Industrialization
Dragos Simandan
How to cite: Simandan D. (2009) “Industrialization”. In R Kitchin & N Thrift, Eds.,
International Encyclopedia of Human Geography, Oxford: Elsevier, volume 5, pp. 419425.
ABSTRACT This article (1) defines industrialisation and indicates ways in which it can be
measured, (2) highlights the importance of the timing of industrialisation and the inherent limits to
the proper scientific explanation of this phenomenon, (3) disentangles the often confused
conceptual relation between industrialisation and capitalism, (4) explicates the causal links
between industrialisation and modernisation, (5) undertakes a brief assessment of the relative costs
and benefits of industrialisation, and (6) discloses the defining contours of scholarship on
industrialisation in Anglo-American human geography and illustrates it with a recent attempt to
integrate the field with the help of a master metaphor called ‘recursive cartographies’. Its portrayal
of economic reality as interplay of legacies, rhythms, and events conveys the usefulness of spatial
thinking in industrialisation research.
Key Words: economic geography, industrialisation, recursive cartographies, capitalism,
modernisation
Industrialisation: definitions and measurement
Industrialisation is a generic name for a set of economic and social processes related to the
discovery of more efficient ways for the creation of value. These more efficient ways are lumped
together under the label “industry” or “the secondary sector” (the primary sector of economic
activity referring to agriculture, hunting, fishing, and resource extraction, and the tertiary sector
referring to services). Beginning with the late seventeenth century, industrial activity has
dramatically enlarged its scope and scale, as machinofacture began to replace manufacture.
Historically, industrialisation studies have concerned themselves primarily with the period known
as the “Industrial Revolution” (Allen, 2007), although in geography this area of enquiry has been
the focus of many economic geographers interested in the contemporary logic of the global
economic landscape.
Using the criterion of the abruptness of change, one can distinguish two types of economic
change: events (swift singular changes) and processes (protracted cumulative changes).
Industrialisation is a process, not an event. A process is an emergent property of a system
(country, region) resulting from a collection of events that share a number of similarities and that
unfold over a slower timescale than that of its component events. If one entrepreneur opens an
industrial plant in an otherwise agrarian region, that singular event cannot be labeled
industrialisation. If a collection of events of this same kind achieves sufficient significance for the
local economy, scholars and policy-makers alike are entitled to refer to it at a higher level of
generalisation, i.e. they can speak of a process of industrialisation changing the face of that
regional economy. Two further conceptual problems require specification in this context.
Firstly, one must distinguish between quantitative economic growth and qualitative economic
change. If an already industrial region witnesses the opening of some new industrial plants, it is
inappropriate to label that set of events industrialisation. Instead, we must refer to it as simply
continuing industrial growth or economic growth. The concept industrialisation should be
restricted to the qualitative economic change occurring whenever an agrarian economy becomes
to such an extent affected by the opening of new industrial plants that it becomes misleading to
continue referring to it as an agrarian economy. In other words, industrialisation is an emergent
property of an economic system, a qualitative leap resulting from the spatially patterned
aggregation of a collection of economic events.
Secondly, one must pay attention to the measurement of the threshold above which it becomes
appropriate to speak of a process of industrialisation taking place. If one singular industrial event
does not by itself constitute a process of industrialisation, when does it make sense to refer to
such a process? Geographers, economists, historians, and sociologists of industrialisation have
been rather casual in their approach to this measurement problem (O’Rourke et al, 2005), relying
on common sense just as much as on specific quantitative cut-off points. There are three major
ways to decide as to whether one national or regional economy is undertaking industrialisation.
The first requires a comparison of the relative contribution to the gross domestic product of the
secondary sector (manufacturing industry) versus that of the primary sector (agriculture, fisheries,
hunting, extraction of raw materials). The second compares the percentage of the workforce
employed in industry versus agriculture. The third is more subjective, but also more geographical,
in that it assesses the extent of industrialisation by simply observing the landscape of a region.
Since industrial activities necessitate a drastic change of the physical landscape (e.g. fixed capital
in the form of built environments), they are easier to spot than more subtle social processes such
as exploitation, racism, or social stratification (Minca, 2007).
Explaining and timing industrialisation
The fundamental question geographers have to ask is whether the concept industrialisation has
contributed in any substantive way to furthering scientific enquiry into how our social world
works. There is probably no easy way to answer in any meaningful form such a question, because
the answer given would depend on the level of explanation at which the concept industrialisation
is being deployed. I argue that industrialisation has been particularly fruitful in helping
geographers and social scientists operate at the higher levels of explanation, or, at what might be
termed “big picture” thinking. Scientists and lay people alike relate to the world by building a
more or less detailed and accurate model of what the world consists in and of how it works. At a
very general level, it becomes fertile to have an understanding of how the history of the world has
unfolded, and such an understanding would need to include the saga of industrialisation. As an
illustration of “big picture” thinking, we can consider Alvin Toffler’s depiction (1980) of the
course of history as a succession of three waves. The first wave refers to the shift from huntergatherer societies to agricultural, sedentary societies. The second wave refers to the relative
decline of agriculture and the growth of industrial activities. Finally, the third wave designates the
shift from industry-based economic growth to service-based economic growth, and the relative
decline of blue-collar workers in favor of white-collar workers.
Historians of industrialisation (Kemp, 1989, Allen, 2007) have pointed out the fact that the timing
of this process is crucial for understanding its nature. In particular, they identify three periods of
industrialisation: the first refers only to England and pertains to historical contingencies between
1763 and 1846. The second includes countries such as USA (Licht, 1995), URSS (Davies, 1980),
Germany, and Japan, which became industrialised in the 19th century and the beginning of the
20th century. The third refers to the countries that have started their industrialisation after the
Second World War (e.g. the tigers and dragons of South-East Asia). The important observation in
this context is that all other countries except England have had at least some other model of
industrialisation which they could imitate and emulate. England is unique in that there
industrialisation appeared spontaneously, unplanned, from scratch, through a set of economic
initiatives that only in retrospect have been labeled “industrialisation”. The theories invoked to
explain the English Industrial Revolution have not ceased to proliferate and to take into account
hitherto ignored factors such as genes (Clark, 2007). Since for all other cases of industrialisation
the imitation factor has played a role, it follows that the geographical study of innovation
diffusion (Hägerstrand, 1952, Simandan, 2006) is a required step in any serious attempt to make
sense of this process.
Geography pretends to be a scientific endeavor and the hallmark of a scientific endeavor is the
attempt to explain and predict phenomena. To explain something means to uncover the lawabiding mechanism that caused it (Bunge, 2006). Scholars of industrialisation have fallen short
of this task, even though their work has converged on admitting the complexity of this process.
There are several inter-locked problems that together keep industrialisation in the clouds of
ambiguity. At the most general level, industrialisation is a social process, and epistemologists of
the social sciences have cast doubt over the feasibility of explanation in the social realm (Carr,
2008). The innumerable variables that contribute to social outcomes do not seem to allow the
social sciences to aspire to the same level of explanatory rigour as the natural sciences. Therefore,
a more modest goal would be to understand rather than explain the process of industrialisation.
Understanding results from describing and comparing the various historical and contemporary
contexts in which industrialisation has occurred, without assuming that there is a law-abiding
mechanism through which industrialisation necessarily emerges. The description and comparison
of the aforementioned contexts allow researchers to detect both the nomothetic and the
ideographic components of industrialisation. The nomothetic components refer to those general
facets of industrialisation shared by all the various contexts in which it has occurred, whereas the
ideographic components capture the unique, particular features that have stamped
industrialisation in a specific context (see Burt, 2005).
A related insurmountable obstacle to the explanation of industrialisation is that it is not possible
to experimentally test and refute the various theories attempting to account for this phenomenon.
Karl Popper (1935) made a forceful case for the idea that theories are scientific only to the extent
that they are refutable. The problem with the scholarship on industrialisation is that one can
always invent a plausible “just-so” story (Carr, 2008) and propose it as the explanation for this
process, without having to subject it to the risk of experimental refutation.
There is no single cause of industrialisation. The process can emerge from a variety of causes.
