
help to some, they also seem to have bred a class of “false cooperatives”, i.e.,
established only for the purpose of gaining access to subsidized credits and inputs,
without any regard for true cooperative principles.
Furthermore, neither government has succeeded in creating a supportive
business environment for this specific self-help organization. Tax disincentives in
both countries are an important reason for lagging numbers of working
cooperatives. Though the profit tax issue was mostly overcome in Ukraine at the
end of 2012, the VAT system in both Ukraine and Kazakhstan discriminates
against smallholders making service cooperatives unattractive for precisely the
set of farms for which these organizations can be most helpful. In Ukraine,
moreover, even farms that are legal entities risk their special tax status by buying
or selling through service cooperatives.
Finally, neither government has really dealt with the important issue of
informing the rural population on the cooperative idea and its benefits. In Ukraine
this issue was mentioned as perhaps the most important issue by the participants
of the All Ukraine Public Meeting “Ukraine on the Eve of the International Year
of Cooperatives” (15 December 2011) attended by service cooperative leaders,
regional cooperative activists, as well as researchers, government employees and
project personnel connected with development of cooperatives (Korinets,
2013:17). Cooperative Development Centers in the United States are an example
of the type of government-private sector collaboration that can accomplish this
task. Cooperative Development Centers are non-profit state-level organizations
funded by cooperatives themselves and co-funded by the US Department of
Agriculture. Their function is to explain the cooperative idea and the specific
benefits for those interested, to train in cooperative management skills, and
support the public with the business, legal and tax information needed for
cooperative startups and management. They also offer individual technical
assistance by qualified experts, the costs of which may be covered by the US
Department of Agriculture grants for the development of cooperatives.
While the type of public-private partnership represented by the US
Cooperative Development Centers is an excellent example of an institution to
172
10. Agricultural Cooperative Development in Kazakhstan and Ukraine
support the development of cooperatives, there is no substitute for a grass-roots
cooperative movement driven by enthusiasm for the cooperative model. It is the
movement in countries around the world that was responsible for building
agricultural service cooperatives far before they became a part of state policy. The
cooperative movement in Ukraine and Kazakhstan from all appearances, seem to
be at an early stage, perhaps understandable for countries that only twenty years
ago knew only the Soviet model of cooperation.
References
Abele, S. and Frohberg, K., eds. (2003). Subsistence Agriculture in Central and
Eastern Europe: How to Break the Vicious Circle, Studies on the Agricultural
and Food Sector in Central and Eastern Europe, Vol. 22, IAMO, Halle.
Agriculture Canada (processed). Agricultural Co-operatives: A Startup Guide.
www.agf.gov.bc.ca/busmgmt/bus_arrange/bus_arrang_pdf/coop1.pdf
Akimbekova, G. U. (2010). “Agricultural Cooperation in Kazakhstan: problems
and possible solutions,” Ekonomika APK (Kiev), No. 9: 161-166.
Bono, P. (2012). Support for Farmers’ Cooperatives; Country Report Italy.
Wageningen: Wageningen UR.
Cabinet of Ministers of Ukraine. (2007). “State Special Program for the
Development of the Ukrainian Village to 2015,” Resolution from 19.09.2007,
no. 1158. http://zakon1.rada.gov.ua/laws/show/1158-2007-%D0%BF
Cabinet of Ministers of Ukraine. (2011). “State Special Economic Program for
the Support of the Development of Agricultural Service Cooperatives to
2015,” Resolution from 7.07.2011 no. 557.
http://zakon1.rada.gov.ua/laws/show/557-2009-%D0%BF
Cobia, D., ed. (1989). Cooperatives in Agriculture, Prentice Hall, Englewood
Cliffs, NJ.
Conception (2012). Conception of the Development of Agricultural Cooperation
in Kazakhstan, Kazakh Research Institute of Agricultural Economics and AO
“Kazagroinnovatsiya” (Almaty, 2012).
Draft amendment (2010). Draft of proposed additions and amendments to the Law
on Rural Consumer Cooperation in the Republic of Kazakhstan [in Russian].
http://www.all-docs.ru/index.php?page=7&vi1=134686.000
EBRD (2012). Transition Report 2012: Integration Across Borders, European
Bank for Reconstruction and Development, London.
Eurostat (2013). “Agricultural holdings, 2000-2010,”
http://epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/statistics_explained/index.php?title=File:Agr
icultural_holdings,_2000-2010.png&filetimestamp=20121105110459
173
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
Filippi, M. (2012). Support for Farmers’ Cooperatives; Country Report France.
Wageningen: Wageningen UR.
Gijselinckx, C., M. Bussels (2012). Support for Farmers’ Cooperatives; EU
synthesis and comparative analysis report; Social and Historical Aspects.
Wageningen: Wageningen UR.
Grigoruk, V. (2009). “Legislative conflicts as a barrier to cooperation,”
http://www.zakon.kz/154625-konflikt-zakonov-tormoz-kooperacii.html
Hofstede, G., Hofstede, G.J. and Minkov, M. (2010). Cultures and Organizations:
Software of the Mind, third edition (New York: McGraw-Hill).
ICA (2013). “Co-operative identity, values & principles,” International
Cooperative Alliance.
http://ica.coop/en/what-co-op/co-operative-identity-values-principles
Kazakhstan-2050 (2012). Strategy for the development of the Republic of
Kazakhstan to 2050, announced by President Nursultan Nazarbaev on 14
December 2012, Astana.
http://adilet.zan.kz/rus/archive/docs/K1200002050/14.12.2012
Korinets, Roman (2013). Sel’skokhoziastvenny obsluzhivaiushchie kooperativy
v Ukraine [Agricultural Service Cooperatives in Ukraine], FAO REU Policy
Studies on Rural Transition No. 2013-6, FAO Regional Office for Europe and
Central Asia.
http://www.fao.org/docrep/018/ar593r/ar593r.pdf
Lissowska, M. (2013). “The Deficit of Cooperative Attitudes and Trust in PostTransition Economies,” EAEPE Papers in Evolutionary Political Economy,
no. 10 (2013).
Mather, J.W., K.C. DeVille, A.L. Gessner, and C.C. Adams (2004). Farm
Marketing, Supply and Service Cooperative Historical Statistics, USDA,
Cooperative Information Report 1, Washington, DC.
Ministry of Agrarian Policy and Food of Ukraine (2002). “Program for the
Development of Agricultural Service Cooperatives for 2003-2004”.
http://zakon2.rada.gov.ua/laws/show/1858-2002-%D0%BF
Ministry of Agrarian Policy and Food of Ukraine (2012). “Information on the
Public Presentation by Mikhail Prisiazhniuk of the Ministry of Agrarian Policy
and Food Initiative “My Village” Designed to Stimulate the Development of
Small and Medium Agricultural Producers”.
http://www.carpathia.gov.ua/data/upload/publication/main/ua/491/18051210
59.pdf
Nivievskyi, Oleg (2012). “Agri-Food Policy Review. Tackling the dilemma of
agricultural taxation: Moving towards a comprehensive and transparent
approach,” issue 9/2012, German-Ukrainian Agricultural Policy Dialogue
174
10. Agricultural Cooperative Development in Kazakhstan and Ukraine
(APD) Institute for Economic Research and Policy (IER) Consulting.
Parliament of Ukraine. (1997). “On Agricultural Cooperation” 17 July, 1997,
Law of Ukraine 469/97.
http://zakon2.rada.gov.ua/laws/show/469/97-%D0%B2%D1%80
Parliament of Ukraine. (2004). “On cooperation,” 11 November, 2004, Law of
Ukraine no. 1087-15.
http://zakon2.rada.gov.ua/laws/show/1087-15
Parliament of Ukraine. (2005). “On the Main Pillars of State Agrarian Policy to
2015,” Law of Ukraine 2005 no. 2982-IV.
http://zakon1.rada.gov.ua/laws/show/2982-15
President of Ukraine. (2000). “On the Means for Development of the Cooperative
Movement and Strengthening of its Role in the Market Reform of the
Ukrainian Economy,” 3UHVLGHQWLDO 'HFUHH .
http://zakon2.rada.gov.ua/laws/show/1348/2000
RBK-Ukraine. (2013). “More than 83% of local governments support the
formation of agricultural cooperatives” 28.02.2013.
http://www.rbc.ua/rus/news/economic/obedinenie-v-selhozkooperativy-uzhepodderzhali-bolee-28022013130900
State Statistics Service of Ukraine (2012). Agriculture of Ukraine 2011:
Statistical Yearbook (Kiev).