Similarly, the consequences of industrialisation vary widely across geographical regions and
historical times. In order to grasp these ideas in all their complexity, it is worth disentangling and
studying the relations between the often confused concepts of capitalism, modernisation, and
industrialisation.
Industrialisation and capitalism
Capitalism is a mode of production. A mode of production is a particular way of organizing the
economy and of allotting the costs and benefits of economic activities. Economic historians have
identified modes of production other than capitalism (primitive communism, slavery, feudalism,
socialism, and advanced communism) and economic geographers (Gibson-Graham, 1996) have
aptly noted that elements from these other modes of production can coexist, somehow “etched” in
the fabric of the dominant mode of production today – capitalism (cf. Peck & Theodore, 2007).
There is no relation of logical or causal necessity between capitalism and industrialisation. This
means that the two concepts do not entail one another either logically or causally. In plain
language, capitalism does not necessarily lead to industrialisation (although it has often been
considered as a favoring factor for industrialisation, especially in the scholarship on the first
Industrial Revolution in England; see Kemp, 1978). Furthermore, industrialisation can and has
happened in non-capitalist regions (e.g. Stalin’s Soviet Union, 1924-1953, see Davies, 1980;
Mao’s China, see Andors, 1977; Ceausescu’s Romania, see Simandan, 2004). To look at these
relations the other way around, it is worth noticing that industrialisation does not necessarily lead
to capitalism (see the cases of Cuba, China, or North Korea today) and that industrialisation is not
a necessary condition for the emergence of capitalism (for example, third world countries may
have a capitalist economy based on agricultural export-oriented monocultures or on tourism).
Statisticians’ urge to remember that correlation does not imply causation is therefore particularly
relevant when studying the relation between capitalism and industrialisation: both across
historical times, and across geographical spaces the two economic processes tend to go together
(Bottazzi et al, 2007). At first glance, one could speculate that they are mutually reinforcing
processes, although counter-arguments to this hasty speculation can also be easily conceived.
To understand the issues involved, note that the most prominent argument for the virtues of
capitalism consists in the neoclassical economic theorising of free-markets as best means for the
efficient allocation of scarce resources to many needs. That argument, in turn, depends on the
assumption of atomistic (innumerable) economic agents forced to coexist and fight with one
another in a condition of perfect competition (i.e. none of them is powerful enough to be sheltered
from competition). In other words, the alleged virtues of free-markets collapse if the assumption
of perfect competition is severely put into question by economic realities (Plummer et al, 1998,
Peck, 2008). And the process of industrialisation systematically does exactly that: on one hand,
technologies (one type of fixed capital) for the industrial process become yet more expensive
(because they embody more and more knowledge), and this need for larger initial investments of
capital encourage the concentration of capital in fewer hands (monopolies or oligopolies); on the
other hand, the need for economies of scale acts as a catalyst for the further integration and
concentration of capital.
However, it is not only the case that the logic of industrialisation can subtly move capitalist
realities far away from their idealised virtues: as Marxist geographers have amply documented
(Massey, 1995, Harvey, 1999, Swyngedouw, 2000, Hudson, 2005), the logic of capitalism
renders industrialisation a very fragile achievement. Just as the logic of industrialisation favors
concentrations of capital, which in turn undermine the free-market conditions of healthy
capitalism, so too the logic of capitalism favors the geographical relocation of capital, which in
turn undermines industrial activities in old industrial regions. In the initial stages of the
industrialisation of a new region, the prospects of continuous growth seem safe and sure.
Nevertheless, as time goes by, there is a tendency for the rate of profit of local capitalists to fall
because of factors such as exhaustion of raw materials, new competitors entering the market,
saturation of the market, increasing rent, new taxes (e.g. green taxes to internalise environmental
externalities), increasing cost of labour because of unionization, etc. Since the logic of capitalism
is the making of profits for profits’ sake, the local capitalists can choose to close the nowunprofitable local plants and reinvest their money elsewhere, in regions where they can make
higher rates of return on their investment. These new regions benefit from industrialisation,
whereas the older ones suffer the costs of the opposite process – deindustrialisation.
In a long term perspective, three observations become self-evident: the first, is that any apparent
beneficiary of capitalist industrialisation has its prosperous days counted before turning into one
of capitalism’s victims. Sometimes, these victims, because they are victims (i.e. high
unemployment, therefore oversupply of labour, therefore cheaper labour) might attract new
rounds of capitalist investment (Storper & Salais, 1997; Sadler & Thompson, 2001). Second,
from a spatial perspective, industrialisation and deindustrialisation are processes that together
express the historical geography of capitalism, its highly dynamic and uneven nature that so much
impressed Marx and his followers (see also Castree, 2007; Peck & Theodore, 2007). Third, from
a political perspective, it becomes clear that the state has a crucial regulatory role to play in
deciding the fate of industrialisation. Many of the contemporary struggles over economic
globalisation emerge precisely because of the conflicts of interest between states and capitalists:
the former care for economic development, high employment, national flourishing, whereas the
latter obey the different (trans-national) logic of capitalist competition (see also Yeung, 2005,
Painter, 2000).
Industrialisation and modernisation
As for the relation between modernisation and industrialisation, their conceptual knot is more
difficult to untie. Modernisation is the historical process whereby the social relations governing a
human community have shifted from being based on kinship, tradition, collectivism, and
magic/religion, to being based on rule of law, rationality, individualism, and scientific
knowledge. The trick is to understand that modernisation can be one of the unplanned effects of
spontaneous industrialisation, but also that political leaders keen to modernise their countries can
deliberately use industrialisation as a very potent means to that cherished end.
To give an example, Erving Goffman’s account of the moral career of stigmatization and his
discussion of ‘tribal’ (i.e. collective) stigma (Goffman, 1990), together with Karen Horney’s work
on collective neuroses (Horney, 1950) have recently been deployed by geographers to shed light
on the political performance of inferiority complexes and on their role in constituting marginal
territories as ‘in need of industrialisation’. Specifically, Simandan (2006) showed how Romanian
and Norwegian intellectuals educated in Paris in the 19th century, upon their return back home,
put their countries on the path of industrialisation and modernisation by attempting to copy what
they saw in France. Industrialisation played the role of a difference-reducing engine between a
deplorable economic backwardness and an intense longing for modernisation. The positive
stories of industrialisation have played a major role in the invention of the modern nations
(Anderson, 1991), as an analysis of media and of general education school texts would clearly
reveal. They have occupied a privileged position in the ‘spaces of constructed visibility’
(Gregory, 1998) where the imaginary geographies of the nation are fabricated (exhibitions,
museums, textbooks, traditional and electronic media, public ceremonies). Nevertheless, and of
paramount significance, these stories have helped fabricating the modern fiction of the nation,
and not just some timeless collective identity.
Until recently, the parties concerned with the development of the third world countries have
encouraged their industrialisation as a way out of backwardness and poverty and towards
civilisation, modernity, and prosperity. The problem with this encouragement is that it is valueladen (Massey, 2005): it implies that the values of modernity (which happen to be the values of
Western culture; Scott, 2005) are superior to the values of traditional cultures in the third-world,
which is akin to saying that the Westerners are superior to the “primitives”. Since Western
scholars and politicians alike have publicly rejected the older assumptions of Western superiority
and have embraced an egalitarian worldview according to which all cultures are equally valuable
(for exceptions see Sowell, 1998; Rindermann, 2008), the ongoing advocacy of industrialisation
as a solution for the third world appears deprived of its most entrenched rationale. To propose a
solution implies that there is a problem, and if backwardness is not the problem, than what is it? I
will leave these thorny questions to the pondering of critical geographers and post-development
studies scholars and turn instead to the weighting of the overall costs and benefits of
industrialisation.
Costs and benefits of industrialisation
Industrialisation’s legacy of delegation of responsibility for environmental problems has been
well documented by geographers and industrial ecologists. The internalisation of its negative
environmental externalities remains an inconsistent and poorly enforced practice in many parts of
the world. Furthermore, the deeper question of the limits of natural resource substitution has
received sustained attention only from a few specialists (Ayres, 2007), despite the fact that the
fate of industries is written in the answer to that question.
Unlike the developed countries who became industrialised before the second world war (England,
USA, URSS, Germany, Japan), the third world countries who are currently trying to start or speed
up the process are confronted with the lack of sufficient local capital. This means that for them
industrialisation can come only at the cost of increasing dependence on foreign capital. If they
choose to specialise in export-oriented industrial production instead of import-substitution
industrial production, this foreign dependence for capital is further amplified by a dependence on
volatile and competitive foreign markets. Furthermore, given that current international economic
policies set by the World Bank, the International Monetary Fund, and the World Trade
Organization implicitly or explicitly support national economic specialisation (Ricardo’s
principle of comparative advantage writ large; Weiss, 2002), the least developed countries in the
world are pressured to participate in a global economic gamble in which their odds of winning are
very long indeed (Harvey, 2003).
Aside from modernisation, the other most frequently invoked benefit of industrialisation is
economic development. The problem – as some third world countries have found out – is that
industrialisation does not necessarily lead to massive economic development. Let me clarify the
concepts involved. Economic growth refers to a quantitative increase in the gross domestic
product of a country. Economic development refers to a qualitative structural change in a given
economy. If a given country or region has some industrial plants specialised in the production of
consumer goods and/or is totally export oriented, it runs the risk of witnessing economic growth
without economic development. The respective industries are not organically embedded in the
regional or national economy and play the role of the cherry on the cake instead of playing the
more ambitious role of the yeast that makes the whole cake grow. This latter role usually is
performed by capital goods industries, i.e. those industries that produce equipment needed for the
development of other industries. The lesson to be gleaned from this brief analysis of economic
growth versus economic development is that whether industrialisation is beneficial or not
critically depends on what kind of industrialisation one is speaking about (O’Rourke et al, 2005).
Scholars and policy makers have also argued that industrialisation is the best way to fight
excessive population growth in the third world (Weeks, 2005). Rural dwellers tend to have very
large families partly because they are less educated than urban dwellers, and partly because for
them children are a source of wealth and security in old age. The process of industrialisation leads
to increased urbanisation, increased general level of education, and increased income, all of
which contribute to changing cultural and demographic patterns in the direction of massively
reduced fertility rates. In statistical parlance, the impact of industrialisation on fertility rates is
mediated by the variables urbanisation, education, and income.
Geography and Industrialisation
The relation between the study of industrialisation and the discipline of geography can be
decomposed into: a) an analysis of how the tools of geography enhance our understanding of
industrialisation, and b) an analysis of how the interdisciplinary research of industrialisation can
add depth and context to the traditional concerns of economic and historical geographers.
Geography is a generic name for a set of various scientific practices loosely held together by a
common concern for the big themes of “space” and “society-nature relations”, as well as by the
networks generated through its having a distinct position in the academic division of labour
(Simandan, 2005). In other words, various texts count as geography to the extent that they
emphasise the use of concepts such as “space”, “place”, “distance”, “region”, “territory”,
“landscape”, and “environment” as entry points into the investigation of the social world. To
study industrialisation from a geographical point of view amounts to embracing a style of
thinking that is biased towards the aforementioned spatial categories. Is this bias justified? Instead
of arguing that the geographical point of view is indispensable to the study of industrialisation, I
would make the more modest claim that geography provides a conceptual toolbox for qualifying
the sometimes crude accounts of this process. Industrialisation unfolds in space and produces
space (Murdoch, 2006), and so do the related phenomena of de-industrialisation (Hudson, 2005),
modernisation (Scott, 2005), globalisation (Massey, 2005), dependency (Harvey, 1999), and
pollution (Bickerstaff & Walker, 2003). The recognition of the spatial dimension of
industrialisation becomes significant only to the extent that geographers can extract the actual
regularities, patterns, or “laws” of the operation of this process. It is at this level of analysis that
old and new challenges keep the geographical conversation open. One of the old challenges
comes from the fact that different political economic worldviews force divergent interpretations
of the same economic processes (see Scott, 2000, for a review). Thus, a geographical perspective
indebted to neoclassical economics (e.g. older style industrial location analysis; Barnes, 2003)
brings with it a more or less tacit endorsement of the beneficial effects of industrialisation,
whereas a Marxist perspective carries with it a strong normative baggage that urges sensitivity to
issues of social justice (e.g. Harvey, 2003, Castree, 2007). Rather than trying to endorse one view
and to discard the remaining views, it might be preferable to think of these different approaches
as theoretical resources with complementary roles to play. Each school of thought is a
constellation of gains and losses (Simandan, 2005): each take on the spatial logic of
industrialisation may be particularly insightful in one respect, and appallingly silent in other
respects.
Once with the turn to culture in the Anglo-American human geography of the 1990s, the
geography of industrialisation has witnessed, among other revampings (Barnes, 2001, Scott,
2000, Thrift, 2000), an orientation towards institutional (Amin, 1999, Rutherford, 2004, Yeung,
2005, Rodriguez-Pose & Storper, 2006) and evolutionary (Grabher, 1993, Grabher and Stark,
1998, Boschma & Frenken, 2006, Hassink & Dong-Ho, 2005, Bottazzi et al, 2007) approaches to
the analysis of the spatial dynamics of the industrial sector. These new directions have enriched
the explanatory power of economic geographies, by showing how path dependency, institutional
cultures, and geographical relations complicate the fabric of pure economic logic. Nevertheless,
more quantitatively minded geographers (Martin, 2001) lament the lack of clarity, rigour, and
empirical support that the new vocabularies of these recent schools brought about.
One of the new challenges that confront the geography of industrialisation comes from
poststructuralism (Yapa, 1996, Murdoch, 2006), feminism (Gibson-Graham, 1996, Massey,
2005), and non-representational theory (Thrift, 2007). These approaches share a reluctance
towards grand theories and criticise both neoclassical and Marxist perspectives on
industrialisation for their illusionary beliefs about an objective economic reality governed by laws
about to be “uncovered”.
This line of criticism alerts us to the limitations of a nomothetic study of industrialisation within a
presumed global space-economy and brings attention, at least indirectly, to the possibility of
using other entry-points to industrialisation research. To illustrate this latter point, a recent
attempt to integrate the field with the help of a master metaphor called ‘recursive cartographies’
(see Simandan, 2006) starts with the simple but powerful idea that the world is the result of the
interplay and mutual metamorphosis of three elements: rhythms, events, and legacies. A short
quote from the industrial geography literature is very helpful for understanding this model
(Hassink and Dong-Ho, 2005: 572):
…the historical process of industrialisation in North America and Europe is marked by stories of
small accidents leading to the establishments of one or two persistent centres of production.
Thereafter cumulative processes can generate a geographical structure of production which may be
stable for long periods of time (italics added).
I emphasized in the text three words. The first is ‘small accidents’ and in recursive cartographies
this would be translated as ‘events’. Anything that abruptly disrupts the pre-existing order of
things qualifies as event. The outstanding features of events are that they bring genuine novelty
and they perturb the state of affairs, though in largely different extents. The discovery of
electricity, political elections, a bankruptcy, a strike, a merger, a foreign investment, etc., are all
events.
The second word emphasized is ‘persistent centres of production’, which in recursive
cartographies would be labeled as ‘rhythms’. Anything that regulates a place, bringing constancy,
predictability, and structural identity to it, constitutes a rhythm. Five decades of communist rule
in Cuba, the production of chocolate in Birmingham, the four seasons of the temperate climate,
the urban timetabling of the transportation network, the legal system of a country, are all rhythms.
They weave the fabric of a place, while being from time to time wounded by events that
challenge their hegemony in processes of place formation. The advent of industrial activity to a
rural area is an event; it its wake, that industrial activity becomes a rhythm that begins to reconstitute that area as ‘industrial’ (e.g. workers going to work at 8am and returning at 5pm, the
schools adapting their curricula to prepare the new workforce, the streams of income in that local
community becoming dependent on those industrial plants, etc).