State Statistics Service of Ukraine (2011). Main Agricultural Characteristics of
Rural Households in Rural Areas (Kiev).
Statistical Agency of Kazakhstan. (2012). Agriculture in Kazakhstan 2009-2011,
Statistical yearbook, Astana. www.stat.kz
Szabó, G. G., (2012). Support for Farmers’ Cooperatives; Country Report
Hungary. Wageningen: Wageningen UR.
Tomich, I. F. (2013). “Initsiativa ‘Rodnoe selo’—posledniaia nadezhda selian”,
Gazeta.ua, 22.03.2013. http://gazeta.ua/ru/articles/488810
USDA (2012). Cooperative Statistics 2011 (Sarah Ali, Jacqueline E. Penn and E.
Eldon Eversull), U.S. Department of Agriculture Service Report 72, October.
USDA (2013). USDA Rural Development: Cooperatives, U.S. Department of
Agriculture Rural Development web site.
http://www.rurdev.usda.gov/LP_CoopPrograms.html
USDA-NAS (2013). Farms, Land in Farms, and Livestock Operations 2012
Summary, U.S. Department of Agriculture, National Agricultural Statistics
Service, February.
Van Bekkum, O. and Van Dijk, G. (1997). Agricultural Co-operatives in the
European Union, Van Gorcum, Assen.
175
11. Cooperatives in CIS and Georgia:20
Overview of legislation
Zvi Lerman and David Sedik (2014)
Cooperatives in agriculture and in other sectors are usually created by
grassroots users to overcome market failures, which are manifested in
unwillingness of private business entrepreneurs to provide services in areas that
they judge unprofitable or, alternatively, in unfair exploitation of the users by
private businesses through monopolistic practices. Best-practice world
experience suggests that farmers’ service cooperatives provide the most effective
way of improving the access of small farmers to market services in both
situations. International Cooperative Alliance (ICA) defines a cooperative as an
autonomous association of persons united voluntarily to meet their common
economic, social, and cultural needs and aspirations through a jointly owned and
democratically controlled enterprise (ICA, 2013). The persons who voluntarily
unite to form a cooperative are usually referred to as members or member-owners.
A cooperative is a legal entity and, in a certain sense, it is an analogue of a
shareholder corporation. There are, however, some fundamental differences
between a cooperative and a corporation, as listed in Table 11.1. Perhaps the main
difference concerns the organization’s objective: while business corporations aim
to maximize their profit, cooperatives aim to maximize the benefits that members
derive from their participation in cooperative activities, including lower prices
paid for inputs and services and higher prices received for products (Cobia, 1998).
The main areas of activity of agricultural service cooperatives are outlined in
Table 11.2.
Smallholders in the Commonwealth of Independent States and Georgia
(abbreviated here in an ad hoc manner as CIS) are exposed to both dimensions of
20
Since August 2009, Georgia is no longer a member of the Commonwealth of Independent States
(CIS). The accepted acronym CIS is used in our context in an ad hoc manner to designate the 11 current
members of the CIS plus Georgia.
176
11. Cooperatives in CIS and Georgia: Overview of Legislation
market failure mentioned above. After twenty years of transition, there are still
not enough private entrepreneurs to satisfy the needs of the huge number of
peasant farms and household plots, and smallholders often feel that they suffer
from blatantly exploitative practices of private intermediaries due to lack of
competition.
Table 11.1. Comparative attributes of a cooperative and a shareholder corporation
Attribute
Owners
Owners’ objective
Organization’s objective
Voting rights
Income distribution rules
Cooperative
Members
Use of services provided by
the cooperative
Maximize members’ benefits
from working with the
cooperative
One member–one vote,
regardless of share
contribution
Income distributed to
members in proportion to
their participation in the
activity of the cooperative
Corporation
Shareholders–investors
Earning income
Maximize corporate profits
Number of votes proportional
to number of shares (i.e.,
share contribution)
Income distributed to
shareholders in proportion to
the number of shares held
Table 11.2. Areas of activity of agricultural service cooperatives
Type
Marketing
cooperatives
Processing
cooperatives
Supply cooperatives
Technical farm
services
Consumer and public
services
Areas of activity
Collection, storage, sorting, packing, sale of farm products;
provision of marketing information and services
Variety of marketing cooperatives: processing of food commodities
(milk, fruits and vegetables, wineries, milling, baking, meat and fish
products, cotton gins, oil pressing); sale of processed products
Purchase and stocking of farm inputs, resale to member-producers;
animal feed
Machinery pools, mechanized field works (plowing, harvesting),
transport, machinery maintenance;
Veterinary services, artificial insemination;
Accounting and computer services
Agricultural extension and consulting services
Development and maintenance of telephone, gas, and electricity
networks in rural areas
Health-care services
Education and training
Legal advice
Market-oriented scholars accordingly expected to see rapid development of
agricultural service cooperatives in CIS in response to smallholder needs (see,
e.g., Chapter 5). These expectations, however, have not materialized and the
177
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
development of agricultural service cooperatives in CIS countries lags far behind
the status of cooperative development in most of the world (see Chapter 10).
Inadequacy of the legislative framework is often cited among the reasons that
may be responsible for the unsatisfactory development of cooperatives in CIS. In
this study, we review the cooperative laws in all 12 CIS countries (including
Georgia) and examine their compatibility with universal cooperative principles
and actual practices in the West.
The Dichotomy of Production and Service Cooperatives in CIS
One of the features of the cooperative legal framework in CIS is the distinction
between agricultural service cooperatives (which idiosyncratically are often
called in Russian “consumer cooperatives” – potrebitel’skie kooperativy) and
agricultural production cooperatives (proizvodstvennye kooperativy). This
dichotomy is hardly ever made explicit in established market economies, where
practically no production cooperatives exist and “agricultural cooperative” is
automatically understood as “agricultural service cooperative”. In CIS countries,
on the other hand, “agricultural cooperative” is automatically understood as an
“agricultural production cooperative” and the adjective “service” must be
explicitly added in Russian to clarify that an agricultural service cooperative is
actually meant (obsluzhivayushchii kooperativ, servisnyi kooperativ).
This is a curious situation for a region (former Czarist Russia) that had a
developed system of service cooperatives before the 1917 Bolshevik revolution
(Epshtein, 1993; Serova, 1991), practically without any production cooperatives
(artel’, as they became known in Russian in the early part of the 20th century).
The paradigm shift dates back to the 1920s, when Lenin proclaimed his socialist
vision of the development of cooperatives: gradual and voluntary movement from
lower to higher forms of cooperation, from marketing, service, and credit
cooperatives to highest forms of production cooperatives (Osipov, 1960; see also
Lenin, 1923). This vision, presenting production cooperatives as the highest form
of cooperation, was subsequently implemented in Stalin’s collectivization drive
(from 1928-1929 through the 1930s), which eventually transformed agriculture
in all countries of the Soviet Union (the predecessors of CIS) to agriculture of
collective farms, i.e., production cooperatives. Thus, contrary to the situation in
developed market economies, tens of thousands of production cooperatives
existed in CIS in the form of collective farms (kolkhozes) well into the post-1992
transition and many continue to exist in the form of “agricultural cooperatives”
after the reforms that eliminated the collective farms (see, e.g., Golovina et al.,
2012).