The third word emphasized is ‘cumulative processes’, which in recursive cartographies would be
classified under the heading ‘legacies’. Anything left in the world that is not either ‘event’ or
‘rhythm’ qualifies as ‘legacy’. Put simply, the legacy of a place is the coagulation of its past
events and past rhythms, with the critical observation that this does not mean that legacy is
‘dead’, lacking agency. Quite on the contrary, it contributes to place formation extensively: our
actions are often guided by lessons learned from past actions, the stereotypes that produce the
‘image’ of a place come from past knowledge (and that image significantly influences present
decisions – e.g. to invest or not to invest in a given regional economy), and a rhythm (e.g. the
petrochemical industry) might rest on regional legacies (petroleum).
The many types of cartographies of industrialisation to be found in contemporary geographical
scholarship make research into this area reach a level of vibrancy and sophistication rarely found
outside geography and promise to contribute to broader questions and critiques of our present
condition.
References
Allen R, (2007). "Engel's Pause: A Pessimist's Guide to the British Industrial Revolution,"
Economics Series Working Papers 315, University of Oxford, Department of Economics, revised .
Amin A, (1999), “An Institutional Perspective on Regional Economic Development” International Journal
of Urban and Regional Research 23 365-378
Anderson B (1991) Imagined communities London: Verso, second edition
Andors St (1977) China’s Industrial Revolution Martin Robertson
Ayres R (2007) On the practical limits to substitution Ecological Economics 115-128
Barnes T, (2001), “Retheorizing Economic Geography: From the Quantitative Revolution to the “Cultural
Turn”” Annals of the Association of American Geographers 91 546-565
Barnes T (2003) The place of locational analysis: a selective and interpretive history. Progress in Human
Geography 27, 69—95
Bickerstaff K, Walker G (2003) The place(s) of matter: matter out of place – public understandings of air
pollution Progress in Human Geography 27(1): 45 – 67
Boschma R, Frenken K (2006) Why is economic geography not an evolutionary science? Towards an
evolutionary economic geography Journal of Economic Geography 6: 273-302
Bottazzi, G., Dosi, G., Fagiolo, G. and Secchi, A. (2007) Modeling Industrial Evolution in Geographical
Space Journal of Economic Geography, 7: 651-672
Bunge M (2006) Chasing reality: Strife over realism Toronto: University of Toronto Press
Burt T (2005) General /particular (Key debates in geography) In Castree N, Rogers A, Sherman D, eds,
Questioning geography: Fundamental Debates Oxford: Blackwell 117-130
Carr D (2008) Narrative explanation and its malcontents History and Theory 47 (1): 19–30
Castree N (2007) Capitalism, the Left and the new world (dis)order, Progress in Human Geography, 31(4):
563-70
Clark G, (2007), A Farewell to Alms: A Brief Economic History of the World Princeton: Princeton
University Press
Davies R W (1980) The Industrialisation of Soviet Russia Vol. 1 The socialist offensive London: Macmillan
Gibson-Graham J.K. (1996) In The End of Capitalism (As We Knew it): A Feminist Critique of Political
Economy. Cambridge, MA: Blackwell
Goffman E, (1990), Stigma. Notes on the management of spoiled identity (Penguin, Harmondsworth)
Grabher G, (1993), “The weakness of strong ties; the lock-in of regional development in the Ruhr area” in
The embedded firm; on the socioeconomics of industrial networks Ed G Grabher (Routledge, London) pp
255-277
Grabher, G, Stark, D, (1998), “Organising diversity: evolutionary theory, network analysis and postsocialism” in Theorising transition. The political economy of post-communist transformations, Eds J
Pickles, A Smith (Routledge, London) pp 54 – 75
Gregory D (1998) Explorations in critical human geography. Hettner-Lecture 1997 Department of
Geography, University of Heidelberg
Hägerstrand T (1952) The Propagation of Innovation Waves, Lund, Sweden: Royal University of Lund
Harvey D, (1999), Limits to capital (Verso, London), second edition
Harvey, D. (2003) The New Imperialism. Oxford: Oxford University Press
Hassink, R., Dong-Ho, S. (2005). “The restructuring of old industrial areas in Europe and Asia: Editorial”,
Environment and Planning A. 37, 571-580.
Horney K (1950) Neurosis and human growth. The struggle for self-realization London: W. W. Norton &
Company
Hudson, R. (2005) Rethinking change in old industrial regions: reflecting on the experiences of North East
England. Environment and Planning A. 37: 581-596
Kemp T (1978) Historical Patterns of Industrialisation London: Longman
Kemp T (1989) Industrialisation in the non-western world London: Longman 2nd edition
Licht, W. (1995) Industrializing America: The Nineteenth Century Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University
Press
Martin R, (2001), “Geography and public policy: the case of the missing agenda” Progress in Human
Geography 25 189 – 210
Massey, D. (1995) Spatial Divisions of Labor: Social Structures and the Geography of Production.
Basingstoke: Macmillan, 2nd edition
Massey D (2005) For Space Sage, London
Minca C (2007) Humboldt's compromise, or the forgotten geographies of landscape Progress in Human
Geography 31: 179-193
Murdoch J (2006) Post-structuralist geography: a guide to relational space London: Sage
O’Rourke, Kevin H. and Williamson, Jeffrey G. (2005). From Malthus to Ohlin: Trade,
Industrialisation and Distribution since 1500 Journal of Economic Growth, Vol. 10, pp. 5-34
Painter, J. (2000) "State and governance." In Sheppard, E. and Barnes, T. (eds.) A Companion to
Economic Geography. Blackwell, Oxford, pp. 359-376
Peck J (2008) Remaking laissez-faire Progress in Human Geography 32(1): 3 - 43
Peck J , Theodore N (2007) Variegated capitalism Progress in Human Geography 31: 731 - 772
Popper K (1935) (1959 edition) The Logic of Scientific Discovery London: Hutchinson
Plummer, P., Sheppard, E., and Haining, R. (1998) "Modeling spatial competition: Marxian versus
neoclassical approaches." Annals of the Association of American Geographers 84: 575-94
Rindermann, H. (2008) Relevance of education and intelligence at the national level for the economic
welfare of people Intelligence 36(2): 127-142
Rodríguez-Pose A, Storper M (2006) Better Rules or Stronger Communities? On the Social Foundations of
Institutional Change and Its Economic Effects Economic Geography 82(1): 1-26
Rutherford T (2004) Convergence, the institutional turn and workplace regimes: the case of lean production
Progress in Human Geography 28: 425 - 446
Sadler D, Thompson R, (2001), “In search of regional industrial culture: the role of labour organisations in
old industrial regions” Antipode 660 - 686
Scott A, (2000), “Economic Geography: The Great Half-Century” Cambridge Journal of Economics 24
483-504
Scott D (2005) Conscripts of Modernity: The Tragedy of Colonial Enlightenment Duke University Press
Simandan D (2004) Poverty, resource management, and the cultural politics of industrialization in Central
Europe: the case of the Romanian Carpathians. Romanian Review of Political Sciences and International
Relations I (2): 45-60.
Simandan D (2005) Pragmatic scepticism and the possibilities of knowledge. Editura Universităţii de Vest.
Timisoara.
Simandan D (2006) Marginally Modern: Psychoanalysis and the Deconstruction of Inadequate
Communities. "Vasile Goldiş" University Press, Arad.
Sowell Th (1998) Conquests and Cultures: An International History New York: Basic Books
Storper M and Salais R (1997) Worlds of production: the action frameworks of the economy Cambridge,
MA: Harvard University Press
Swyngedouw E (2000) The Marxian Alternative – Historical Geographical Materialism and the Political
Economy of Capitalism, in Barnes T., Sheppard E. (Eds.) A Companion to Economic Geography,
Blackwell, Oxford, pp. 41-59
Thrift N, (2000), “Pandora’s box? Cultural geographies of economies” in The Oxford Handbook of
Economic Geography Eds G L Clarck, M P Feldman, M S Gertler (Oxford University Press, Oxford) pp
689 - 704
Thrift N (2007) Non-Representational Theory: Space, Politics, Affect London: Routledge
Toffler A (1980) The Third Wave New York: Knopf
Weeks J (2005) Population: an introduction to concepts and issues Belmont, CA: Wadsworth, 9th edition
Weiss J (2002) Industrialisation and Globalisation: Theory and Evidence from Developing Countries
London: Routledge
Yapa, L., (1996). What causes poverty? A postmodern view. Annals of the Association of American
Geographers 86, 707 – 728.