178
11. Cooperatives in CIS and Georgia: Overview of Legislation
Perhaps the main difference between a service cooperative and a production
cooperative is the status of a member vis-à-vis the cooperative. A service
cooperative is an association of members-producers who retain their legal and
operational independence, with production activities conducted on memberowned farms outside the cooperative (Figure 11.1). Participation in cooperative
activities – marketing, input purchasing, machinery services, etc. – is obligatory,
but members are not required to contribute their labor by working in the
organization. The service cooperative in turn conducts transactions primarily with
its members, not with third persons. It is expected that the service cooperative will
be able to achieve, through economies of size, higher prices for the integrated sale
of members’ products and lower costs for the bulk purchase of inputs for the
members. This price advantage is the benefit that members derive from the service
cooperative.
Figure 11.1. Schema of a service or consumer
cooperative.
Figure 11.2. Schema of a production
cooperative.
In a production cooperative, on the other hand, members typically work inside
the cooperative, and not as independent entities (Figure 11.2). They engage in
joint production using pooled resources (land or machinery); the cooperative sells
the jointly produced output in the market and purchases inputs for the joint
production process – not for individual members. The production cooperative
conducts business transactions primarily with third persons and remunerates the
member-workers from its operating revenues and surpluses. Like a service
cooperative, it strives to benefit its members, but in a different way: the benefits
to members come through providing them with a secure workplace and a
satisfactory salary (income) that could be otherwise difficult to achieve.
The theory behind production cooperatives is that economies of scale work in
primary agriculture and that joint production on large tracts of pooled land is more
efficient and profitable than individual production on small plots (a claim that has
179
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
never been proved for primary agriculture). Despite these substantive differences
between production and service cooperatives and the frequent promulgation of
separate laws for the two types of cooperatives in CIS, the legal definitions of
their operating scope are virtually identical: only one function – “production” –
distinguishes between the list of activities prescribed for service cooperatives and
production cooperatives in the civil codes and cooperative laws of CIS countries.
Other than “production”, both service and production cooperatives are legally
allowed to engage in the full range of agricultural service and support activities.
The 2013 Tajikistan Law of Cooperatives states, without elaboration, that
production cooperatives may engage in production alongside a range of other
activities, while the 1999 Tajikistan Civil Code elaborates the “other activities”
by listing processing, marketing, contract work, trade, and consumer services –
all of which are standard functions of a service cooperative. A recent survey of
cooperatives and cooperative members in Kyrgyzstan (see Chapter 9) has
actually shown that, in addition to joint production based on member labor inputs,
production cooperatives also provide farm services to non-members –
independent peasant farmers and household plot operators who are not part of the
joint production system. The activities of service cooperatives are thus a subset
of the activities envisaged for production cooperatives in CIS legislation;
production cooperatives may engage in the same service activities plus primary
production. It is therefore understandable how some CIS countries managed to
incorporate both production and service cooperatives in one cooperative law (see
row 3 of the comparative analysis of cooperative laws in Table 11.5).
Table 11.3. Differences in legal classification of cooperatives in CIS legislation
Production cooperative
Legal body
Commercial (“for profit”) organization
Sales to third parties only
Members part of the labor force
Consumer (service) cooperative
Legal body
Non-commercial (“not-for-profit”) organization
Sales mostly to members
Members not necessarily part of the labor force
It seems that the legal distinction between production and consumer (service)
cooperatives in CIS legislation is not based on functional attributes (i.e., what the
cooperatives do). Instead, cooperatives are classified based on formal businessrelated attributes (Table 11.3), such as profit-making behavior (“commercial”,
i.e., “for profit” organizations and “non-commercial”, i.e., “not for profit”
organizations), clientele orientation (sales to members or non-members), and
composition of the labor force (members work or do not work in the cooperative).
Unfortunately, these formal attributes are ambiguous and fuzzy for cooperatives
and are not suitable for unambiguous classification.
180
11. Cooperatives in CIS and Georgia: Overview of Legislation
In theory, a cooperative – whether a service cooperative or a production
cooperative – is a “zero-profit” organization: it may distribute all its operating
surpluses to members through adjustment transactions motivated by cooperative
principles and end up with zero bottom line in the statement of financial results.
Payments to members for their products (or for their work in production
cooperatives) and charges for inputs and services are regarded as advances when
they are routinely made during the year. In a service cooperative, surpluses may
arise if, for instance, the cooperative initially paid the members for their products
less than what it eventually received in the market (“underpayment”), or
alternatively if the cooperative initially charged for services more than the actual
cost (“overcharging”). In a production cooperative, surpluses may arise if the
salaries paid to member-workers over the year were too low compared to the final
revenues reported at the end of the period. In both situations, the surpluses can be
distributed to members (in proportion to their participation in the cooperative
activities) so that the cooperative reports zero accounting profit.
Whether or not a cooperative is viewed as a “zero-profit” organization
naturally has an impact on its tax liabilities. The prevailing practice in established
market economies is to recognize service cooperatives as non-profit entities and
to exempt payouts to members from taxation at the level of the cooperative (see,
e.g., Autry and Hall, 2009; Dutch Cooperative, undated); thus, only the retained
portion of the surplus, if any, is taxed. On the other hand, no clear pattern with
respect to tax status can be distinguished in CIS legislation. Many CIS countries
treat production cooperatives as “for profit” manufacturing corporations and tax
them in full. The treatment of service cooperatives varies: some countries treat
service cooperatives also as “for profit” (“commercial” in Civil Code terminology
across CIS) entities and tax their surpluses before distribution to members, while
other countries are beginning to allow “not for profit” (“noncommercial”) status
to service cooperatives and exempt their surpluses from taxes. It seems that
ongoing tax legislation reforms will do nothing with regard to the taxable status
of production cooperatives while pushing all service cooperatives toward taxexempt “not for profit” status.
Inventory of Cooperative Laws in CIS
Legislation on cooperatives in CIS is usually organized on three levels. The
general legislative level includes primarily the Civil Code, which is the
foundation for the definition of cooperative as a legal form, and the Tax Code,
which introduces cooperative-specific taxation provisions (if and when
necessary). On the next level, we have cooperative-specific laws, which are
devoted in their entirety to treatment of cooperatives as a separate organizational
181
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
and functional form. These may be separate laws for different types of
cooperatives (production, service, consumer), a law on all agricultural
cooperatives, or a law on cooperation including both agricultural and nonagricultural cooperatives. In this category, we also have special laws on Water
User Associations (especially in Central Asia) and credit unions (credit
cooperatives) – recent innovations formulated and adopted during the transition.
The cooperative-specific laws are supported by implementation-enabling
government resolutions (third-level supporting legislation).21 The various
cooperative laws in the 12 CIS countries are inventoried in Table 11.4.
After this chapter had been written, FAO’s Regional Office for Europe and
Central Asia (FAO/REU) developed a database of cooperative laws in the
countries of the former Soviet Union, including excerpts relating to cooperatives
from the Civil and Tax Codes for each country (Compendium, 2016). The laws
in the compendium are current as of 2015-2016 and they are regularly updated
with inputs from each country when new legislation on cooperatives is passed by
national parliaments.
Content of Cooperative Laws Across CIS
ILO recommendations for cooperative legislation (Henry, 2012) set out the
following bullet points for the main contents of a standard cooperative law:
1.
2.
3.
4.
5.
6.
Preamble: cooperative principles
General provisions: definition of cooperative
Formation and registration
Membership
Organs/bodies and management
Capital formation, accounts, surplus distribution and loss coverage
21
The terminological tangle is exacerbated when we notice that in addition to “laws of cooperatives”
the CIS countries also have so-called “laws of consumer cooperation”, which were passed in 1991-1992
based on Soviet concepts of cooperation as enunciated in the 1988 USSR Law on Cooperation. These
“laws of consumer cooperation” deal with so-called “rural consumer societies” – part of a centrally
imposed state-run system (formerly known as Tsentrosoyuz in the Soviet Union) whose function was to
supply consumer goods to the rural population and sell the output produced on household plots. The
“consumer cooperation system” is dormant today in rural areas, but its administrators in the center
remain a powerful lobby. The system, although hardly functioning, is so entrenched in former Soviet
countries that Tajikistan, for instance, was forced to retain the 1992 Law of Consumer Cooperation in
its statutes in parallel with the new 2013 Law of Cooperatives. The “consumer societies” should be
clearly distinguished from the current concept of “consumer cooperatives” confusingly used as a
synonym for “service cooperatives”. At the risk of increased terminological confusion, we should
mention that, on paper, the “consumer societies” share many characteristics with the Western concept
of rural consumer cooperative – i.e., a local “coop store” that supplies consumer goods in the village,
thus saving the residents the need to travel to town more than is absolutely necessary.
182
11. Cooperatives in CIS and Georgia: Overview of Legislation
7. Audit
8. Dissolution
9. Simplified cooperative structures
10.Horizontal and vertical integration
11.Dispute settlement
Table 11.4. Inventory of cooperative-related legislation in CIS
Region/country
European CIS
Belarus
Civil Code
Cooperative laws
Production coops only (Dec1998, Sec.
3, art. 107-112)
N Production coops (collective farms):
standard kolkhoz statute (Presidential
Decree, Feb2001)
N Law on cooperation (Jan1992)
N Consumer cooperation (Sep2000)
N Business (entrepreneurial) coops
(Apr2001)
N Production coop (Apr2002, upd. 2010)
N Draft law on producer groups (2013)
N Law Ag Cooperation (Dec1995, upd.
Dec2011)
N Production coops (May1996, upd.
Nov2011)
Moldova
General non-specific definitions
(6Jun2002, Part 3, art. 171-178),
anticipating specific coop legislation
Russia
Production cooperatives (commercial
entities) Consumer (=service)
cooperatives (non-commercial entities)
(Oct1994, Ch. 4, Sec. 3, Art. 107-112;
Sec. 5, Art. 116)
Production coops only (Nov2012
update, Ch. 8, Art. 163-166)
Ukraine
Transcaucasia
Armenia
General non-specific definition, either
commercial or non-commercial entities
(28July1998, Ch. 5, Sec. 1, art. 50, 51;
Sec. 3, art. 117-121)
Georgia
No mention of cooperatives
Azerbaijan
Cooperatives are commercial entities
(Dec1999, Ch. 2, Art. 109-113)
183
N Law on Cooperation (Nov2004, upd.
Jun2009)
N Law on Agricultural Cooperation
(Nov2012, eff. Jan2013)
N Law on Consumer Cooperation
(Dec1993, marginal update Oct2011):
Soviet heritage inconsistent with Civil
Code
N Ongoing donor and government
initiatives without clear legislative
support
N Law on Entrepreneurs 2008-2012 (Ch.
5)
N Draft Law on Farmers Groups
(Mar2013)
N Law on Agricultural Cooperatives
(Jul2013)
N Law on Cooperation (Feb1996)
N Draft law on Agricultural Cooperation,
2010-2013 (2nd reading after
Mar2013)
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
Table 11.4 (continued)
Region/country
Central Asia
Kazakhstan
Kyrgyzstan
Tajikistan
Turkmenistan
Uzbekistan
Civil Code
Cooperative laws
Initially production coops only
(Dec1994, art. 96-101), subsequently
updated to include consumer (=service)
coops (1998, art. 108)
N Law of Production Cooperatives
(1995)
N Law of Agricultural Partnerships and
Their Associations (2000)
N Law of Consumer (=Service)
Cooperatives (2001, upd. Dec2012)
N Law of Rural Consumer Cooperation
(=Rural Service Cooperatives) (1999,
upd. Dec2012)
N Law of Cooperation (1991)
N Law of Cooperation (1999)
N Law of Cooperatives (2005)
General non-specific definition, either
commercial or non-commercial entities
(May1996, upd. 2010, Ch. 5, Sec. 1,
Art. 85; Sec. 3, Art. 152-153)
Production cooperative (commercial
entity) (Art. 118-123)
Consumer cooperative (noncommercial
entity) (Art. 128)
(Jun1999, upd. 2010 Chapter 4, Sec. 1,
3, 5)
Duality of definition as in Uzb
No mention of cooperatives (Aug2012)
Production cooperative (commercial
entity) (Sec. 2, Art. 69)
Consumer cooperative (noncommercial
entity) (Sec. 3, Art. 73)
Both definitions compatible with notion
of service cooperative; see Taj
(Mar1997, repeatedly updated to
Sep2010)
N Law of Consumer Cooperation (1992,
upd 2008)
N Law of Production Cooperatives
(2002)
N Law of Cooperatives (2013)
N Law of Consumer Cooperation (1991)
N Law of Peasant Associations
[Production Coops] (1995)
N Law of Consumer Cooperation (1991,
revised 1993-98)
N Law of Agricultural [Production]
Coops (Shirkats) (1998, updt to 2013)
By and large, the cooperative laws in all CIS countries where they exist are
formally structured according to these blocks. This applies not only to the
relatively recent cooperative laws heavily influenced by donor views
(Azerbaijan, Kyrgyzstan, Tajikistan), but also to much of the older legislation
based on the traditional Soviet template.
While it is useful to keep these bullets as a formal checklist for “clearing”
cooperative legislation across countries, we will move from this strictly structural
level to more substantive content reflecting the treatment of basic conceptual
issues in CIS cooperative laws. In line with the conceptual discussion above, we
review the CIS legislation on cooperatives by the following parameters:
184
11. Cooperatives in CIS and Georgia: Overview of Legislation
N
N
N
N
N
N
N
N
N
N
N
N
Existence of cooperative laws
Acceptance of ICA cooperative principles
Objectives
Separate laws for service and production cooperatives
Membership (physical/legal bodies)
Participation in cooperative activity
Contribution of member labor to cooperative
Distributions to members
Cooperative profits and tax status
Clientele
Multilevel structure of the cooperative system
Ability to invest individual land shares in cooperative equity
The review is presented in Table 11.5, with each row covering one of the
issues above. Since most countries have adopted multiple cooperative laws over
the years, the information in Table 11.5 is based on the latest law currently in
force (identified in the notes to the table). Cells marked N.A. in Table 11.5 reflect
situations when the existing law does not touch at all on the relevant issue. Below
we elaborate in more detail the various issues covered by the rows of Table 11.5.
Existence of Cooperative Laws
Practically all CIS countries have cooperative-specific laws in their statutes
(see Table 11.4). Almost the only exceptions are Belarus and Turkmenistan,
where agricultural cooperatives are still identified exclusively with collective
farms. Uzbekistan, another CIS country that emphasizes collective farms and
production cooperatives, has nevertheless elaborated its law of production
cooperatives (shirkats) to include cooperative attributes ranging beyond the
limited scope of collective farms. Curiously, Armenia – originally one of the
leading reformers in the CIS – still has not passed a coherent up-to-date law of
cooperatives, although various drafts are being debated on donor initiatives. There
appears to be a singular lack of political will in Armenia to push in the direction
of proper cooperative legislation. Armenia still relies on the 1993 Law of
Consumer Cooperation based on the Soviet tsentrosoyuz model of rural consumer
societies guided by a national union.
185
Table 11.5. Main characteristics of agricultural cooperatives as reflected in CIS legislation
Bel
No
Mol
Yes
Rus
Yes
Ukr
Yes
Arm
Yes
Geo
Yes
Az
Yes
Kaz
Yes
Kyr
Yes
Taj
Yes
Yes
(implicitly
in kolkhoz
statute)
Yes;
separate
definition
in Civil
Code
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
No
No
No; but no
distinction
in law
between
two types
No
Yes
No: law
covers all
forms of
coops
Membership: physical
& legal bodies
Yes
(implicitly
: right to
associate)
Yes
(serv.)
No (prod.)
Combined
prod/serv
law plus
separate
law on
prod coop
Yes;
specific
mention
of hh plots
Yes
Yes (other
coops)
Yes (only
physical
in prod
coops)
Yes
Minimum age
Minimum number
Participation in
cooperative activity
Contribution of
member labor to
cooperative
Preferential prices for
members
Distribution of income
to members
18
N.A.