Yeung H (2005) Rethinking relational economic geography Transactions of the Institute of British
Geographers 30(1): 37-51
Related Websites
www.lakemac.infohunt.nsw.au/library/links/hschelp/modernhistory/industrialisation
www.fordham.edu/halsall/mod/modsbook14.html
http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/industrialisation
http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Industrial_Revolution
Glossary
Nomothetic: epistemological perspective that focuses the research process on the uncovering of
universal patterns, regularities, or laws. It perceives reality as the interplay of “surface
characteristics” and “deep structure” and attempts to explain the former in terms of the latter.
Ideographic: epistemological perspective that focuses the research process on the detection of
the uniqueness of each geographical location. It denies the nomothetic belief in the existence of
universal patterns, and thus portrays reality in descriptive rather than explanatory terms.
Industrialization
D. Simandan, Brock University, St. Catharines, ON, Canada
& 2009 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
Glossary
Ideographic Epistemological perspective that focuses
the research process on the detection of the uniqueness
of each geographical location. It denies the nomothetic
belief in the existence of universal patterns, and thus
portrays reality in descriptive rather than explanatory
terms.
Nomothetic Epistemological perspective that focuses
the research process on the uncovering of universal
patterns, regularities, or laws. It perceives reality as the
interplay of ‘surface characteristics’ and ‘deep structure’
and attempts to explain the former in terms of the latter.
Industrialization: Definitions and
Measurement
‘Industrialization’ is a generic name for a set of economic
and social processes related to the discovery of more
efficient ways for the creation of value. These more efficient ways are lumped together under the label ‘industry’ or ‘the secondary sector’ (the primary sector of
economic activity referring to agriculture, hunting, fishing, and resource extraction, and the tertiary sector referring to services). Beginning with the late-seventeenth
century, industrial activity has dramatically enlarged its
scope and scale, as machinofacture began to replace
manufacture. Historically, industrialization studies have
concerned themselves primarily with the period known
as the Industrial Revolution, although in geography this
area of enquiry has been the focus of many economic
geographers interested in the contemporary logic of the
global economic landscape.
Using the criterion of the abruptness of change, one
can distinguish two types of economic change: events
(swift singular changes) and processes (protracted cumulative changes). Industrialization is a process, not an
event. A process is an emergent property of a system
(country or region) resulting from a collection of events
that share a number of similarities and that unfold over a
slower timescale than that of its component events. If one
entrepreneur opens an industrial plant in an otherwise
agrarian region, that singular event cannot be labeled as
industrialization. If a collection of events of this same
kind achieves sufficient significance for the local economy, scholars and policymakers alike are entitled to refer
to it at a higher level of generalization, that is, they can
speak of a process of industrialization changing the face
of that regional economy. Two further conceptual problems require specification in this context.
First, one must distinguish between quantitative economic growth and qualitative economic change. If an already industrial region witnesses the opening of some
new industrial plants, it is inappropriate to label that set
of events as industrialization. Instead, we must refer to it
as simply continuing industrial growth or economic
growth. The concept ‘industrialization’ should be restricted to the qualitative economic change occurring
whenever an agrarian economy becomes to such an extent affected by the opening of new industrial plants that
it becomes misleading to continue referring to it as an
agrarian economy. In other words, industrialization is an
emergent property of an economic system, a qualitative
leap resulting from the spatially patterned aggregation of
a collection of economic events.
Second, one must pay attention to the measurement of
the threshold above which it becomes appropriate to speak
of a process of industrialization taking place. If one singular industrial event does not by itself constitute a process of industrialization, when does it make sense to refer
to such a process? Geographers, economists, historians,
and sociologists of industrialization have been rather casual in their approach to this measurement problem,
relying on commonsense just as much as on specific
quantitative cutoff points. There are three major ways to
decide as to whether one national or regional economy is
undertaking industrialization. The first requires a comparison of the relative contribution to the gross domestic
product of the secondary sector (manufacturing industry)
versus that of the primary sector (agriculture, fisheries,
hunting, and extraction of raw materials). The second
compares the percentage of the workforce employed in
industry versus agriculture. The third is more subjective,
but also more geographical, in that it assesses the extent of
industrialization by simply observing the landscape of a
region. Since industrial activities necessitate a drastic
change of the physical landscape (e.g., fixed capital in the
form of built environments), they are easier to spot than
more subtle social processes such as exploitation, racism,
or social stratification.
Explaining and Timing Industrialization
The fundamental question geographers have to ask is
whether the concept industrialization has contributed in
any substantive way to furthering scientific enquiry into
how our social world works. There is probably no easy
419
420
Industrialization
way to answer in any meaningful form such a question,
because the answer given would depend on the level of
explanation at which the concept industrialization is
being deployed. It has been argued that industrialization
has been particularly fruitful in helping geographers and
social scientists operate at the higher levels of explanation, or, at what might be termed ‘big-picture’ thinking.
Scientists and lay people alike relate to the world by
building a more or less detailed and accurate model of
what the world consists in and of how it works. At a very
general level, it becomes fertile to have an understanding
of how the history of the world has unfolded, and such an
understanding would need to include the saga of industrialization. As an illustration of ‘big-picture’ thinking, we
can consider Alvin Toffler’s depiction of the course of
history as a succession of three waves. The first wave
refers to the shift from hunter-gatherer societies to
agricultural, sedentary societies. The second wave refers
to the relative decline of agriculture and the growth of
industrial activities. Finally, the third wave designates the
shift from industry-based economic growth to servicebased economic growth, and the relative decline of bluecollar workers in favor of white-collar workers.
Historians of industrialization have pointed out the
fact that the timing of this process is crucial for understanding its nature. In particular, they identify three
periods of industrialization: the first refers only to
England and pertains to historical contingencies between
1763 and 1846. The second includes countries such as
USA, USSR, Germany, and Japan, which became industrialized in the nineteenth century and the beginning
of the twentieth century. The third refers to the countries
that have started their industrialization after World War
II (e.g., the tigers and dragons of Southeast Asia). The
important observation in this context is that all other
countries except England have had at least some other
model of industrialization which they could imitate and
emulate. England is unique in that there industrialization
appeared spontaneously, unplanned, from scratch,
through a set of economic initiatives that only in retrospect have been labeled ‘industrialization’. The theories
invoked to explain the English Industrial Revolution have
not ceased to proliferate and to take into account hitherto
ignored factors such as genes. Since for all other cases of
industrialization the imitation factor has played a role, it
follows that the geographical study of innovation diffusion is a required step in any serious attempt to make
sense of this process.
Geography pretends to be a scientific endeavor and
the hallmark of a scientific endeavor is the attempt to
explain and predict phenomena. To explain something
means to uncover the law-abiding mechanism that
caused it. Scholars of industrialization have fallen short of
this task, even though their work has converged on admitting the complexity of this process. There are several
interlocked problems that together keep industrialization
in the clouds of ambiguity. At the most general level,
industrialization is a social process, and epistemologists
of the social sciences have cast doubt over the feasibility
of explanation in the social realm. The innumerable
variables that contribute to social outcomes do not seem
to allow the social sciences to aspire to the same level of
explanatory rigor as the natural sciences. Therefore, a
more modest goal would be to understand rather than
explain the process of industrialization. Understanding
results from describing and comparing the various historical and contemporary contexts in which industrialization has occurred, without assuming that there is a
law-abiding mechanism through which industrialization
necessarily emerges. The description and comparison of
the aforementioned contexts allow researchers to detect
both the nomothetic and the ideographic components of
industrialization. The nomothetic components refer to
those general facets of industrialization shared by all the
various contexts in which it has occurred, whereas the
ideographic components capture the unique, particular
features that have stamped industrialization in a specific
context.
A related insurmountable obstacle to the explanation
of industrialization is that it is not possible to experimentally test and refute the various theories attempting
to account for this phenomenon. Karl Popper made a
forceful case for the idea that theories are scientific only
to the extent that they are refutable. The problem with
the scholarship on industrialization is that one can always
invent a plausible ‘just-so’ story and propose it as the
explanation for this process, without having to subject it
to the risk of experimental refutation.
There is no single cause of industrialization. The
process can emerge from a variety of causes. Similarly,
the consequences of industrialization vary widely across
geographical regions and historical times. In order to
grasp these ideas in all their complexity, it is worth disentangling and studying the relations between the often
confused concepts of capitalism, modernization, and
industrialization.
Industrialization and Capitalism
Capitalism is a mode of production. A mode of production is a particular way of organizing the economy
and of allotting the costs and benefits of economic activities. Economic historians have identified modes of
production other than capitalism (primitive communism,
slavery, feudalism, socialism, and advanced communism)
and economic geographers have aptly noted that elements from these other modes of production can coexist,
somehow ‘etched’ in the fabric of the dominant mode of
production today – capitalism. There is no relation of
Industrialization
logical or causal necessity between capitalism and industrialization. This means that the two concepts do not
entail one another either logically or causally. In plain
language, capitalism does not necessarily lead to industrialization (although it has often been considered as a
favoring factor for industrialization, especially in the
scholarship on the first Industrial Revolution in England).
Furthermore, industrialization can and has happened in
noncapitalist regions (e.g., Stalin’s Soviet Union, 1924–53;
Mao’s China; and Ceausescu’s Romania). To look at these
relations the other way around, it is worth noticing that
industrialization does not necessarily lead to capitalism
(see the cases of Cuba, China, or North Korea today) and
that industrialization is not a necessary condition for the
emergence of capitalism (e.g., Third World countries may
have a capitalist economy based on agricultural exportoriented monocultures or on tourism). Statisticians’ urge
to remember that correlation does not imply causation is
therefore particularly relevant when studying the relation between capitalism and industrialization: both
across historical times, and across geographical spaces the
two economic processes tend to go together. At first
glance, one could speculate that they are mutually reinforcing processes, although counter-arguments to this
hasty speculation can also be easily conceived.
To understand the issues involved, note that the most
prominent argument for the virtues of capitalism consists
in the neoclassical economic theorizing of free markets as
best means for the efficient allocation of scarce resources
to many needs. That argument, in turn, depends on the
assumption of atomistic (innumerable) economic agents
forced to coexist and fight with one another in a condition of perfect competition (i.e., none of them is
powerful enough to be sheltered from competition). In
other words, the alleged virtues of free markets collapse if
the assumption of perfect competition is severely put into
question by economic realities. The process of industrialization systematically does exactly that: on the one
hand, technologies (one type of fixed capital) for the
industrial process become yet more expensive (because
they embody more and more knowledge), and this need
for larger initial investments of capital encourages the
concentration of capital in fewer hands (monopolies or
oligopolies); on the other hand, the need for economies of
scale acts as a catalyst for the further integration and
concentration of capital.
However, it is not only the case that the logic of industrialization can subtly move capitalist realities far
away from their idealized virtues: as Marxist geographers
have amply documented, the logic of capitalism renders
industrialization a very fragile achievement. Just as the
logic of industrialization favors concentrations of capital,
which in turn undermine the free-market conditions of
healthy capitalism, so too the logic of capitalism favors
the geographical relocation of capital, which in turn
421
undermines industrial activities in old industrial regions.
In the initial stages of the industrialization of a new region, the prospects of continuous growth seem safe and
sure. Nevertheless, as time goes by, there is a tendency
for the rate of profit of local capitalists to fall because of
factors such as exhaustion of raw materials, new competitors entering the market, saturation of the market,
increasing rent, new taxes (e.g., green taxes to internalize
environmental externalities), increasing cost of labor
because of unionization, etc. Since the logic of capitalism
is the making of profits for profits’ sake, the local capitalists can choose to close the now-unprofitable local
plants and reinvest their money elsewhere, in regions
where they can make higher rates of return on their investment. These new regions benefit from industrialization, whereas the older ones suffer the costs of the
opposite process – deindustrialization.
In a long-term perspective, three observations become
self-evident: the first is that, any apparent beneficiary of
capitalist industrialization has its prosperous days counted
before turning into one of capitalism’s victims. Sometimes,
these victims, because they are victims (i.e., high unemployment, therefore oversupply of labor, therefore
cheaper labor) might attract new rounds of capitalist investment. Second, from a spatial perspective, industrialization and deindustrialization are processes that together
express the historical geography of capitalism, its highly
dynamic and uneven nature that so much impressed Marx
and his followers. Third, from a political perspective, it
becomes clear that the state has a crucial regulatory role to
play in deciding the fate of industrialization. Many of the
contemporary struggles over economic globalization
emerge precisely because of the conflicts of interest between states and capitalists: the former care for economic
development, high employment, and national flourishing,
whereas the latter obey the different (transnational) logic
of capitalist competition.
Industrialization and Modernization
As for the relation between modernization and industrialization, their conceptual knot is more difficult to
untie. Modernization is the historical process whereby
the social relations governing a human community have
shifted from being based on kinship, tradition, collectivism, and magic/religion, to being based on rule of law,
rationality, individualism, and scientific knowledge. The
trick is to understand not only that modernization can be
one of the unplanned effects of spontaneous industrialization, but also that political leaders keen to modernize
their countries can deliberately use industrialization as a
very potent means to that cherished end.
To give an example, Erving Goffman’s account of the
moral career of stigmatization and his discussion of ‘tribal’
422
Industrialization
(i.e., collective) stigma, together with Karen Horney’s work
on collective neuroses have recently been deployed by
geographers to shed light on the political performance of
inferiority complexes and on their role in constituting
marginal territories as ‘in need of industrialization’. Specifically, Simandan showed how Romanian and Norwegian
intellectuals educated in Paris in the nineteenth century,
upon their return back home, put their countries on the
path of industrialization and modernization by attempting
to copy what they saw in France. Industrialization played
the role of a difference-reducing engine between a deplorable economic backwardness and an intense longing
for modernization. The positive stories of industrialization
have played a major role in the invention of the modern
nations, as an analysis of media and of general education
school texts would clearly reveal. They have occupied a
privileged position in the ‘spaces of constructed visibility’
where the imaginary geographies of the nation are fabricated (exhibitions, museums, textbooks, traditional and
electronic media, and public ceremonies). Nevertheless,
and of paramount significance, these stories have helped
fabricating ‘the modern fiction’ of the nation, and not just
some timeless collective identity.
Until recently, the parties concerned with the development of the Third World countries have encouraged
their industrialization as a way out of backwardness and
poverty and toward civilization, modernity, and prosperity. The problem with this encouragement is that it is
value laden: it implies that the values of modernity
(which happen to be the values of Western culture) are
superior to the values of traditional cultures in the Third
World, which is akin to saying that the Westerners are
superior to the ‘primitives’. Since Western scholars and
politicians alike have publicly rejected the older assumptions of Western superiority and have embraced an
egalitarian worldview according to which all cultures are
equally valuable, the ongoing advocacy of industrialization as a solution for the Third World appears deprived
of its most-entrenched rationale. To propose a solution
implies that there is a problem, and if backwardness is not
the problem, than what is it? These thorny questions
could be left to the pondering of critical geographers and
postdevelopment studies scholars and we could turn instead to the weighting of the overall costs and benefits of
industrialization.
Costs and Benefits of Industrialization
Industrialization’s legacy of delegation of responsibility
for environmental problems has been well documented
by geographers and industrial ecologists. The internalization of its negative environmental externalities remains an inconsistent and poorly enforced practice in
many parts of the world. Furthermore, the deeper
question of the limits of natural resource substitution has
received sustained attention only from a few specialists,
despite the fact that the fate of industries is written in the
answer to that question.
Unlike the developed countries who became industrialized before World War II (England, USA, USSR,
Germany, and Japan), the Third World countries who are
currently trying to start or speed up the process are
confronted with the lack of sufficient local capital. This
means that for them industrialization can come only at
the cost of increasing dependence on foreign capital. If
they choose to specialize in export-oriented industrial
production instead of import-substitution industrial
production, this foreign dependence for capital is further
amplified by a dependence on volatile and competitive
foreign markets. Furthermore, given that current international economic policies set by the World Bank, the
International Monetary Fund, and the World Trade
Organization implicitly or explicitly support national
economic specialization (Ricardo’s principle of comparative advantage writ large), the least-developed
countries in the world are pressured to participate in a
global economic gamble in which their odds of winning
are very long indeed.