N.A.
16
5
Yes
16
5
Yes
16
3
Yes
N.A. (only
physical in
rural
consumer
societies)
16
30
N.A.
18
3-5
Yes
16
3
Yes
Yes
Yes (prod
only)
N.A.
N.A.
N.A.
N.A.
No (serv.)
Yes
(prod)
Yes
N.A.
N.A.
N.A.
Yes (prod
coops
only)
N.A.
Yes
Yes
Income
net of
member
transactio
ns
N.A.
Yes
Yes
Acceptance of ICA
cooperative principles
Objectives: benefit
members
Separate laws for
service/production
cooperatives
186
Tur
No:
created by
order
“Rural
pop”
Uzb
Yes
No: law
covers all
forms of
coops
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
No
Yes
18
2
Yes
18
7
Yes
16
3
Yes
Adults
N.A.
N.A.
16
N.A.
N.A.
No
N.A.
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
N.A.
Yes
Yes
N.A.
No
Yes
Yes
N.A.
Yes; in
propor. to
asset
share
Yes
(social
infrastr.)
Table 11.5 (continued)
Bel
Prod coop
(commer.)
Consumer
coop
(noncommer.)
Mol
Commercial entity;
no VAT
on
transactions w.
members*
Rus
Prod coop
(commer.)
Consumer
coop
(noncommer.)
Clientele: members &
nonmembers
N.A.
Yes
(50%)
Yes
(50%)
Multilevel structure
Yes
(implicitly
: right to
associate)
Yes
Yes
Yes
Cooperative tax status:
non-commercial entity,
tax exemptions
Land transferred to
coop
Ukr
Non-profit
entities;
transactio
ns with
members
do not
contribute
to income
N.A.
Arm
No: either
form
Geo
Yes
Az
Tax
credits for
ag
producers
extended
to service
coops
Kaz
Yes
Kyr
Yes
N.A.
N.A.
Yes
Yes
N.A.
N.A.
Yes
(service
coops)
Yes
Yes
No (serv.)
Yes
(prod)
Tur
N.A.
N.A.
Taj
Noncomm
(mainly
trans.with
members)
Comm
(mainly
w/nonmembers)
Yes
Yes
Yes
N.A.
N.A.
Uzb
Prod coop
(commer.)
Consumer
coop
(noncommer.),
taxexempt
Yes: hired
labor
Yes
No (lease
Yes
Yes
N.A.
Yes
Yes
No (lease
Yes for
N.A.
Yes (prod
only)
only)
joint use,
coops
only)
excl. own
plots
Bel: Civil Code (Dec1998), Production coops (collective farms): standard kolkhoz statute (Presidential Decree, Feb2001); minimum age: age of adulthood from Civil Code (by default).
Mol: Law on Business (entrepreneurial) coops (Apr2001); *Tax Code (2013), Part III, Ch. 4, art. 103(1): 22)
Rus: Law on Agricultural Cooperation (Dec1995, upd. Dec2011)
Ukr: Law on Cooperation (Nov2004, upd. Jun2009), Law on Agricultural Cooperation (Nov2012, eff. Jan2013)
Arm: Civil Code (28July1998, Ch. 5); Law of Consumer Cooperation (1993); minimum number of members is given according to Law of Consumer Cooperation (1993) for a rural cooperative society
Geo: Law on Entrepreneurs (25May2012), Law on Agricultural Cooperatives (12July2013), Law on Cooperation (Feb1996)
Az: Civil Code (Dec1999, Ch. 2, Art. 109-113), Law on Agricultural Cooperation (draft, 2nd reading, Apr2012),
Kaz: Law of Rural Consumer Cooperation (1999, upd. Dec2012), Law of Consumer Cooperatives (2001, updated Dec2012)
Kyr: Law of Cooperatives (2005), Tax Code (2009)
Taj: Law of Cooperatives (2013)
Tur: Law of Peasant Associations [Production Coops] (1995)
Uzb: Law of Agricultural [Production] Coops (Shirkats) (1998, updated to 2013), Tax Code (2007-2013)
187
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
Cooperative Objective
Supplementing the ICA principles, most laws explicitly recognize that the
objective of a cooperative is to increase the benefit of its members. The only
exceptions are Belarus, Turkmenistan, Uzbekistan – the countries without fullfledged cooperative law that continue to identify cooperatives with collectivefarm structures. In Uzbekistan, the objective of production cooperatives (shirkats)
is defined as improving “rural social infrastructure”, and in Turkmenistan it is
defined (for production-based peasant associations – daikhan berleshik) as
working for the benefit of the “rural population”. In Belarus, the standard statute
of a kolkhoz (which has the force of a kolkhoz law) describes at length how the
kolkhoz works to improve the situation of the members and of the rural population
at large, without specifically formulating member benefits as the cooperative
objective. This is as close as the laws in these three countries come to defining
member benefits as the cooperative objectives. Probably nothing should be done
about this omission at the present stage: it will need to be taken care of, alongside
with other deficiencies, when the three countries are ready to promulgate proper
cooperative laws, fully recognizing cooperatives of all different types.
As part of the goal of maximizing member benefits, some countries explicitly
include a provision that guarantees preferential prices to members. Most
countries, however, are silent on this point. The Moldova Law of Production
Cooperatives paradoxically includes a provision that prohibits “granting any
preferential rights to cooperative members” (art. 14(2), amended May 2008). The
only acceptable interpretation of this article is that it excluded granting
preferential rights to some members over other members of the same cooperative,
not over non-members.
Dichotomy Between Production and Service (“Consumer”)
Cooperatives
The prominent role of production cooperatives in CIS countries (as successors
of Soviet-era collective farms) is reflected in the prevailing service/production
dichotomy, which is often “canonized” in separate laws for the two types of
cooperatives. Six of the twelve CIS countries have separate laws for production
and service cooperatives on their statutes (see Table 11.5). This is not the
recommended practice in market-oriented economies. The ILO guidelines for
cooperative legislation recommend “one law for all types of cooperatives,
possibly with specific parts/chapters for specific types of cooperatives” (Henry,
2012, p. 59), and CIS countries indeed seem to be moving in this direction in their
188
11. Cooperatives in CIS and Georgia: Overview of Legislation
recent legislative attempts (Kyrgyzstan, Tajikistan, Azerbaijan, and perhaps most
notably Ukraine). According to the ILO guidelines, the one-law approach, among
other benefits, diminishes bureaucracy and prevents fragmentation of the
cooperative system that inevitably weakens its self-monitoring and lobbying
power. Reduction of bureaucracy is a particularly important benefit in the highly
bureaucratized and corruption ridden former Socialist economies.
Cooperative Membership
Membership in a cooperative, according to ICA principles, is subject to the
“open door” policy, ensuring both freedom of entry and freedom of exit. This is
typically reflected in CIS cooperative legislation. Individual members are usually
required to be adults (older than 16 or in some countries older than 18) and the
prevailing laws generally impose a minimum membership for the creation of a
cooperative (Table 11.5, rows for minimum age and minimum number). The
minimum number of members in CIS laws ranges from 2 to 7, while the ILO
recommendations suggest 3 as the minimum: with fewer than 3 members, “the
associative or group entrepreneur character of cooperatives becomes doubtful”
(Henry, 2012, p. 73). From considerations of freedom of association, the
minimum number of members in a cooperative should be kept as low as possible
and no maximum should be imposed. Consistently with the ILO conception, CIS
cooperative laws do not impose a maximum membership in cooperatives.
Cooperatives are allowed to create associations, unions, and other agglomeration,
which implies that, in principle, both physical and legal persons may be members
of a cooperative. The nature of a production cooperative requires personal
participation in cooperative production activities and membership in a production
cooperative is typically limited to physical persons. This is not so in service
(“consumer”) cooperatives, where members do not work in the cooperative and
thus legal persons may join as members.
Although household plots play a crucial role in agricultural production in all
CIS countries and due to their smallness are ideal candidates for joining a service
cooperative, only the Russian cooperative law mentions them explicitly as a
membership category. In all other countries, household plots are relegated to the
old Soviet-style law of rural cooperative societies, which was originally designed
during the Soviet era to address the specific needs of household plots. This may
lead to a legal attitude that focuses only on commercially oriented peasant farms
as “agricultural producers” eligible for membership in a service cooperative. On
no account should the role of household plots in agricultural production be
ignored, and they must always be regarded as legitimate candidates for full
membership in service cooperatives.
189
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
Member Participation in Cooperative Activity and in Labor Input
Participation of members in the activity of their cooperative is a basic principle
and it is indeed incorporated in the cooperative laws of most CIS countries (see
Table 11.5; other countries are silent on this issue). Contribution of member labor
to the cooperative, i.e., an obligation to work in the cooperative, is properly
limited to production cooperatives, which are totally based on member labor.
Service (“consumer”) cooperatives are usually based on hired labor, although
members may also work in such cooperatives.
Transactions with Members and Non-Members
Cooperatives are in principle conceived to serve their members’ interests.
Transactions with non-members are therefore regarded as an exception. However,
it is not always possible to avoid transactions with non-members, as the
membership base may be too narrow to allow growth and development. This is
the main motive that pushes service cooperatives to engage in transactions with
non-members. In production cooperatives, the situation is somewhat different:
production cooperatives employ members’ labor to produce for the market, not
for the members themselves, and their sales activities are automatically conducted
with non-members. The attitude toward transactions with non-members is one of
the features that differentiate between service and production cooperatives. The
European approach is to treat transactions with members as “cooperative
transactions” that do not generate profit and the transactions with non-members
as profit-generating “commercial transactions” (Henry, 2012, pp. 23, 38). 22 This
approach may have influenced (perhaps indirectly) the cooperative law in some
CIS countries, where profit earned on transactions with non-members cannot be
distributed to members.
Western cooperative literature usually cautions against allowing transactions
with non-members to spread too much and emphasizes the primacy of
transactions with members, although cooperatives laws in Europe and EU
Regulations somewhat paradoxically allow unlimited business with nonmembers
(Henry, 2012, p. 12, note 35). The treatment of this issue in CIS cooperative
legislation is patchy. Kazakhstan, Tajikistan, and Azerbaijan allow transactions
with non-members. Moldova and Russia impose a cap of 50% of sales on
transactions with non-members: if this cap is exceeded, the cooperative may lose
its status and all associated preferences. Other countries are usually silent on this
22
In Latin American legislation (including the 2008 Ley marco para las cooperativas de America
Latina), the transactions between members and their cooperative are qualified as acto cooperativa
(cooperative acts) as opposed to commercial acts (Henry, 2012, p. 38).
190
11. Cooperatives in CIS and Georgia: Overview of Legislation
issue and it is mainly discussed in the context of taxation: tax preferences may be
allowed on transactions with members, but not on transactions with nonmembers.
Taxation of Cooperatives
Tax inspectors in all CIS countries are bound by the language of the Tax
Code. Cooperative law can outline conceptual principles and suggest taxation
guidelines, but ultimately any tax ruling is based on the Tax Code. Thus, the
2005 Law of Cooperatives in Kyrgyzstan contains a blanket statement
deferring all tax-related decisions for cooperatives to the Tax Code (Article
32). Taxation of cooperatives involves two distinct issues: (a) value added tax
(VAT) and (b) tax on profits at the level of the cooperative. In both instances,
the Western approach to cooperative taxation is guided by the view that
cooperatives are “the mandatories of their members” (Henry, 2012, p. 71),
i.e., they “act on behalf of their members as their agents”:
Because of the close involvement of the members in the decisionmaking processes in the cooperative and because of the special
nature of the transaction between the members and their cooperative,
cooperatives can be seen as the executing agents of the members.
This view suggests that transactions between cooperatives and their
members should be exempt from both VAT and profit tax. The burden of
taxation should shift from the cooperative (“the agent”) to the members as the
principal.
Value Added Tax (VAT)
Cooperatives as legal bodies charge VAT on all their transactions. This has no
major effect on legal bodies doing business with the cooperative – such as
registered peasant farms, other cooperatives, or agricultural enterprises. In
accordance with universal VAT procedures, these legal bodies simply offset the
VAT charged by the cooperative against their own cumulative VAT obligations,
while the cooperative offsets the VAT charged by its clients against its own
cumulative VAT obligations. In this way, only the last incremental amount of
VAT is effectively paid to the VAT authorities. Yet smallholders who are not
registered VAT payers find themselves at a disadvantage. On the one hand, they
cannot offset the VAT charged by the cooperative on their transactions against
anything, and this increases their costs. On the other hand, the cooperative is
obliged to calculate the full amount of VAT on any transaction with the
191
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
smallholders and becomes liable to the VAT authorities for this full amount,
instead of just the incremental amount on the last link in a chain of transactions.
The cooperative will naturally attempt to charge this extra “cost” back to the
smallholder, paying less than the original invoice amount for the product received.
The smallholder is thus at a clear disadvantage when selling his products to a
cooperative (or actually any legal body) or when buying supplies from a
cooperative. A smallholder would be better off by dealing with a small private
intermediary (supplier or trader) who does not charge VAT rather than with the
cooperative.
Cooperative lobbyists in CIS advocate that all transactions with members
should be exempt from VAT. The Moldova Tax Code has maintained exemption
of agricultural service cooperatives from VAT on transactions with members for
many years (see 2013 version, Part III, Ch. 4, art. 103(1): 22). The 2009 Tax Code
of Kyrgyzstan similarly exempts agricultural service cooperatives from VAT on
transactions with members (Article 239). This is also the attitude of the developers
of the 2013 Law of Cooperatives in Tajikistan, who drafted an appropriate
amendment to the Tax Code. In other countries, there are no sweeping exemptions
of cooperatives from VAT. Partial solutions have been attempted in Kazakhstan,
where service cooperatives enjoy preferential terms paying only 30% of the
general VAT rate, and in Ukraine, where the novel concept of Agricultural VAT
allows agricultural cooperatives (alongside with all agricultural producers) to
accumulate their VAT obligations for internal development purposes instead of
transferring them to the state. These solutions are effective for legal bodies, but
not for smallholders. The VAT bias against smallholders can be resolved only by
unambiguous legislation that exempts from VAT all transactions with members.
Tax on Profits
Regardless of the formal status of cooperatives as non-commercial or nonprofit organizations, their financial reports may show an accounting profit at the
level of revenues and expenses. This accounting profit is taxable in principle.
Thus, although the Ukrainian law of cooperatives (2013) explicitly recognizes
cooperatives as non-profit entities, this conception has not yet fully penetrated the
Tax Code. The accounting profit is called “surplus” in Western cooperative
accounting, as the term “profit” is deemed inappropriate for “non-profit”
organizations. Surplus is created because the cooperative may have initially
underpaid its members for products delivered (expenses too low) or overcharged
them for inputs supplied (revenues too high). If the financial report shows an
accounting loss (i.e., “deficit” or negative “surplus”), this indicates that the
cooperative overpaid the members for the products delivered during the reporting
192
11. Cooperatives in CIS and Georgia: Overview of Legislation
period or undercharged for input supplies. In effect, the accounting profit or loss
(surplus or deficit) is the result of internal pricing decisions within the
cooperative, and not profit in the usual economic sense of the term.
Cooperatives do not know in advance, at the time of the actual transaction,
how much to pay to members for product deliveries and how much to charge for
input supplies and other services. Financial settlements with members are handled
in two waves: the first-wave payments and charges are in the nature of an initial
advance, and the final settlement is made at the end of the period, when the
financial statements have been prepared on the basis of actual costs and revenues,
including all overhead and management costs. As a result, a service cooperative
usually presents a financial statement that shows a positive surplus (accounting
profit) or a deficit (accounting loss) according to the scheme in Table 11.6.