Aside from modernization, the other most frequently
invoked benefit of industrialization is economic development. The problem – as some Third World countries
have found out – is that industrialization does not necessarily lead to massive economic development. Let us
clarify the concepts involved. Economic growth refers to
a quantitative increase in the gross domestic product of a
country. Economic development refers to a qualitative
structural change in a given economy. If a given country
or region has some industrial plants specialized in the
production of consumer goods and/or is totally export
oriented, it runs the risk of witnessing economic growth
without economic development. The respective industries are not organically embedded in the regional or
national economy and play the role of the cherry on the
cake instead of playing the more ambitious role of the
yeast that makes the whole cake grow. This latter role
usually is performed by capital goods industries, i.e.,
those industries that produce equipment needed for the
development of other industries. The lesson to be
gleaned from this brief analysis of economic growth
versus economic development is that whether industrialization is beneficial or not critically depends on what
kind of industrialization one is speaking about.
Scholars and policymakers have also argued that industrialization is the best way to fight excessive population
growth in the Third World. Rural dwellers tend to have
very large families partly because they are less educated
than urban dwellers, and partly because for them children
are a source of wealth and security in old age. The process
of industrialization leads to increased urbanization,
Industrialization
increased general level of education, and increased income, all of which contribute to changing cultural and
demographic patterns in the direction of massively reduced fertility rates. In statistical parlance, the impact of
industrialization on fertility rates is mediated by the
variables urbanization, education, and income.
Geography and Industrialization
The relation between the study of industrialization and
the discipline of geography can be decomposed into:
(1) an analysis of how the tools of geography enhance our
understanding of industrialization, and (2) an analysis of
how the interdisciplinary research of industrialization
can add depth and context to the traditional concerns of
economic and historical geographers. Geography is a
generic name for a set of various scientific practices
loosely held together by a common concern for the big
themes of ‘space’ and ‘society–nature relations’, as well as
by the networks generated through its having a distinct
position in the academic division of labor. In other words,
various texts count as geography to the extent that they
emphasize the use of concepts such as ‘space’, ‘place’,
‘distance’, ‘region’, ‘territory’, ‘landscape’, and ‘environment’ as entry points into the investigation of the social
world. To study industrialization from a geographical
point of view amounts to embracing a style of thinking
that is biased toward the aforementioned spatial categories. Is this bias justified? Instead of arguing that the
geographical point of view is indispensable to the study
of industrialization, we could make the more modest
claim that geography provides a conceptual toolbox for
qualifying the sometimes crude accounts of this process.
Industrialization unfolds in space and produces space,
and so do the related phenomena of deindustrialization,
modernization, globalization, dependency, and pollution.
The recognition of the spatial dimension of industrialization becomes significant only to the extent that
geographers can extract the actual regularities, patterns,
or ‘laws’ of the operation of this process. It is at this level
of analysis that old and new challenges keep the geographical conversation open. One of the ‘old challenges’
comes from the fact that different political economic
worldviews force divergent interpretations of the same
economic processes. Thus, a geographical perspective
indebted to neoclassical economics (e.g., older-style industrial location analysis) brings with it a more or less
tacit endorsement of the beneficial effects of industrialization, whereas a Marxist perspective carries with it a
strong normative baggage that urges sensitivity to issues
of social justice. Rather than trying to endorse one view
and to discard the remaining views, it might be preferable to think of these different approaches as theoretical
resources with complementary roles to play. Each school
423
of thought is a constellation of gains and losses: each take
on the spatial logic of industrialization may be particularly insightful in one respect, and appallingly silent in
other respects.
Once with the turn to culture in the Anglo-American
human geography of the 1990s, the geography of industrialization has witnessed, among other revampings, an
orientation toward institutional and evolutionary approaches to the analysis of the spatial dynamics of the
industrial sector. These new directions have enriched the
explanatory power of economic geographies, by showing
how path dependency, institutional cultures, and geographical relations complicate the fabric of pure economic logic. Nevertheless, more quantitatively minded
geographers lament the lack of clarity, rigor, and empirical support that the new vocabularies of these recent
schools brought about.
One of the ‘new challenges’ that confronts the geography
of industrialization comes from post-structuralism, feminism, and nonrepresentational theory. These approaches
share a reluctance toward grand theories and criticize both
neoclassical and Marxist perspectives on industrialization
for their illusionary beliefs about an objective economic
reality governed by laws about to be ‘uncovered’.
This line of criticism alerts us to the limitations of a
nomothetic study of industrialization within a presumed
global space-economy and brings attention, at least indirectly, to the possibility of using other entry points to
industrialization research. To illustrate this latter point,
Simandan’s recent attempt to integrate the field with the
help of a master metaphor called ‘recursive cartographies’ starts with the simple but powerful idea that the
world is the result of the interplay and mutual metamorphosis of ‘three’ elements: rhythms, events, and legacies. A short quote from the industrial geography
literature is very helpful for understanding this model:
ythe historical process of industrialisation in North
America and Europe is marked by stories of small accidents leading to the establishments of one or two persistent
centres of production. Thereafter cumulative processes can
generate a geographical structure of production which
may be stable for long periods of time (italics added).
(Hassink and Dong-Ho, 2005: 572)
Three words have been emphasized in the text. The
first is ‘small accidents’ and in recursive cartographies
this would be translated as ‘events’. Anything that abruptly disrupts the preexisting order of things qualifies as
event. The outstanding features of events are that they
bring genuine novelty and they perturb the state of affairs, though in largely different extents. The discovery of
electricity, political elections, a bankruptcy, a strike, a
merger, a foreign investment, etc., are all events.
424
Industrialization
The second word emphasized is ‘persistent centers of
production’, which in recursive cartographies would be
labeled as ‘rhythms’. Anything that regulates a place,
bringing constancy, predictability, and structural identity
to it, constitutes a rhythm. Five decades of communist rule
in Cuba, the production of chocolate in Birmingham, the
four seasons of the temperate climate, the urban timetabling of the transportation network, and the legal system
of a country, are all rhythms. They weave the fabric of a
place, while being from time to time wounded by events
that challenge their hegemony in processes of place formation. The advent of industrial activity to a rural area is
an event; in its wake, that industrial activity becomes a
rhythm that begins to reconstitute that area as ‘industrial’
(workers going to work at 8 am and returning at 5 pm, the
schools adapting their curricula to prepare the new
workforce, the streams of income in that local community
becoming dependent on those industrial plants, etc.).
The third word emphasized is ‘cumulative processes’,
which in recursive cartographies would be classified under
the heading ‘legacies’. Anything left in the world that is not
either ‘event’ or ‘rhythm’ qualifies as ‘legacy’. Put simply,
the legacy of a place is the coagulation of its past events
and past rhythms, with the critical observation that this
does not mean that legacy is ‘dead’, lacking agency. Quite
on the contrary, it contributes to place formation extensively: our actions are often guided by lessons learned from
past actions, the stereotypes that produce the ‘image’ of a
place come from past knowledge (and that image significantly influences present decisions – e.g., to invest or not
to invest in a given regional economy), and a rhythm (e.g.,
the petrochemical industry) might rest on regional legacies (petroleum).
The many types of cartographies of industrialization
to be found in contemporary geographical scholarship
make research in this area reach a level of vibrancy and
sophistication rarely found outside geography and
promise to contribute to broader questions and critiques
of our present condition.
See also: Capitalism; Development I; Diffusion; Industrial
City; Industrial Districts; Industrial Location; Industrial
Organization; Industrial Parks; Industrial Restructuring;
Innovation; Modernity.
Further Reading
Allen, R. (2007). Engel’s Pause: A Pessimist’s Guide to the British
Industrial Revolution, Economics Series Working Papers 315,
University of Oxford, Department of Economics, revised.
Amin, A. (1999). An institutional perspective on regional economic
development. International Journal of Urban and Regional Research
23, 365--378.
Anderson, B. (1991). Imagined Communities (2nd edn.). London: Verso.
Ayres, R. (2007). On the practical limits to substitution. Ecological
Economics 22, 115--128.