Table 11.6. Schematic “profit and loss” statement of a service cooperative
Marketing cooperative
Revenues from sale of members’ products to
third parties
Costs:
First-wave payments to members
Operating costs of the cooperative
Gross income (surplus/deficit)
Supply cooperative
Revenues: first-wave payments from members
Costs:
Paid to suppliers
Operating costs of the cooperative
Gross income (surplus/deficit)
Gross income (^hoh^ in Russian) represents the surplus or deficit that is
further allocated by three channels:23
1) Allocation to the cooperative reserve fund or other capital funds (“retention
of earnings” in standard accounting terminology).
2) Distribution to members in proportion to their share contribution to the
cooperative capital (“dividends” in standard Western terminology; iZ_\u_
\uieZlu in Russian).
3) Patronage refunds (dhhi_jZlb\gu_ \uieZlu) in proportion to the
members’ use of cooperative services (i.e., essentially in proportion to firstwave payments to the members).
The sum of the three amounts distributed to members is equal to gross income.
Patronage refunds are determined as the difference between gross income and the
first two allocations (Table 11.7).
23
This income distribution scheme is outlined in detail in the 2013 Tajik Law of Cooperatives (Article
36) and more concisely in the 2005 Kyrgyz Law of Cooperatives (Article 28) or the 2012 Ukrainian
Law of Cooperatives (Article 9(5)).
193
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
Table 11.7. Allocation of profit in a service cooperative
Gross income (surplus/deficit):
Less allocation to reserve fund and other obligatory funds
Less distribution in proportion to share contribution (iZ_\u_ \uieZlu, “dividends”)
Difference available for distribution as patronage refunds (dhhi_jZlb\gu_ \uieZlu)
Conventional interpretation of the tax code will require the cooperative to
pay tax on the full gross income at applicable rates. Recognition of the special
nature of patronage refunds in cooperatives (as second-wave adjustment of initial
over- or under-payment to members) suggests that this component of gross
income should not be taxable. Furthermore, the U.S. tax code recognizes
“dividends” paid to members in agricultural cooperatives (but not other
cooperatives) as non-taxable at the cooperative level, i.e., exempt from
withholding taxes (Autry and Hall, 2009). The Dutch principles of the taxation of
cooperatives also exempt all distributions to members (“dividends”) from profit
tax under the so-called “participation exemption” (Dutch Cooperatives, undated).
If these tax principles are adopted, the cooperative will be required to pay tax only
on the share of gross income retained in reserve fund and other capital funds. The
amount retained in the reserve fund and other capital funds will be shown net after
deduction of the appropriate taxes.
Recognizing the need to exempt patronage refunds from taxation, the 2013
Law of Cooperatives in Tajikistan introduced an important provision in Art.
36(3):
Payments to cooperative members in accordance with their
participation in cooperative activities … are treated as expenses.
This essentially implies that patronage refunds are deducted from revenues as
part of operating costs in Table 11.7 and do not figure as part of taxable Gross
Income. We argue that the same treatment should be applied to the “dividend”
component (following the U.S. example).
The 2012 Ukrainian Law of Cooperatives classifies service cooperatives as
non-profit organizations (Article 9(1)) and similarly to the Tajik law explicitly
excludes receipts from sale of members’ products from calculation of accounting
profit (Article 9(4)). However, these attitudes have not been fully absorbed into
the Ukrainian Tax Code. As of January 2013, the profit tax for service
cooperatives is assessed on net income after subtracting all “mandatory and
dividend payments,” meaning that the profit tax is assessed on the net income
available for distribution as patronage funds – the last component in Table 11.7.
194
11. Cooperatives in CIS and Georgia: Overview of Legislation
This approach still subjects farmers who join cooperatives to double taxation, but
the tax base has been reduced considerably. 24
Tax codes in CIS often allow extensive concessions to the category of
agricultural producers. Thus, in Ukraine, agricultural producers have been subject
to a so-called special tax regime since 1998, which leaves them virtually untaxed.
Agricultural producers are entities that mostly engage in primary agricultural
production so that service cooperatives (including processors) are generally not
regarded as agricultural producers and do not enjoy the various exemptions
allowed to producers. This is often cited as a strong disincentive for farmers to
join a cooperative: as independent producers they enjoy a host of tax exemptions,
which are lost once they become members of a cooperative. A possible solution
to this dilemma is to explicitly recognize service cooperatives as agricultural
producers. Thus, in Kazakhstan, the current tax code does not envisage any
special tax concessions for cooperatives, but it explicitly puts agricultural service
cooperatives in one category with other agricultural producers. As such, service
cooperatives in Kazakhstan are entitled to follow a highly simplified tax-return
system, with minimum accounting requirements, and furthermore they pay only
30% of the standard tax rate on all basic taxes (primarily VAT and corporate
income tax, as well as land tax, land lease payments to the state, property tax,
social tax, vehicle tax). In Azerbaijan, the appropriate provision is incorporated
directly in the new Law of Agricultural Cooperation. According to Article 9.6,
“existing tax preferences … provided in law for agricultural producers are also
applicable to cooperatives created by agricultural producers.”
Although this approach eliminates some of the blatant tax distortions for
service cooperatives, possible distortions still arise for operators of household
plots. As physical persons, they only pay personal income tax and their
agricultural activities are exempt from taxes. If they join a service cooperative,
the cooperative – a legal entity – will be obligated to calculate VAT on their
transactions and to deduct profit tax from their share of income earned through
the cooperative
Registration Requirements for Cooperatives
Cooperatives are legal bodies and as such require registration, either as part of
general registration of legal bodies according to Civil Code or as a special
registration procedure specified in the country’s law of cooperatives. The ILO
guidelines for cooperative legislation state that, “the establishment of a speedy
24
A bill to amend the Ukrainian Tax Code so that agricultural service cooperatives are considered nonprofit entities in the Tax Code, and not only in the Law of Cooperatives, was introduced into the
Ukrainian Rada in March 2012 by the Communist parliamentary faction, but has not been passed.
195
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
and impartial registration procedure is a first step by the state towards facilitating
the development of a genuine cooperative system” (Henry, 2012, p. 69).
The registration requirements in CIS legislation are usually formulated in a
muted general language. Thus, the Azerbaijan Law of Cooperation (1996) devotes
a single sentence to the registration of cooperatives:
Article 9. State registration of a cooperative
A cooperative undergoes state registration in accordance with the
laws of the Republic of Azerbaijan and is granted the status of legal
person from the date of registration.
Similar laconic language is used for registration in the cooperative laws of
other CIS countries (e.g., Russia, Kazakhstan). The Civil Code of Belarus – a
highly authoritarian and centralist country – goes even further and explicitly states
that
… refusal to register a legal person from motives of inadequacy is
not allowed… Refusal to register by state registration organs may be
appealed through the courts (art. 47.1).
The 2005 cooperative law of Kyrgyzstan similarly states that
State registration of a cooperative may be refused only if the legally
prescribed creation procedure has not been followed or its
foundation documents are inconsistent with Kyrgyz legislation.
Refusal to register … or avoidance to register [by the state authority]
may be appealed to the courts (art. 10.3)
This mild tone adopted in various CIS laws is consistent with the ILO
recommendations on registration of cooperatives (Henry, 2012):
N …a cooperative must be registered once the conditions laid down in the
law are fulfilled (p. 68)
N …if prior approval is necessary, the discretionary power of the approving
authority must be strictly and effectively limited by law (p. 68)
N In no case must the registration procedure hinder people from forming
entities in the way that suits them best (p. 69)
N registration will be concluded within a short time period; a refusal to
register must be justified in writing; in the case of refusal, the founders may
appeal before a court, which should give a decision within a brief time
period (p. 70)
196
11. Cooperatives in CIS and Georgia: Overview of Legislation
N the fees for the registration and publication must in no case be prohibitive
(p. 70)
A different approach is found in the new Law of Agricultural Cooperatives
(2013) in Georgia. Uniquely among the CIS countries, Georgia
N establishes a special state agency, the Agency for the Development of
Agricultural Cooperatives within the Ministry of Agriculture, given in law
the power to confer or withdraw the status of agricultural cooperative (art.