Barnes, T. (2001). Retheorizing economic geography: From
the quantitative revolution to the ‘Cultural Turn’. Annals of
the Association of American Geographers 91,
546--565.
Barnes, T. (2003). The place of locational analysis: A selective
and interpretive history. Progress in Human Geography 27,
69--95.
Bickerstaff, K. and Walker, G. (2003). The place(s) of matter: Matter out
of place – public understandings of air pollution. Progress in Human
Geography 27(1), 45--67.
Boschma, R. and Frenken, K. (2006). Why is economic geography not
an evolutionary science? Towards an evolutionary economic
geography. Journal of Economic Geography 6, 273--302.
Bottazzi, G., Dosi, G., Fagiolo, G. and Secchi, A. (2007). Modeling
industrial evolution in geographical space. Journal of Economic
Geography 7, 651--672.
Bunge, M. (2006). Chasing Reality: Strife over Realism. Toronto:
University of Toronto Press.
Burt, T. (2005). General/particular (key debates in geography).
In Castree, N., Rogers, A. & Sherman, D. (eds.) Questioning
Geography: Fundamental Debates, pp 117--130. Oxford: Blackwell.
Carr, D. (2008). Narrative explanation and its malcontents. History and
Theory 47(1), 19--30.
Castree, N. (2007). Capitalism, the Left and the new world (dis)order.
Progress in Human Geography 31(4), 563--570.
Clark, G. (2007). A Farewell to Alms: A Brief Economic History of the
World. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Davies, R. W. (1980). The Industrialisation of Soviet Russia Vol. 1. The
Socialist Offensive. London: Macmillan.
Gibson-Graham, J. K. (ed.) (1996). The End of Capitalism (As We Knew
It): A Feminist Critique of Political Economy. Cambridge, MA:
Blackwell.
Goffman, E. (1990). Stigma. Notes on the Management of Spoiled
Identity. Harmondsworth: Penguin.
Grabher, G. (1993). The weakness of strong ties; the lock-in of regional
development in the Ruhr area. In Grabher, G. (ed.) The Embedded
Firm; On the Socioeconomics of Industrial Networks, pp 255--277.
London: Routledge.
Grabher, G. and Stark, D. (1998). Organising diversity: Evolutionary
theory, network analysis and post-socialism. In Pickles, J. & Smith,
A. (eds.) Theorising Transition. The Political Economy of PostCommunist Transformations, pp 54--75. London: Routledge.
Gregory, D. (1998). Explorations in critical human geography. HettnerLecture 1997 Department of Geography, University of Heidelberg.
Hägerstrand, T. (1952). The Propagation of Innovation Waves. Lund:
Royal University of Lund.
Harvey, D. (1999). Limits to Capital (2nd edn.). London: Verso.
Harvey, D. (2003). The New Imperialism. Oxford: Oxford University
Press.
Hassink, R. and Dong-Ho, S. (eds.) (2005). The restructuring of old
industrial areas in Europe and Asia: Editorial. Environment and
Planning A 37, 571--580.
Horney, K. (1950). Neurosis and Human Growth. The Struggle for SelfRealization. London: W. W. Norton & Company.
Hudson, R. (2005). Rethinking change in old industrial regions:
Reflecting on the experiences of North East England. Environment
and Planning A 37, 581--596.
Kemp, T. (1978). Historical Patterns of Industrialisation. London:
Longman.
Kemp, T. (1989). Industrialisation in the Non-Western World (2nd edn.).
London: Longman.
Licht, W. (1995). Industrializing America: The Nineteenth Century.
Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press.
Martin, R. (2001). Geography and public policy: The case of the missing
agenda. Progress in Human Geography 25, 189--210.
Massey, D. (1995). Spatial Divisions of Labor: Social Structures and the
Geography of Production (2nd edn.). Basingstoke: Macmillan.
Massey, D. (2005). For Space. London: Sage.
Minca, C. (2007). Humboldt’s compromise, or the forgotten
geographies of landscape. Progress in Human Geography 31,
179--193.
Murdoch, J. (2006). Post-Structuralist Geography: A Guide to
Relational Space. London: Sage.
Industrialization
O’Rourke, K. H. and Williamson, J. G. (2005). From Malthus to Ohlin:
Trade, industrialisation and distribution since 1500. Journal of
Economic Growth 10, 5--34.
Painter, J. (2000). State and governance. In Sheppard, E. & Barnes, T.
(eds.) A Companion to Economic Geography, pp 359--376. Oxford:
Blackwell.
Peck, J. (2008). Remaking laissez-faire. Progress in Human Geography
32(1), 3--43.
Peck, J. and Theodore, N. (2007). Variegated capitalism. Progress in
Human Geography 31, 731--772.
Popper, K. (1935). The Logic of Scientific Discovery (1959 edn).
London: Hutchinson.
Plummer, P., Sheppard, E. and Haining, R. (1998). Modeling spatial
competition: Marxian versus neoclassical approaches. Annals of the
Association of American Geographers 84, 575--594.
Rindermann, H. (2008). Relevance of education and intelligence at the
national level for the economic welfare of people. Intelligence 36(2),
127--142.
Rodrı́guez-Pose, A. and Storper, M. (2006). Better rules or stronger
communities? On the social foundations of institutional change and
its economic effects. Economic Geography 82(1), 1--26.
Rutherford, T. (2004). Convergence, the institutional turn and workplace
regimes: The case of lean production. Progress in Human
Geography 28, 425--446.
Sadler, D. and Thompson, R. (2001). In search of regional industrial
culture: The role of labour organisations in old industrial regions.
Antipode 660--686.
Scott, A. (2000). Economic geography: The great half-century.
Cambridge Journal of Economics 24, 483--504.
Scott, D. (2005). Conscripts of Modernity: The Tragedy of Colonial
Enlightenment. Durham, NC: Duke University Press.
Simandan, D. (2004). Poverty, resource management, and the cultural
politics of industrialization in Central Europe: The case of the
Romanian Carpathians. Romanian Review of Political Sciences and
International Relations I (2), 45--60.
Simandan, D. (2005). Pragmatic Scepticism and the Possibilities of
Knowledge. Timisoara: West University Press.
Simandan, D. (2006). Marginally Modern. Arad: ‘Vasile Goldis’
University Press.
Sowell, T. (1998). Conquests and Cultures: An International History.
New York: Basic Books.
425
St. Andors (1977). China’s Industrial Revolution. London: Martin
Robertson.
Storper, M. and Salais, R. (1997). Worlds of Production: The Action
Frameworks of the Economy. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University
Press.
Swyngedouw, E. (2000). The Marxian alternative – historical
geographical materialism and the political economy of capitalism.
In Barnes, T. & Sheppard, E. (eds.) A Companion to Economic
Geography, pp 41--59. Oxford: Blackwell.
Thrift, N. (2000). Pandora’s box? Cultural geographies of economies.
In Clarck, G. L., Feldman, M. P. & Gertler, M. S. (eds.) The Oxford
Handbook of Economic Geography, pp 689--704. Oxford: Oxford
University Press.
Thrift, N. (2007). Non-Representational Theory: Space, Politics, Affect.
London: Routledge.
Toffler, A. (1980). The Third Wave. New York: Knopf.
Weeks, J. (2005). Population: An Introduction to Concepts and Issues
(9th edn.). Belmont, CA: Wadsworth.
Weiss, J. (2002). Industrialisation and Globalisation: Theory
and Evidence from Developing Countries. London: Routledge.
Yapa, L. (1996). What causes poverty? A postmodern view.
Annals of the Association of American Geographers 86,
707--728.
Yeung, H. (2005). Rethinking relational economic geography.
Transactions of the Institute of British Geographers 30(1),
37--51.
Relevant Websites
www.fordham.edu
Industrial Revolution and the Standard of Living
Essay.
www.lakemac.infohunt.nsw.au
Industrialization website – a good brief overview of history and
characteristics of The Victorian Web Site at Brown University.
This site is useful for nutshell summaries of the Poor Laws, the
Corn Laws, etc., lectures on The Industrial Revolution in
England by Arnold Toynbee – lectures on The Industrial
Revolution.