8);
N introduces a two-step registration process for cooperatives: first register as
a legal body, then apply to the Agency for recognition as a cooperative (art.
7.2).
The Agency has powers to “grant and terminate a status of an agricultural
cooperative” (art. 8.5e)), without any explicit requirement to justify its decisions
in writing or to allow the injured parties to appeal to the courts. According to the
Law on Agricultural Cooperatives (art. 15.2), the rules for granting and
termination of the status of an agricultural cooperative were to be specified within
2 months after the Law came into force in July 2013. However, to date (March
2014) no regulation on this crucial issue has been made public. The two-step
registration process without clear criteria for the granting and termination of the
status of an agricultural cooperative would appear to be inconsistent with the
strong recommendations for simplicity and transparency voiced by the ILO (see
above).
Sources within Georgia25 state that the two registrations are intended for
different purposes. Registration as a legal entity is the normal record-keeping
listing required in Georgia for legal bodies, including all cooperatives.
Registration with the Agency is an optional step to be undertaken if the
cooperative would like to participate in government support programs. The
authority to grant and terminate the status of “agricultural cooperative” in Georgia
represents an effort at quality control, in order to weed out “false cooperatives”
which abuse the cooperative name in order to qualify for state aid. This is an
important function, as the “sleeping cooperative” phenomenon is fairly
widespread in the region (see Chapter 6).
On a technical level, we should perhaps also note that the lengthy and detailed
discussion of the Agency in articles 8 and 9 is more appropriate for an internal
25
Information provided by the FAO Representation Office in Tbilisi, Georgia (March 2014).
197
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
ministry document or a government resolution. It looks completely out of place
when embedded prominently in a law of cooperatives.
News reports in the Georgian press indicate that the government expects the
new cooperative law “to stimulate the enlargement of farms” (Georgia Business,
2013). The government also stresses that “irrespective of the size of the land plot
contributed by a member to the cooperative – whether 1 ha or 100 ha – all
members are equal, each member has one vote.” While the emphasis on the
democratic principle of “one man, one vote” is laudable, these statements give the
impression that the government officials think strictly in terms of production
cooperatives: members are expected to contribute their plots to the cooperative
for joint cultivation – instead of requiring the cooperative to provide services to
independent smallholders.
Georgia’s new law of agricultural cooperatives does not speak explicitly of
agglomeration of holdings in production cooperatives or transfer of individually
owned land to cooperatives. The views in the media are apparently fostered by
the definition of agricultural cooperative in article 6 of the new law, where areas
of cooperative activity are listed as “production, processing, packaging, labelling,
storage, transportation and marketing of agricultural products”. Lack of clear
differentiation between the activities of production and service cooperatives is
probably responsible for the traditional identification of any cooperative with
“production cooperative”. It is surprising that donor advice did not emphasize the
need to distinguish clearly between the two types of cooperatives and to refocus
the attention on service cooperatives, rather than production cooperatives.
Conclusion
The CIS countries have established an impressive array of cooperativeoriented laws. Most countries explicitly recognize the ICA principles of
cooperation, but difficulties and lacunae remain with regard to practical
differentiation between production and service cooperatives as well as taxation of
cooperatives.
The specific mix of agricultural cooperatives in CIS requires further work on
both the legal level and the public awareness level to clearly differentiate between
production and service cooperatives. Education efforts by the country
governments and the donor community are needed to explain the advantages of
the service cooperative model and its appropriateness for the CIS farming
population. Without acceptance by an enlightened rural population, there is little
chance for agricultural service cooperatives to take root. As part of the legal
efforts, the separate legislation for “rural consumer societies” inherited from the
Soviet era should be abolished, as these societies can be easily incorporated in
198
11. Cooperatives in CIS and Georgia: Overview of Legislation
general cooperative legislation. However, this approach will require political will
to overcome the lobbying power still retained by old bureaucratic structures.
Attention to taxation legislation is a highly practical area that requires
immediate attention. For cooperatives to become sustainable, it is essential to
adopt the Western principles and exempt transactions with members and all
distributions to members from taxation at the cooperative level. Only the portion
of surplus retained in the cooperative equity for growth and expansion may be
taxed.
A third issue, which is not related to legislation, concerns access to credit. It is
usually recognized that start-up cooperatives may require seed money to launch
their operations and establish an infrastructure base. These funds may come from
the government in the form of reduced interest rate loans through financial
institutions or from donors in the form of direct grants of money or assets. To
avoid wasteful distribution of subsidized credit, cooperatives should be required
to provide sufficient matching funds before getting cheap loans and entitlement
to credit should be strictly linked to performance: only active cooperatives with
valid business operations should be entitled to receive subsidized loans or other
grants. The approach of the Georgian government (as outlined above by the FAO
Representation Office in Georgia) could represent a novel approach to provide
vital investment support to true agricultural service cooperatives, while weeding
out false cooperatives which have registered themselves purely to take advantage
of occasional government support. As to donor support, it is important to change
the donor mindset: the traditional short-term horizons of one or two years are not
constructive for development purposes. It is essential to develop programs
ensuring sustained long-term support to cooperatives, such as the programs
initiated by Heifer Ukraine. It may also be useful to focus on establishing links
between agricultural cooperatives, as suppliers of raw materials, and private
processors, as users of raw materials. A good example of such an alliance is
provided by Danone Ukraine: Danone reaches out to agricultural service
cooperatives as sources of supply of quality milk for its dairy operations, while
ensuring long-term cash inflows for cooperatives through its milk purchasing
commitments.
In summary, development of public awareness, attention to taxation issues,
and creation of sustainable forms of financial support are the main issues that need
to be considered in the context of cooperative development in CIS.
199
Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition Countries
References
Autry C. and Hall, R. (2009). The Law of Cooperatives, American Bar
Association: Business Law Section, Chicago, IL.
Cobia, D., ed. (1989). Cooperatives in Agriculture, Prentice Hall, Englewood
Cliffs, NJ.
Compendium (2016). Legislation governing cooperatives in former Soviet Union
Countries, in: Comparative Analysis of Cooperative Legislation in Post-Soviet
Countries, FAO/REU, Budapest.
http://www.fao.org/europe/resources/compendium/en/
Dutch Cooperative (undated). Memorandum: Taxation of the Dutch Cooperative,
Blue Clue Tax Solutions, The Hague.
http://www.blueclue.nl/images/brochures/en/blue%20clue%20%20taxation%20of%20the%20dutch%20cooperative%20v1.0.pdf
Epshtein, D. (1993). “Cooperative movement in the Soviet Union: History and
future prospects,” in: C. Csaki and Y. Kislev, Agricultural Cooperatives in
Transition, Westview Press, Boulder, pp. 291-300.
Georgia Business (2013). Business Gruziya, 9 August 2013.
http://bizzone.info/agriculture/2013/1376075873.php.
Golovina, S., Nilsson, J., and Wolz, A. (2012). “The development of agricultural
production cooperatives in Russia,” Journal of Rural Cooperation, 40(1): 4459.
Henry, H. (2012). Guidelines for Cooperative Legislation, 3rd revised edition,
International Labor Organization, Geneva.
ICA (2013). “Co-operative identity, values & principles,” International
Cooperative Alliance. http://ica.coop/en/what-co-op/co-operative-identityvalues-principles.
Lenin, V.I. (1923). On Cooperation [in Russian], in: Collected works of V. I.
Lenin, 5th ed., vol. 45, pp. 369-377.
http://revarchiv.narod.ru/vladimilitch/lenin45/cooperation.html
Osipov, N.T. (1960). “Lenin’s Cooperative Plan and Some Issues in Current
Development of Kolkhozes” [in Russian], Pravovedenie, No. 2, pp. 73-82.
http://www.law.edu.ru/article/article.asp?articleID=1128478
Serova, E. (1991). Agricultural Cooperation in the USSR [in Russian], Moscow:
Agropromizdat, pp. 44-57.
200